ebook img

Categories in Use PDF

270 Pages·2006·5.252 MB·1-267\270
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Categories in Use

RELATIONS AND CATEGORIES Viviana A. Zelizer andCharles Tilly I. Introduction Duringthelate1990s,ateamofFrenchsocialresearchersledbyJean‐Michel Servetinvestigatedwhatwasthenarapidlyspreadingformoforganizationin France:theSyste`mesd’E´changeLocal(SEL).Theyconductedclosestudiesof these proliferating local money groups in a number of urban and rural communities.Annie,amemberofalocalmoneycircleinthePyrenees,told themhow‘‘Intheregularsystem,Ihavecash,Ipay,Iamfree;intheSEL,Iam notfree,Iforgearelation.’’Similarly,Ya60‐year‐oldretireefromtheSELof la Garrigue reported: ‘‘The exchange [within the SEL] inevitably leads to somethingelse,whilewhenIgivesomeonea100francnote,Ihandhimthe 100 franc note and it’s over. There we discuss what’s going on, politics, the economy,theSEL’’(Servet,1999,p.144). Annie and Y clearly see a sharp diVerence between economic transactions occurring inside and outside the SEL. That boundary between insiders and outsidersmatters.Itmattersbothbecausepeopleoneithersideoftheboundary havediVerentrelationstoeachotherandbecausewhenmembersoftheSEL crosstheboundarytointeractwithoutsiderstheychangetheirownbehavior. The boundary, as members describe it, separates a local world of authentic interpersonalsolidarityfromanotherworldtaintedbycommercialism. Parallelmonetarysystemshaveexistedsincetheinventionofmoneymillen- niaago.Thedistinctionbetween‘‘real’’money—legaltenderbackedbygov- ernments—and alternative currencies took on serious consequences when THEPSYCHOLOGYOFLEARNING Copyright2007,ElsevierInc. ANDMOTIVATIONVOL.47 1 Allrightsreserved. DOI:10.1016/S0079-7421(06)47001-8 0079-7421/07$35.00 2 ZelizerandTilly statesbeganestablishingmonopoliesofmonetaryproductionduringthenine- teenthcentury(Helleiner,1999).Butanideologicallytingedworldwidemove- ment to create alternative local currencies of superior moral value only took rootduringthe1980sandbegansproutingaroundtheglobeduringthe1990s. Yet the movement grew fast. In his comprehensive survey of SEL‐like localcurrencies,Je´roˆmeBlancestimates250,000membersofsuchorganiza- tions across the world in the year 2000 (Blanc, 2000, p. 243). As of 2001, a semioYcialinternationalwebsitelistsover1500groups(Lets‐Linkup,2005). In one place afteranother on allthe inhabitedcontinents, peopleare draw- ing boundaries and creating consequential insider–outsider categories by establishing local monetary systems. Local money provides just one example of a much more general process. In a wide variety of situations, people engaged in everyday social interac- tionestablishboundariesbetweeninsidersandoutsidersthatsustaincrucial socialactivities.Thoseboundariesthencreateconsequentialconnectedcate- gories—not only insiders and outsiders but also us and them, worthy and unworthy, intimate and impersonal, congenial and threatening. To be sure, generalcognitiveprocessesaVectperceptionanduseofthosecategories.But thecategoriesthemselvesemergefromsocialinteraction,andtheircontents depend on social interaction (Tilly, 2005b; Zelizer, 2005). This chapter pursues that insight, first within the zone of money and then outside. We return to local monies for a closer look, then move on to parallels with legal tender, including a perplexing new currency, the euro. Immigrant remittances provide a doorway into related phenomena, in this case still mainly monetary, but now involving long‐distance and long‐term creation ofcategories through complex social interaction. Fromimmigrantremittanceswe turntoother formsofcategorycreation inwhichmoneyoccupiesalesscentralplace:interpersonalnetworksoftrust and relations between nationalism and citizenship. Each case illuminates a diVerentaspect ofa general argument: (cid:1) Socialinteractiongenerates,informs,andthenrespondstoasignificant set of connected categories. (cid:1) Those categories depend on interaction among three elements: (1) socially maintained boundaries, (2) relations within the boundaries, and (3) relationsacross theboundaries. (cid:1) Theyregularlyinvolvementalaccountingsystems,ofwhichshort‐term quid pro quo exchanges constitute onlyone special type. (cid:1) People complement mental accounting systems with earmarking prac- tices;theyestablishsubdivisionswithinostensiblyhomogeneousmoney andothermediabysignalingcommitmentofmediasegmentstodistinct relations and transactions. RelationsandCategories 3 (cid:1) Relational work—the eVort of establishing, terminating, negotiating, and transforming interpersonal relations—goes on continuously, shap- ing boundaries, accounting systems, and categories. By the end we hope to have established not that all categories result from interpersonal interactions, much less that all categories are somehow essen- tially social, but that coherent social processes regularly generate, deploy, and alteran important set ofhuman categories. II. Local Money FromtheFrench‘‘graindesel’’andtheAustralian‘‘greendollars’’totheItalian ‘‘Mistho`s,’’theGermanTalent,theMexicanTlaloc,theArgentine‘‘cre´ditos,’’ theJapanese‘‘ecomoney,’’orthe‘‘Seeds’’ofMendocino,California,localcur- rencies mark geographically circumscribed economies (see Helleiner, 1999, 2000; Powell, 2002; Rizzo, 1999; Schr oeder, 2002;S ervet, 1999; YenRivals, 2001). These c urrenc ies belong to wel‐lor ga ni ze d, lo ca liz ed , a n d vo lu nt ar y groups that go by names such as SEL, local exchange and trading systems (LETS),BancadelTempo(Bdt),SistemadiReciprocita` Indiretta(SRI),Club delTrueque,Tauschring,andHOURS. In all this bewildering variety of monetary groups, people are building categoriesthatinsulateinternaloperationsoftheirsystemfromthekindsof economic activities that go on outside. They do so via a series of elements: theymarkaboundarydistinguishinglifeinsideandoutside,assigncontrast- ing meanings to those worlds, use a distinctive idiom for their internal exchanges, set up tailor‐made accounting systems, adopt media to repre- sent those accounting systems, and establish a limited set of transactions among members. All this amounts to the construction of connected cate- goriesseparatinginsidersfromoutsiders.Relationalworkwithlocalmoney createsnewcategories. Of course, the process varies in diVerent kinds of local money groups. Discussionsoflocalmoneyoftenmention,andsometimesconfuse,fourrather diVerent phenomena: pegged currencies, time exchanges, commodity‐based systems, and barter. Pegged currencies, as in the SEL or LETS, establish a distinct local medium whose value corresponds to that of legal tender. Time exchanges, such as New York’s pioneering Ithaca HOURS, take their value fromhoursofeVortcontributedbytheirmembers.Commodity‐basedsystems involvecoupons,vouchers,andcreditsthatareultimatelyredeemableonlyin certainearmarkedgoodsorservices.Barterincludesdirectexchangeofgoods and services for each other without intervention of a currency. Although combinations of all four systems appear here and there, the overwhelming 4 ZelizerandTilly majorityofdeliberatelyorganizedlocalmonetarysystemsfallintherangeof thefirsttwo,frompeggedcurrenciestotimeexchanges. For illustration, we focus here on the world’s most widespread system: LETS. LETS members transfer goods and services using a locally circum- scribedmedium,ordinarilypeggedtoanationalcurrency.Atleasttwomajor variantsofLETSexist.Somecreatetokenstorepresenttheircurrency,while othersrelyontelephone‐linkedorcomputer‐basedcentralaccountswithout physicaltokens.Participantsgenerallypayanentrancefeeandsubscribetoa servicelistingavailablegoodsandservicesprovidedbymembersofagroup. Buyersandsellerscontacteachotherandnegotiateaprice;theirtransaction isthenrecordedbythelocalLETSoYce. Althoughsome enthusiastsfortheselocalarrangementsimaginetheyare doingawaywithmoneyentirely,infacttheyarecreatingnewformsofmoney devotedtodistinctivegroups.AsServetandhiscollaboratorsnote,theSEL areinsearchofa‘‘goodmoney’’(bonnemonnaie)(Servet,1999,p.12). How do members of these groups distinguish themselves and their rela- tions from others outside? As we saw with Annie and Y, participants draw emphatic boundaries between themselves and a diVuse commercial world. The groups’ self‐descriptions commonly emphasize this distinction between aninsideworldofsociablesolidarityandanoutsideworldofself‐interested commercialism. Language further marks that divide: LETS enthusiasts discourage partici- pantsfromusingtraditionaleconomicterminology,suchas‘‘price,’’‘‘money,’’ or ‘‘sales,’’ referring instead to ‘‘estimated amounts,’’ ‘‘units,’’ ‘‘favours,’’ or ‘‘exchanges’’(Blanc,2000,p.261;Servet,1999,pp.28–30;Taris,2005).Indeed, theeVortofManchesterLETSorganizerstointegratetheirexchangesextensively intothenationaleconomyoutragedotherBritishLETSorganizers.Criticsofthe Manchesterplan,KeithHart(1999,283)reports,preferred‘‘sealingoVamore wholesomekindofcircuitfromthecontaminationofcapitalism.’’ LETS participants regularly draw additional, very diVerent boundaries between themselves and their intimates. Nonmember lovers, close friends, and family members belong to a separate set of relations from their LETS partners.DenisBayon,aninvestigatorattheUniversityofLyon,comments: One may, of course, fall in love in a SEL (as elsewhere) or make friends; but then the romanticorfriendlyrelationshipbreaksoutoftheSELdomain;acouple,friends,certainly don’tcounttheservicestheyprovideforeachother,whichfromnowonbelongtotheir privatelifeandcouldhavebeen,inothercircumstances,exchangesmediatedbytheSEL. (Bayon,1999,p.61fn.1) Thedistinctionalsooperatesintheotherdirection.Whenfriendsbecome LETSpartners,theyredefinetheirrelationships.Inherinterviewswithlocal RelationsandCategories 5 money participants in Ontario and New York state, Mary‐Beth Raddon foundrespondentsstrugglingtoreadjusttheirpersonalrelationstothenew LETS media for their ongoing transactions. She reports, for instance, one mother’suneasytransitionfromfreebabysittingforfriendstoalocalmoney system. As Erinexplained: Youknow,Iwouldwatchmyfriend’schildandshewouldwatchmine,andwesortofkept trackofthehourssothatwewereeven,butoncewewerebothmembersofLETSwe’d always pay each other in green [dollars]. But there was a change that happened once a currencygotattachedtoitthatmadeitfeelabitdiVerent,sortofmoreformalizedandless acurrencyoffriendship.(Raddon,2003,p.79) Establishingboundariesbetweenthemselvesandthevarious‘‘them’’out- sidethegroup,however,isonlypartofthecategory‐buildingsocialprocess. LETS participants further solidify their internal connections by marking their own economic activities and relations as distinctive. They do so most notablybycreatingspecializedmediaandaccountingsystems,aswellasby control ofmembership, transactions,and commodities. Participants often reinforce their community by incorporating locally meaningful symbols into their monetary tokens. LETS networks that do notrelyonphysicallydistinctmediausesymbolicallychargednames,usually with transparent local meaning. In Britain, for instance, Greenwich uses ‘‘anchors,’’ Canterbury ‘‘tales,’’ and Totnes ‘‘acorns’’ (Helleiner, 2000, pp.46–47).InFrance,thePyre´ne´esSELuses‘‘grains,’’‘‘cailloux’’servethe Lyon Croix‐Rousse SEL, while the ‘‘fil’’ circulates in the textile region of Sailly‐surla‐Lys,PasdeCalais(Blanc,2000,p.265). How do LETS regulate their membership? Although almost anyone can sign up, once inside the group new members enter into a particular set of relations, and must agree to abide by certain standards that distinguish insiders from outsiders. For instance, item 18 in the Lyon‐Croix‐Rousse SEL’s‘‘Charted’adhe´sion’’states:‘‘Exclusionofaparticipantwhosebehav- ior contradicts the good functioning of the SEL constitutes a right of the generalassembly’’(Servet,1999,p.30).LETSgroupsfortifytheirdistinctive economic world by regulating transactions across boundaries. LETS cur- rency,forinstance,isnotconvertibleintolegaltender.Indeed,anymember whochargeslegaltender,ratherthanthelocalcurrency,ascompensationfor servicesor goods,breaks a crucialrule (Servet,1999, p.59). Although no one has looked comparatively at the composition of local monetary systems in detail, available descriptions leave the impression that they tend to be socially homogeneous. Internal diVerences in participation by age and gender (see, e.g., Raddon, 2003) do not significantly qualify that impression. All such systems restrict participation in some regards. 6 ZelizerandTilly In Germany some Tauschring circuits confine their membership to the elderly, the handicapped, foreigners, or women. Others expand their circuit to include whol e communi ties or firms (Pierret, 1999). Even those, howeve r, remain radically delimited as compared to thescopeof legal tender. Localmoneysystemsalsorestrictthecommoditiestheycover.Althoughthe range of goods and services ranges widely, including such items as clothing, farm tools, and food, as well as foreign‐language instruction, gym courses, plumbing, gardening, babysitting, and computer support, not all are fit to circulate.Forinstance,manySELgroupsbantransfersofcertaingoodsand servicesasmorally,ecologically,orpoliticallyoV‐limits.Bannedcommodities include firearms, animals, goods manufactured by third‐world exploitation, and in one case a member’s book on ‘‘how to get rich quick’’ (Bayon, 1999, pp.73–74).Bayonreports: OneoftheSELmadeaninterestingspecificationconcerningmassages.Aninternaldocu- mentdistinguisheseroticmassages(growingoutofmembers’personalrelations),therapeu- tic massages (that require the intervention of qualified professionals, eligible for social security reimbursement and exchanges in national currency), and massagesdesigned for generalwell‐beingandrelaxation.(Bayon,1999,pp.73–74) The first two kinds of massage, according to Bayon, are forbidden, the third acceptable. More generally, this SEL favored treatment by means of alternative medicines. Whenitcomestopricinggoodsandservicestheyexchange,localtrading systems commonly reject existing market prices for their own negotiated tariVs.Oftenthelocalpricereflectsthegroup’sgreaterevaluationofservices that,inthemembers’estimation,thenationalmarketundervalues.Inapara- doxical turn, for instance, household and caring tasks, typically women’s laborexcludedordevaluedbythemainstreameconomy,findanappreciative market within the SEL (Helleiner, 2000,p. 44;Raddon,2003). What is more, apparently equivalent goods and services fetch diVerent prices depending on the parties’ evaluation of the relationship. In a report from the Centre Walra s, Etienne Perrot (1999, p. 386) notes: ‘‘The personal - ityoftheproviderandtheaVectivedimensionofSELrelationshipsleadthe ‘client’ to pay a friend’s price (prix d’ami) independent of strict economic calculation.’’ Similarly, Bayon observes: Wedonotsetagainsteachotherthehoursofbaby‐sitting,orthehoursofreadingstoriesto children....It’sJean‐Paulmyneighborwhowatchedmychildyesterday,it’sHe´le`newho cametoread‘‘scarystories’’tomyyoungchildren,etc.AtthecoreofSELs...wefind chains of exchange and solidarity mixing and interweaving with each other as invisible threadsdesigningthecommongood.It’sJacqueswhotellsFranc¸oiseheneedssomeoneto helphimwithhousework,orpreciselyFranc¸oiseknowsPierrewhowashelpedbyLuc,etc. It’speoplewhojoinintosharechores.(Bayon,1999,pp.80–81) RelationsandCategories 7 As a result, Bayon continues: Thestructureof‘‘prices’’inSELcurrencywouldmakeanordinaryeconomistscream.The ‘‘same’’ (but precisely it is not the same) hour of ironing gives us here 50 grains, there, 60grains,here40grains,etc.Anoversizednewpairofshoesboughtbymistakewillbe givenherefor100grains,there150grains.(Bayon,1999,p.81) By the same token, SEL members, according to Bayon, reject prices that seem morally excessive to them, regardless of the amount that the good or servicewouldbringinnationalcurrencyoutsidethecircuit(seealsoRaddon, 2003).Evenlocalmoneysystemsthatpegtheircurrenciestolegaltenderthus createtheirownaccountingschemestoaccommodatesettingofvalueswithin themembership. All over the world, then, people are building distinctive social arrange- ments around parallel monetary systems. Each system begins with a well‐ marked boundary between inside and outside, diVerentiates the sorts of transactions that occur inside and outside, uses distinct accounting systems inside and outside, labels and evaluates inside and outside relations diVer- ently, and assigns diVerent meanings to the combinations of accounting systems, monetary media, transactions, and relations on either side of the boundary. Inso doing, they constructnew, powerful, connected categories. Moregenerally,foreachmeaningfullydistinctcategoryofsocialrelations, people erect a boundary, mark the boundary by means of names and prac- tices,establishasetofdistinctiveunderstandingsandpracticesthatoperate within that boundary, designate certain sorts of economic transactions as appropriate for the relation, bar other transactions as inappropriate, and adopt certain media for reckoning and facilitating economic transactions within the relation (for social boundary processes, see Abbott, 1995; Barth, 1969,1981;Epstein,1992;Fuller,2003;Lamont&Molnar,2002;Ong,1996; Sanders, 2002; Tilly, 2005b). All these eVorts belong to relational work: establishmentofdiVerentiatedsocialties,theirmaintenance,theirreshaping, theirdistinctionfromotherrelations,andsometimestheirtermination.They createsocialboundaries,relationswithintheboundaries,relationsacrossthe boundaries,andmeaningfulcategoriesdistinguishingpersons,activities,and relationsondiVerentsidesoftheboundaries. III. Legal Tenders Impressively parallel processes occur as people use legal tender. For all the assumption of community money enthusiasts that they are building a dis- tinct world from the crass, insipid, homogenized sphere of legal tender, in fact the same kindof relational work goeson within that other sphere, and 8 ZelizerandTilly hassincetheinventionofmoney.Ironically,managersoflegaltendercreate a mirror image of local money’s categories. They distinguish their genuine money and its economic sphere from corrupt, incomplete, improvised, and ineYcientapproximationstomoney.Withthebackingofanationalgovern- ment,genuinemoneythusdefinedtakesontheauraofpatriotism.Aswewill see, exactly where the boundary lies and who backs the money become categorical problems with such transnational currency asthe euro. The very creation of uniform national currencies involved an extensive process of social reorganization. Contrary to the presumption that eYcient money automatically follows the expansion of markets, national states worked vigorously to impose standardized national forms of money. Start- ing in the nineteenth century, the US government struggled to replace multiple circulating monies with a uniform currency. It did so by taxing thousandsofstate‐issuedpapercurrenciesoutofexistence,banningforeign currencies; suppressing the private issue of tokens, paper notes, or coins by stores, businesses, churches, and other organizations; and stamping out the personalizationofmoneybyindividuals(Helleiner,2003;Zelizer,1994). Standardizationofmoney,however,didnotproceedsmoothlyandconsen- sually.DefiningAmericancurrencybecameoneofthelatenineteenthcentury’s mostexplosivepoliticalandsocialissues.Despiteadramaticpost–CivilWar increaseinpeople’suseofdepositsrather than cash,the debatescenteredon currencies.Weregreenbacks‘‘real’’money,ordidonly‘‘hard’’metallicmoney serveasauthenticcurrency?Shouldgold,asmonometallistsargued,betheonly ‘‘true’’standard?Or,couldsilver,as‘‘freesilver’’proponentsmaintained,serve asequallysoundmoney?Werenotesissuedbynationalbankslegitimate?Or,as Greenbackersinsisted,wasonlygovernment‐issuedmoneyacceptable?These were not merely word games or strictly technical distinctions; the ‘‘money question’’becameafiercelycontestedpublicdebate,polarizingsocialgroups andshapingthepoliticalprocessoflatenineteenth‐centuryAmericansociety. By the turn of the century, controversy began to wane in the United States. Free‐silver proponents lost the 1896 election and the 1900 Gold StandardActestablishedthegolddollarasthenationalmonetarystandard. Within some four decades, the American state had achieved a significant degreeofmonetarystandardization.Notuntil1933,however,didCongress formallydeclareallUScoinsandcurrenciestobeequallegaltender(Zelizer, 1994, pp. 13–18). The state moved as well against the personalization of money by indivi- duals. It broadened definitions of counterfeiting and mutilation, pursuing, for instance, the popular late nineteenth‐century trompe l’oeil paintings of dollar bills. The government even forbade the common late nineteenth‐ century practice of inscribing coins with sentimental messages, calling that practice ‘‘mutilation.’’ After 1909, a law forbidding the mutilation of RelationsandCategories 9 coins turned the popular ‘‘love token’’ gifts into an illegal currency. As the SupremeCourtofIndianadeclaredinNovember1889,thegovernment‘‘has arighttoprovideacurrencyforthewholenation,andtodriveoutallother circulatingmediumsbytaxationorotherwise’’(Hancocketal.v.Yaden366 Supreme Court ofIndiana at 372). It was a losing battle. Although the American state did achieve a sig- nificant degree of standardization and monopolization of legal tender, peo- ple continually disrupted monetary uniformity, actively creating all sorts of monetary distinctions. In a remarkableparallelto the formation of local monetary communities, people created distinctive uses of legal tender that corresponded to diVerent sets of social relations. They did relational work withlegaltender.Theydidsobyasetofearmarkingpractices:treatmentsof money that signal the nature of the relationship between the parties to a particular kind of transaction. Earmarkingclearlyqualifiesasrelationalwork.Techniquesofearmarking include three main varieties: 1. Establishing social practices that sort otherwise identical media into distinct categories. Depending on how it is used, when, and most importantlyforwhattypeofsocialrelation,thesamephysicallyindis- tinguishable medium (e.g., dollar or a euro) can serve as a wage, a bonus, a tip, a gift, an allowance, charity, or a remittance. Each calls fora diVerent set of routines representing its character. 2. Asinthecaseoflocalmonies,creationofsegmentedmediaintheform of tokens, coupons, scrip, chits, food stamps, aYnity credit cards, money orders, vouchers, or gift certificates, which are appropriate for restrictedsetsofrelationsandtransfers,andinmanycasesarenotlegal tender within the larger economy. 3. Transformationofselectedobjectsintomonetarymedia,aswithcigarettes, postagestamps,subwaytokens,pokerchips,orbaseballcards. In each case, earmarking calls up its own mental accounting system, for example,separatingrentmoney(keptinacheckingaccount)fromgiftmoney (keptinaChristmasClubaccount).Theprocessofearmarkingmoniesisnot only complex and constant but often also highly contested. Disputes arise when parties to an interaction have contradictory understandings of the relationship, when their values clash, or when they are pursuing conflicting interests.TheyalsoarisewhenthepartieshaveadopteddiVerenttechniques forearmarking,especiallywhenthepreferredtechniquesofonepartymean somethingdiVerentandundesirabletotheotherparty. Such practices connect with psychological work on mental accounting. Studiesofthesubjectgenerallyrejectthenotionthatmoneyispsychologically general,maintainingthatinsteadmoneyinvolves‘‘multiplesymbolizations.’’ 10 ZelizerandTilly An important literature on mental accounting challenges economists’ assumptionoffungibilitybyidentifyingthewaysthatindividualsdistinguish between kinds of money. For instance, people treat windfall income much diVerentlyfromabonusoraninheritance,evenwhenthesumsinvolvedare identical(see,e.g.,Heath&Soll,1996;Kahneman&Tversky,1982;McGraw, Tetlock,&Kristel,2003;Thaler,1999).Mentalaccountingturnsouttobea psychological earmarking mechanism, in this case a particular treatment of moneythatfitsspecificcognitivecategories. Related work points to the behavioral impact of ‘‘money illusions’’ by whichpeopleadoptaseriesoflocalizedconventionsforevaluatingmonetary transactions in diVerent situations rather than translating them into the economists’neutral,fungiblemedium(see,e.g.,Shafir,Diamond,&Tversky, 1997).PoliticalscientistRobertE.Lane(1991)hasalsodocumentedawide varietyofwaysinwhichAmericansthinkofmoneyasvariable,ameaningful symbol of attitudinal feelings such as personal inadequacy, loss of control, shamefulfailure,security,orneedofsocialapproval. There are two ways—cognitive and relational—of interpreting what is goingonwiththesemonetaryearmarkingpractices:twodistinguishableyet interdependent processes. One sees monetary variations as mental distinc- tionsorcognitivemaps.TheotherseesmonetarydiVerentiationasmarking andemergingfromdistinctivesocialrelationsandsharedmeaningsystems.In the latter, money’s variations do not just symbolize but in fact serve to construct social relations. They become means of relational work. Thus, social scientists are not simply reporting sophisticated individual budgetary strategies but identifying the significance of monetary practices as out- comes, contents, and origins of social relations. Both processes—cognitive andsocial—areofcoursegoingon.Therelationalworkofestablishinglegal tender creates social boundaries, relations within the boundaries, relations across the boundaries, and meaningful categories distinguishing persons, activities,andrelationsondiVerentsidesoftheboundaries. IV. The Euro Across the European Union, the initiation of the euro in 1999 rekindled many of the same struggles over legitimate currencies that had marked the eventually successful nineteenth‐century eVort of western states to impose nationallegaltenders(Fishman&Messina,2006).Alongwithvariousforms ofelectronicmoney,theeurothreatenedtheprecariousmonetarymonopolies thosestateshadestablishedandincitednewversionsofearmarking. Europromoterstookonthedelicatetaskofinventingacurrencyinorder toconstructanewtransnationaleconomicandpoliticalcategory,whatsome call Euroland. But unlike national states, euro architects did so without a

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.