ebook img

Measuring the value of public goods : a new approach with applications to recreational fishing and public utility pricing PDF

142 Pages·2002·6.8 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Measuring the value of public goods : a new approach with applications to recreational fishing and public utility pricing

MEASURING THE VALUE OF PUBLIC GOODS: A NEW APPROACH WITH APPLICATIONS TO RECREATIONAL FISHING AND PUBLIC UTILITY PRICING By DAVID WILLIAM CARTER A DISSERTATION PRESENTED TO THE GRADUATE SCHOOL OF THE UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA IN PARTIAL FULFILLMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR THE DEGREE OF DOCTOR OF PHILOSOPHY UNIVERSITY OF FLORIDA 2002 Copyright 2002 by l)a\id W. Carter ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Several groups and individuals contributed to the development ofthe ideas in this research. First and foremost, I would like to acknowledge the seemingly unending support ofWally Milon and Clyde Kiker. Wally continued to help sculpt my high-flying ideas into manageable research even after moving on from the University ofFlorida. Clyde ensured that didn't loose my interest in high-flying ideas and provided much needed encouragement throughout the ordeal. The other members ofmy Supervisory Committee, especially Bob Emerson, are also to be commended for their timely comments and expert guidance. Next, I would like to implicate my fellow graduate students and the group in 1094, especially Maxwell Mudhara, Bowei Xia, Mike Zylstra, Larry Perruso, Chris DeBodisco and Tom Stevens. These individuals kindly filtered many ofmy early thoughts on this research and provided excellent moral support. Chris DeBodisco, in particular, is to be thanked for his insights and compassion for learning. Last, but not least, I would like to acknowledge the support ofmy friends and family for making the Ph.D. experience an enjoyable chapter in my life. 111 ("ONTEMs \U1 01 I I page MS ACKN0W1 m D(.\ll 1 LIST01 IAH1 is vi is OF FIGURES vii l i ABSTRACT viii (II \piir OVERVIEW 1 1 Revealed Preference Valuation of Public Goods 2 Alternative Approach to Revealed Preference Valuation 4 Potential Applications 4 Audience 5 2 REA Ml NT EFFECTS AS WELFARE MEASURES 6 I I Introduction 6 Structural Approaches to Public Good Valuation 8 Welfare Measures 9 Structural Demand Approaches 1 1 Structural I tilit\ Approaches 15 Combined Structural Approaches and a Canonical Model 20 Critique of Structural Approaches 22 Treatment Effects Approach to Public Good Valuation 25 realment Effect Welfare Measures for Panel Data or Repeated Cross-Sections. 2S I reatment Effect Welfare Measures tor Cross-Section Data 31 I Econometric Framework 34 reatment Effect Welfare Measures J7 I Discussion 44 APPLICATION rORECRJ VTIONA1 FISHING 46 1 \\ elfare Measurement with Capital Expenditures 48 Structural Demand Approach 51 reatment Effects Approach 55 I Data 60 1\ Results 65 Travel Cost Model 65 Treatment Effects Models 68 Discussion 74 4 APPLICATION TO PUBLIC UTILITY PRICING 76 Price Perception and the Value ofPrice Information 77 Empirical Models 85 Water Demand Model 86 Treatment Effects Bill Model 91 Data 95 Results 99 Structural Demand Model 99 Treatment Effects Model 105 Discussion 110 SUMMARY 5 112 APPENDIX MATHEMATICA© DERRIVATION OF THE NET UTILITY FUNCTION 115 REFERENCES 119 BIOGRAPHICAL SKETCH 129 \m i.isi 01 S i i Table page 1 l tilu\ outcomes with activity choice and change combinations 16 2 Spending outcomes with public good use and change combinations 30 3 Sample means and standard deviations for rigs model variables 61 4 Replacement rules tor missing variable cost data 63 5 Spending included in the variable and capital fishing expenditures 64 6 Estimates for the Poisson-normal travel cost model vvith selectivity 67 7 Count model welfare analysis for loss ofrigs access 68 8 Annual variable expenditures treatment effects model results 69 9 Total annual expenditures treatment effects model results 71 10 Annual expenditure treatment effects and welfare estimates ofrig access 73 1 1 Utility outcomes with price knowledge and information change 82 2 Formulas for key model parameters 91 1 3 Rate schedules in study area 97 1 14 Summarv statistics for water demand data 98 5 Watei demand model estimation results 100 1 16 Estimates for kev water demand model parameters 103 17 Monthly bill treatment effects model results 106 15 Bill treatment effects and welfare estimates of price information 109 vi LIST OF FIGURES Figure page 1 The value ofa public good change with interdependence in demand space 12 2 The value ofa public good change with interdependence in utility space 17 3 Expenditure difference threshold 41 4 Value ofprice information: perceived price greater than actual price 84 5 Value ofprice information: perceived price less than actual price 84 vn Abstract of Dissertation Presented to the Graduate School ofthe l fniversit) ofFlorida in Partial Fulfillment ofthe Requirements tor the Degree of Doctor ofPhilosophy MEASURING Mil OF PUBLIC GOODS: ANEWAPPROACH WITH V \l I I APPLICA IONS TO RECREA K >\AI. ISI1ING AND PUBLIC UTILITY PRICING 1 I I By David William Carter December 2002 Chair: J. Walter Milon Cochair: Clyde P. Kiker Department: Pood and Resource Economics Program evaluation (PL) techniques are adapted to measure the value ofpublic good access. The premise is that interventions in the supply ofa public good can be considered "programs' where "use" is tantamount to participation or "treatment." Three chapters (Chapters 2 through 4) explore this premise. Chapter 2 compares the "treatment effects' approach (TEA) to conventional revealed preference (RP) methods for valuing public good access. Program evaluation techniques are adapted to derive access value from differences in related nonmarket activity expenditures between actual and potential public good users. Unlike methods such as the travel cost approach, this approach does not estimate a structural demand or Utility model to derive welfare measures. Thus, the TEA avoids main ofthe wideb recognized problems ofendogeneit) in RP models. A ke> insight is that alternative COUnterfactual assumptions can be used to condition estimates ofthe demand for a public good Mil Chapter 3 applies the TEA to measure the recreational fishing value ofGulfof Mexico petroleum platforms. Those anglers who currently fish at these platforms are the treatment group, while those who fish elsewhere are the controls. An econometric model developed in Chapter 2 is used to obtain a measure ofthe expected value ofplatform access. The measure is relatively comprehensive because the TEA readily incorporates capital expenditures. Results from the TEA model are compared to those from a travel cost model. Chapter 4 examines the conservation value ofa program that informs public utility customers about the price ofservice. An analytical model ofperceived price is developed that can be used to assess the value ofprice information. The corresponding empirical models are built around a dataset ofFlorida water customers that assigns households to treatment and control groups based on whether or not they know the price. The results from demand and treatment effects models are used to derive the expected value ofprice information for an uninformed household. Importantly, the notion of counterfactuals developed in Chapter 2 allows the welfare measures to be adjusted for the possibility that price elasticities change once a household learns the price. IX CHAPTER 1 <)\l KVII \\ he domain ofconsumer choice includes consumed commodities and market I goods \ commodity is valued as a source ofsatisfaction (utility and/or as an input into I the production ofa commodit) that yields satisfaction. A market good is a commodity whose relative social value is given by its price in a forum ofexchange (i.e., a perfectl) competitive market with no externalities). These commodities are excludable and rival, that is. they are (locally) scarce and subject to competition in use. Given nonattenuated property rights for a commodity, the competition over use privileges will establish a price indicative of its relative value as a market good in a Pareto-efficient allocation (Randall 1987). Commodities that are not market goods can be termed nonmarket goods. As commodities, nonmarket goods have value, but the relative value ofadditional units cannot be measured (directly) by an equilibrium market price. There are a number of reasons win a commodit) will not be traded in a perfectly competitive market, but for present purposes the kc\ reason relates to its public good characteristics. Briefly, a public good is nonexclusive and or nonrival in consumption so that a price in use or trade cannot be established because propert\ rights cannot be assigned. Thus, an important difference between market and public goods for consumer choice is the absence ofa consistent indicator of relative \alue or price for the latter. I he lack ofprices for public goods means that other measures must be used to evaluate the relative value ofchanges in the suppl) of these commodities. Such measures 1

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.