Taming the Corporation Taming the Corporation How to Regulate for Success Robert Baldwin and Martin Cave 1 1 Great Clarendon Street, Oxford, OX2 6DP, United Kingdom Oxford University Press is a department of the University of Oxford. It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research, scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide. Oxford is a registered trade mark of Oxford University Press in the UK and in certain other countries © Robert Baldwin and Martin Cave 2021 The moral rights of the authors have been asserted First Edition published in 2021 Impression: 1 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permitted by law, by licence or under terms agreed with the appropriate reprographics rights organization. Enquiries concerning reproduction outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department, Oxford University Press, at the address above You must not circulate this work in any other form and you must impose this same condition on any acquirer Published in the United States of America by Oxford University Press 198 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016, United States of America British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data Data available Library of Congress Control Number: 2020941054 ISBN 978–0–19–883618–6 Printed and bound in Great Britain by Clays Ltd, Elcograf S.p.A. Links to third party websites are provided by Oxford in good faith and for information only. Oxford disclaims any responsibility for the materials contained in any third party website referenced in this work. Preface Our goal in writing this book is to set out how positive regulation can work in a way which is beneficial to firms and investors and to citizens and consumers. We have combined an account of how positive regulation can and should work with extended case studies of climate change regulation and the regulation of traditional physical networks and of modern digital platforms. In doing so we discuss how regulators can get things right, or how they may fail to ‘regulate for success’. We have also included a number of shorter illustrations of success and failure, and a chapter on how regu lators can seek to avoid the latter. This book is not about economic and social policy or its making, which is the preserve of legislatures or governments, but about the more tech nical aspects of regulation that are commonly undertaken by independent agencies within broad policy frameworks set by governments. Thus strat egies for implementing or enforcing given policies are central to our con cerns. This is seen, for example, in our discussion in chapter 6 of regulatory activity designed to support climate change objectives; our objective is not to discuss governmental objectives but to outline how regulation can best achieve them. Robert Baldwin is chiefly responsible for Chapters 1–5 and 10–11; Martin Cave for Chapters 7–9. Chapter 6 is a joint production. The views expressed belong to the authors alone and not to any organizations with which they are affiliated. The book aims to highlight the strategic relevance of many messages gleaned from scholarly and practitioner analyses of regulation. For a more detailed discussion of a wider range of regulatory issues, scholarship and operational experience see R. Baldwin, M. Cave, and M. Lodge, Understanding Regulation: Theory, Strategy, and Practice (2nd ed., Oxford University Press, 2012). We are grateful to many people for help and advice, including in par ticular: Peter Alexiadis, Sean Ennis, Rob Nicholls, and Tim Tutton. List of Figures and Tables Figures 4.1 Responsive regulation: enforcement pyramid 89 4.2 The GRID (Good Regulatory Intervention Design) 100 6.1 The net zero challenge 142 Tables 1.1 Enabling versus restrictive approaches 7 1.2 The elements of positive regulation 7 2.1 Core regulatory tasks 15 2.2 Hallmarks of the excellent regulator 19 2.3 Winwin possibilities: nine questions 28 3.1 Common nudge tools 45 3.2 Common behavioural limitations 45 3.3 Nudge tools and corporations 48 3.4 Four models of firm 52 4.1 The DREAM framework 70 4.2 Progressions across three stages of risk development 72 4.3 Factors influencing a firm’s compliance motivation 75 4.4 Measures likely to enhance compliance 76 4.5 The Operational Risk Appraisal (Opra) system 77 4.6 Factors driving risk identifications 79 4.7 Impact of compliance strategy on different types of firm 85 4.8 Impact of deterrence strategy on different types of firm 88 4.9 Contrasting styles of prescription—pilot safety 92 4.10 Performance of different formulations of prescription 93 4.11 Types of firm and reactions to principlesbased regulation 95 4.12 Common intervention tools 97 4.13 Firmtypes and the effectiveness of intervention tools 98 4.14 Risk types 99 x List of Figures and Tables 5.1 General arguments in favour of precaution 105 5.2 When the evidence is uncertain: arguments for consumer rather than producer protection 106 5.3 FCA Project Innovate: six initiatives 112 5.4 Innovationenhancing strategies and different types of firm 114 5.5 Changes that may impact on business costs 115 5.6 Processes for managing regulatory changes 116 6.1 Driving change to improve sustainability 136 7.1 Utility value chains by sector 157 7.2 Rate of return and incentive regulation: two approaches 162 7.3 How estimates of the allowed real rate of return (in % per year) in a network sector may diverge 168 8.1 Single and multihoming in the foodordering market and the resulting effect on platform competition 176 8.2 Potential corrections in the ridehailing market 179 9.1 Decisionmaking styles at Oftel 197 1 Positive Regulation Politicians and commentators often protest: ‘Why regulate? Why not leave matters to the market?’ They complain about the restrictiveness of regu la tion, the way that it interferes with economic activity and increases the costs of doing business. They see regulation in negative, ‘red light’, terms— as mainly about stopping healthy entrepreneurial activity. Case in point: Taking the brakes off In July 2015 the UK Government launched an initiative to cut red tape in the energy, waste, agriculture and a number of other sectors. Business Secretary Sajid Javid said: ‘I am determined to take the brakes off British businesses and set them free from heavy-handed regu- lators. The government’s pledge to cut £10 billion in red tape over the course of this parliament will help create more jobs for working people, boost prod uct iv ity and keep our economy growing. For the first time, these reviews will look not only at the rules themselves but the way they are enforced.’ This book adopts a more positive view and argues that regulation is part of the process for creating economic wealth and social welfare. Positive regu la tion is probusiness and prosociety. Using regulation to tame the cor por ation is about harnessing corporate capacities and motivations so as to maximize the excess of benefits over costs—taking both economic and social factors into account. We stress here that regulation has a strong en ab ling, or ‘green light’ role. It is a respectable activity! Laws and regulations, after all, actually enable markets to operate. Property laws are the building blocks that support systems of rights and allow these to be traded in an efficient manner. Without the protections offered by legal rights the actors in markets would have to take other, far more burdensome, steps in order to create the levels of security that would 4 Taming the Corporation induce them to trade.1 Property laws provide readily available, prepackaged and secure regimes for allocating rights, and for enforcing these. They create lowcost frameworks for buying and selling. As Joseph Singer has stressed: ‘Neither private property nor the free market can exist without regulation.’2 There is, accordingly, no opposition between free markets and regu la tion. Laws allow markets to operate. We may object to examples of bad regulation, to controls that impose costs unjustifiably, but these examples make no case for seeing regulation negatively—any more than a few poor meals should lead us to see food as an unnecessary evil. It is also misguided to see markets as processes that somehow exist in states of nature, and which are interfered with by regulators. Markets only exist and sustain over time because there are general laws and more spe cific regulatory regimes that make this possible. Take, for example, the use of radio frequency bands (or spectrum) for mobile telephony. A range of frequencies is divided into segments which can be assigned, traded, and used by companies to supply services to end users. It is the relevant regula tory regime (a mixture of general property laws and more particular laws dealing with telecommunications issues) that makes use of the frequency bands possible in this way and which provides a controlled environment in which the market can operate to the consumer advantage. Regulation, in this context, is logically prior to the market and is enabling. Companies and entrepreneurs need regulation in order to create wealth. A first reason for this is consumer and investor confidence. Few travellers would buy a ticket for a potentially dangerous activity (e.g. travelling by air) unless they felt that there was a regulator whose actions would ensure their safety. When consumers think about buying a pension plan they want to know that there is a competent financial regulator to protect their important investment. For the airlines and the pensions providers, the regulators act to promote the purchase of their products as much as their own marketing divisions. The regulators foster economic activity just as forcefully. On the larger scale, inward investments have to be underpinned by regulatory regimes that create confidence. Take, for example, a train operating company’s decision to spend millions of pounds in setting up its business. Before it invests, that company will want to know that it will have 1 See generally J. Singer, No Freedom Without Regulation (Yale University Press, 2015). 2 Singer, No Freedom Without Regulation, p. 2.