ebook img

Classics in the Theory of Public Finance PDF

264 Pages·1958·29.99 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Classics in the Theory of Public Finance

CLASSICS IN THE THEORY OF PUBLIC FINANCE Classics in the Theory of Public Finance Edited by Richard A. Musgrave and Alan T. Peacock M in association with the St. Martin9s Press Palgrave Macmillan o InI~mational Economic A~~ociarion 195K Softcover reprint of the hardcover 1st edition 1958 978-0-333-61355-9 All righ~ ~~rv~d. No reproducrion, copy or trammi~,ion of thi~ publication may be m3de without writt~n penni~,ion. No paragraph of thi~ publication may be reproduc~d, copied or tran~l11itted ~v~ with written I,....m,i~sion or in accordance with thr provi~ion~ of thr Copyright, De~ign~ and l'att'nI. Act 19RK, or under the temlS of any licence permitting limited copying i~ued by the Copyright Licen~ing Agency, 9() Tottenhall1 Court Road, London WlI' 9HE. Any penon who does my un3uthori.ed act in rdation to thi~ publication may be liable to criminal pra.ecution and civil cbim~ for damages. l'ubli~hed in Great Uritain by THE MACMILLAN PRESS LTD HOllndmill~, Ua~in~toke, Hal11p.hire RG21 2XS and London Compani~ and repr~nlariv~~ throughout the world A catalogue record for thi~ book i~ available from the Uritish Libnry. ISBN 978-1-349-23428-8 ISBN 978-1-349-23426-4 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-1-349-23426-4 Antony Rowe Ltd Chippenham, Wilt~hire fint edition 195R Reprinll"d 1961, 19M, 1967 (with new I'rl·f.,ce), 1994 (with new I,r .. f.,u) I'ubli~hed in th .. United Sl3te~ of Americ. by Scholarly and Reference Divi.ion, ST. MARTIN'S PRESS, INC., 175 Fifth Avenue, New York, N.Y. 11)(111l ISBN 978-0-312-12162-4 Library of Congr~' Cataloging-in-Publication Data CIa~,ic~ in the theory of public finance / edited by Richard A. Mu'gr:tve and Alan T. I'eacock. p. cm. Include~ bibliographical referrnc~ and index. ISBN 978-0-312-12162-4 I. Finance, Pllblic-tli~tory. I. Mu~ve, Richard Abel, 1910- II. Peacock, Abn T. 1922- 1IJ14l.C55 1994 336-<fc2() 94-115R CII' CONTENTS l'ag~ Preface VII Preface to the Fourth Impression Vlll Preface to the Fifth Impression IX Introduction RICHARD A. MUSGRAVE and ALAN T. PEACOCK xm Three Extracts on Public Finance ADOLPH WAGNER Contribution to the Theory of the Distribution of Public Expenditure MAFFEO PANTALEONI 16 On Taxation LORENZ VON STEIN 28 The Formation of the Prices of Public Goods UGO MAZZOLA 37 On Progressive Taxation ARNOLD JACOB COHEN STUART 48 A New Principle of Just Taxation KNUT WICKSELL 72 The Pure Theory of Taxation FRANCIS YSIDRO EDGEWORTH 119 The Fundamental Principles of a Pure Theory of Public Finance GIOVANNI MONTEMARTINI 137 On Taxation in General PAUL LEROY-BEAULIEU 152 On Public Needs ENRICO BARONE 165 Just Taxation - A Positive Solution ERIK LINDAHL 168 The Valuation Theory of Taxation EMIL SAX 177 A Theory of the Public Economy FRIEDRICH VON WIESER 190 A Sociological Approach to Problems of Public Finance RUDOLF GOLDSCHEID 202 Some Controversial Questions in the Theory of Taxation ERIK LINDAHL 214 Communal Economy and Market Economy HANS RITSCHL 233 Index of Names 243 PREFACE For some forty years, beginning about 1880, a lively debate on one of the central problems in welfare economics took place between Continental writers on public fmance. This problem was concerned with the optimum distribution of resources between the government and the private sector, and with the ideal means of taxing individuals so that resources could be put at the disposal of the state. The debate absorbed the energies of Austrian, French, German, and Swedish writers, and made the reputation on the con tinent of the Italian writers on public fmance. It would be interesting to speculate on the reasons for the neglect of these writers in the English-speaking world, were it not that so many other writers in the field of economic theory encountered similar treatment. We may be sure, however, that this neglect has meant that Anglo-Saxon economics has suffered in consequence. More over, this seems an appropriate moment to introduce some of this largely forgotten work, because controversy on welfare economics in English language journals has recently turned to the problem of the pricing of public goods, albeit rather belatedly. In the present volume, we cannot do more than provide a sample of the voluminous literature on the subject. However, it can be claimed that the writings of no important school of thought have been omitted. We have tried to assist the reader in the understanding of the evolution of the debate by means of an Introduction. The arrangement of material which seems best suited to clarify the pattern of the debate is a chronological one. It is true that this arrangement results in the placing of the work of Sax almost to the end of the period of debate instead of establishing his right to be one of the pioneers of the application of utility analysis to public expenditure. However, we have preferred to print Sax's final thoughts on the subject and to discuss his earlier work in our Introduction. We feel also that our approach demands the inclusion of the famous dis cussion ofjustice and taxation by Edgeworth, although this is already available in English. The editors are indebted to many people who have helped in selecting and translating the essays here presented, and in permitting their reproduction. In particular, thanks are due to Professor James Buchanan of the University of Virginia, for his assistance in the Italian selections. Our only regret is that so much good material had to be omitted, reflecting no doubt the pains of social choice which are the basic subject of this volume. THE EDITORS PREFACE TO THE FOURTH IMPRESSION The first (1958) edition of this 'York was prepared mainly for specialists on the assumption that itwould provide the background to an important neglected field of'discussion in public finance. Since that date, the theory of public goods and its implications for public policy has become incorporated in the main body of the economic analysis of public fmance in the Anglo-Saxon literature. A glance at the footnotes of rome of the standard textbooks on public fmance indicates that this assembly of articles has not been in vain. Indeed, the first edition has already been reprinted twice, and now seems the appropriate time to make the work available as a paperback also. Probably the most influential part of this collection has been the theory of public expenditUre, which contains two closely related elements. The first is as a part of welfare economics: under what conditions, if any, can Pareto opti mality be achieved in an economic system in which some goods supplied are indivisible! This question has been considered very thoroughly in recent years with due attention paid to the earlier work ofWicksell and Lindahl in particular. The other strand of thought is concerned with the positive theory of the public sector: how can we use economic analysis in order to explain how the size and composition of the budget is actually determined! This is a much more difficult question to answer because it entails the development of a theory of collective action. While there is less evidence of fundamental thinking on this question in this work, it is perhaps of interest to note that, since it first appeared, Erik Lindahl in one of his last appearances in print, has offered some interesting observations on this second element exactly forty years after the appearance of Die Gerichtigkeit der Besteuerung (1). The essence of his contribution is an attempt to employ utility theory, as developed in his earlier work, to explain the size composition of the Swedish budget during the twentieth century. Lindahl also showed in this contribution that he was fully familiar with recent work outside Sweden which stemmed from his own earlier contributions. There is a lesson to be learnt from this when one considers how long it has taken for him and his contemporaries to receive the attention which was denied them in the past. THE EDITORS (1) "Omskatteprincipcrochskattepolitik", El!#nonli Politile Samluillt, Festkrift till Berti! Ohlins 6o-hsdag, Stockholm, 1959, pp. 151-171. .This paper is available: in an English translation by T. L. Johnston in l>ttmu~tiotuJI &otwmic Papns, No. 10, pp. 7-2.3. PREFACE TO THE FIFTH IMPRESSION Neither of the editors envisaged that, thirty-five years after the first appear ance of this work, the publishers would invite us to re-introduce it. Their reason must be that scholars and their students may still find it useful not simply to have the work in the nearest library but even on their book shelf. That being so, it is arguable whether a further preface is needed when the interest of those consulting the work presumably still lies in the classical literature rather than further commentary. Nevertheless, it may be of interest to consider how f.u Classics stands up to the tests set by the scope and method of public finance theory, as it is taught and practised today, for there have been major changes since we first compiled this collection. The first major change is that the teaching of public finance has become throughly integrated with the standard body of micro theory and relabelled "public economics". Following general practice in academic economics, much of the :malysis is presented in more rigorous and mathematical form, along with empirical testing by econometric methods. The remaking of incidence analysis in general equilibrium models offers a good example. The computer revolution has not stopped short of public finance. At the same time, increased emphasis on technique has tended to crowd out the history of economic thought as an integral part of economic training and concern. Public finance has been no exception, as is testified by the contemporary contents of its leading journals, but it has not been affected to quite the same extent. One reason for this is that the economics content of the training of political scientists and public administrators has been increased, and public finance represents a major element in this change. These fields of enquiry are more sympathetic to and possibly more dependent on the study of the evolution of ideas and there is much in the history of fiscal thought which would be consonant with such an approach. A further reason is that major new developments in the content of the economics of public finance have derived some of their inspiration from a reconsideration of the work of past genera tions, including some of their contributions in this volume. As it happens, prominent authors of the past who form this link with present ideas were no slouches when it came to mathematical formulation, for example Wicksell and Edgeworth. Looking back, we must plead guilty with regard to two omissions, papers which had appeared prior to the first publication of this volume (1 958). As is evident from this later perspective, Ramsey's classic contribution on the theory of taxation (1 927) should have been included since it had laid the basis for the theory of optimal taxation which was to blossom fifty years later. Samuelson's classic piece on the pure theory of expenditures (1954) should also have been part of these pages, since it formally integrated budget activity into the framework of welf.1re economics. · X PREE4CE TO THE FIFTH IMPRESSION This brings us to the second major change which, as already hinted at, refers to the content of the economics of public finance itself. The subject of public choice in which economic analysis of human behaviour has penetrated the study of electoral systems, legislative procedures and bureaucratic action has burgeoned (for excellent commentary, see Mueller (1989)). The influence of both normative and positive public choice analysis with its wider perspective has been profound and a revised edition of this volume would call for additional material to show its historical roots. Nevertheless, we can at least claim that Classics offers a starting point for examining the historical origins of public choice theory, notably in the contributions of Lindahl, Wagner and, of course, Wicksell, which are frequently cited in the present-day literature. But judged from a contemporary standpoint, public choice theorists anxious to widen the perspective of their students would clearly wish to add such authors as Condorcet, de Tocqueville, Puviani, to mention only those whose work did not appear in English. Following our own precedent of including Edgeworth, in order to preserve historical balance, one would have to extend this list to include, amongst others, excerpts from Hobbes, Locke, Hume, Smith, Charles Dodgson (Lewis Carroll) and Black. The third major change is represented by the revival of the utilitarian theory of taxation. It will be recalled that Edgeworth presented an elegant demon stration of the proposition, already advanced by Bentham, that if the marginal utility of income falls as income rose (assuming interpersonal comparability and similar utility functions), then the utilitarian goal of least total sacrifice or maximum welfare would require the government to equalize income: "(t)he acme of socialism is thus for a moment sighted; but it is immediately clouded over by doubts and reservations" (loc.cit.). He accepted that as well as the need to minimize disincentive effects of taxation, practical difficulties, such as tax evasion, and other policy objectives, would severely modify any policy conclu sions that his analysis suggested. The present-day theory of optimal income taxation is essentially a more explicit version of Edgeworth's model and his caveats, so Classics is still useful for those interested in its origins. Optimal t.1x theory also extends to the formulation of rules for the imposition of commodity taxes. Here the matter to be resolved is the extent to which efficiency criteria requiring the taxing of commodities with low price elasticity conflict with utilitarian equity criteria which entail lessening the overall tax burden of the lower income groups. (For a useful summary of optimal taxation and policy issues, see Heady (1993).) This model of optimal taxation remains to be reconciled with earlier views which defined good taxation in terms of horizontal and vertical equity rules. Although conscious of the gaps in the literature which are still to be filled, yet not anxious to embark on another expedition down the highways and PRET-ACE JD THE FIFTH IMPRESSION XI byways of the history of economics, perhaps other work of the editors may help anyone who should wish to supplement the contributions reprinted in this volume. Musgrave's "A Brief History of Fiscal Doctrine" (1985), as the title suggests, gives a conspectus of the history of the subject in the span of fifty pages and contains over 15 0 references, a large proportion being works before 1900. In a more specialized contribution Peacock (1992) has raised the question as to whether the study of the history of fiscal thought is a necessary element in the training of public economists, illustrating his answer with references to those thinkers interested in explaining the causes and consequences of the growth in public expenditure. The reader of these works should be warned, however, that as well as being possibly useful as works of reference, the editors are still out to persuade the reader that the hi~tory of fiscal thought is both fascinating and important. Analytical developments since they first met forty years ago have not diminished their enthusiasm for preaching this lesson! THE EnnoRs References Christoph~r H~ady, "Optimal Taxation a~ a Guid~ to Tax Policy", Fi.(atl Studies, Vol. 14, No. 1, F~bruary 1993, pp. 15-41. D~nnis C. Mu~ll~r. Public Clrc>ire II (Cambridge Univ~rsity Pre~~. 191!9). Richard A. Musgrav~. "A Urief Hi~tory of Fi~cal Doctrine", in A. J. Auerbach and M. Feldstein (~ds), llmrdbc>ok C!f Public Errmc>~rric.( (EI~evier, 191!5), reprinted as Chapter 23 in Richard A. Mmgrave, Public Firrarrce irr a Democratic Sc>ciety: Volume II (Whea~heaf), pp. 331!-393. Alan T. Peacock, Public Clrc>icc Arralysis irr Hi.llc>rical Past'atir~·. Mattioli Lecture~. Cambridge University Pre~~. 1992. F. Rams~y. "A Contribution to th~ Theory ofT.1xation", r:twrc>micJ.,rrrra/, 37, 1927. Paul A. Samuel~on, "The Pure Theory of Public Expenditures", Re11h11' C!f Ecc>rromirs arrd Sllltistirs, 1954, pp. 3R6-3R9.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.