ebook img

The Future of Finance PDF

294 Pages·2010·3.82 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The Future of Finance

THE FuTurE oF FinancE The LSE Report Adair Turner Andrew Haldane Paul Woolley Sushil Wadhwani Charles Goodhart Andrew Smithers Andrew Large John Kay Martin Wolf Peter Boone Simon Johnson Richard Layard futureoffinance.org.uk Copyright © by the Authors. All Rights Reserved. 2010. Adair Turner and others (2010), The Future of Finance: The LSE Report, London School of Economics and Political Science. Cover Design: LSE Design Unit For further information, contact Harriet Ogborn Email: [email protected] Tel: 020 7955 7048 Contents Diagnosis Preface 1 Richard Layard 1. What do banks do? Why do credit booms and busts occur and what 5 can public policy do about it? Adair Turner 2. What is the contribution of the financial sector: Miracle or mirage? 87 Andrew Haldane, Simon Brennan and Vasileios Madouros 3. Why are financial markets so inefficient and exploitative – and a 121 suggested remedy Paul Woolley 4. What mix of monetary policy and regulation is best for stabilising 145 the economy? Sushil Wadhwani Ways Forward 5. How should we regulate the financial sector? 165 Charles Goodhart 6. Can we identify bubbles and stabilise the system? 187 Andrew Smithers 7. What framework is best for systemic (macroprudential) policy? 199 Andrew Large 8. Should we have “narrow banking”? 217 John Kay 9. Why and how should we regulate pay in the financial sector? 235 Martin Wolf 10. Will the politics of global moral hazard sink us again? 247 Peter Boone and Simon Johnson The Authors 289 Preface The financial crash of 2008-9 has been the most damaging economic event since the Great Depression – affecting the lives of hundreds of millions of people. The most immediate problem now is to prevent a repeat performance. Much has been written about reforming the world financial system. But it is rarely based on a searching in-depth analysis of the underlying weaknesses within the system. Nor does it usually tackle the key question of what a financial system is for. To correct this omission, we invited eighteen leading British thinkers on these issues to form a Future of Finance Group.1 They included journalists, academics, financiers and officials from the Financial Services Authority, the Bank of England and the Treasury. We have met twelve times, for what many of those present described as the best and most searching discussions they had ever participated in. The result is this book. The issues at stake are extraordinarily difficult and profound. The central question is what the financial system is for? Standard texts list five main functions – channelling savings into real investment, transferring risk, maturity transformation (including smoothing of life-cycle consumption), effecting payments and making markets. But if we study how financial companies make their money, it is extraordinarily difficult to see how closely this corresponds to the stated functions, and it is often difficult to explain why the rewards are often so high. Any explanation must also explain why the system is so prone to boom and bust. Chapters 1, 2 and 3 in the book deal with these fundamental issues: the ideal functions of the system; the way the system has actually operated; and the sources of boom and bust. To answer these questions much of the abstract theory of finance has to be abandoned in favour of a more realistic model of how the different agents actually behave. Central to this is opacity and asymmetric information, combined with short-term performance-related pay. For example, the asset price momentum which accompanies booms occurs because the owners of giant funds expect fund managers to shift into the fastest rising stocks. (They would do better to invest on a longer-term basis.) The opacity of the system has increased enormously with the growth of derivatives. Did this contribute to high long-term growth? The issue remains open. On one side, people point to the high real growth in 1950-1973 (an era of financial repression) and the real cost of the present downturn. On the other side, many studies, discussed in Chapter 4, point to real benefits from financial deepening. But apart from this Chapter, all others in the book invoke the need for a radically simplified and slimmer financial system 1 Other regular members of the group (apart from the authors) were Alastair Clark, Arnab Das, Howard Davies, Will Hutton, Martin Jacomb, Jonathan Taylor, Dimitri Vayanos and David Webb. 1 Preface – Richard Layard There are four aims of such a reform. The first is to prevent the financial system destabilising the real economy, as it has in the recent past. The second (closely related) is to protect tax-payers against the possible cost of bailouts. The third is to reduce the share of real national income which accrues as income to the financial sector and its employees for reasons not related to the benefits it confers – thus absorbing into the sector talent that could be more usefully used elsewhere. And all of this has to be done in a way that works. There are two main lines of approach. The first is regulation – higher capitalisation of all financial institutions, and levels of required capital that rise in a boom and fall in a slump. These are discussed in Chapters 5, 6 and 7. Chapter 5 points to some of the difficulties involved in any such regulation; Chapter 6 shows that asset price booms can be identified, at least sometimes; and Chapter 7 discusses how such information could be used, if there were an independent Committee specifically charged with ―macroprudential regulation‖. (Chapter 4 argues by contrast that financial booms should be mainly controlled via interest rates.) The second main approach to a more stable system is institutional reform. Chapter 8 argues strongly for the introduction of narrow banking. In such a system, only deposit- taking institutions could expect to be insured through the state, and they would not be allowed to build up a balance sheet of risky assets. This is a version of the so-called Volcker Rule. Faced with these two possible lines of approach, Chapter 9 comes down in favour of strong regulation, linked perhaps to some institutional reform, aimed especially at greater competition. It argues that the state would in fact bail out any major financial institution threatened with bankruptcy, whether deposit-taking or not; it must therefore regulate all institutions. Moreover managers must face totally different incentives and pay. In particular Chapter 9 suggest the managers should be liable to repay a substantial proportion of their pay if their institution requires state assistance or goes bankrupt within 10 years of their getting that pay. All these proposals would directly reduce the profitability of banks and the pay of bankers. Do they have a chance? Chapter 10 documents the huge influence that banks exert in the political sphere worldwide. And it argues strongly that only a worldwide system of regulation embodied in a worldwide treaty organisation, like the WTO, could have a chance. In this context it is encouraging that the Working Party of the G20 Financial Stability Board which will deliver proposals to the G20 Summit this November is chaired by our first author, Adair Turner. 2 Preface – Richard Layard It has been an extraordinary privilege to chair the discussion of these chapters. The book was discussed at a major conference at Savoy Place, London, on July 14th 2010. Both the Conference and the work of the Group have been funded by The Paul Woolley Centre for Capital Market Dysfunctionality at LSE. We are extremely grateful to Paul Woolley for his financial support and for his foresight in establishing his Centre well before the crash. The Group and the Conference have been jointly planned by Paul Woolley in his Centre and by myself in the Centre for Economic Performance. The Group has been superbly organised by Harriet Ogborn, and the Conference likewise by Jo Cantlay. Richard Layard July 2010 3 Chapter 1 What do banks do? Why do credit booms and busts occur and what can public policy do about it? Adair Turner Over the last 30 to 40 years the role of finance within developed economies has grown dramatically: debt to GDP ratios have increased, trading volumes exploded, and financial products have become more complex. Until the recent crisis this growing scale and complexity were believed to enhance both efficiency and stability. That assumption was wrong. To understand why, we need to recognise specific features of financial markets, credit contracts, and fractional reserve banks. The recent crisis was particularly severe because of the interaction between the specific characteristics of maturity transforming banks and securitised credit markets. The regulatory response needs to distinguish the different economic functions of different categories of credit: only a fraction of credit extension relates to capital formation processes. The response should combine much higher bank capital requirements than pre-crisis, liquidity policies which reduce aggregate maturity transformation, and counter-cyclical macro prudential tools possibly deployed on a sectorally specific basis. Introduction and Summary In 2007 to 2008 the world faced a huge financial crisis, which has resulted in major losses in wealth and employment and which has imposed great burdens on the public finances of developed countries. The latest stage of the crisis – its mutation into sovereign debt concerns – is still ongoing. We still need to manage out of the crisis; and we need to learn the lessons of what went wrong, so that we can reduce the probability and severity of future crisis. To do that effectively, we need to ask fundamental questions about the optimal size and functions of the financial system and about its value added within the economy, and about whether and under what conditions the financial system tends to generate economic stability or instability. We need to debate what the ―future of finance‖ should be. That is the purpose of the essays combined in this book. The recent past of finance, the last 20 to 30 years, has been striking, with three important developments: (i) first, a very major growth in the scale of financial activities relative to the real economy; (ii) second, an explosion of the complexity of financial products and services, in particular linked to the development of securitised credit and of credit and other derivatives; (iii) and third, a rise in intellectual confidence that this 5 Chapter 1 – Adair Turner growth in scale and complexity was adding economic value, making the global economy both more efficient and less risky. It is now clear that the third assumption was quite wrong: we need to understand why. Many aspects of what went wrong are obvious and have been set out in numerous official and academic reports. Risk management practices were often poor, relying on over-simplistic mathematical models; governance arrangements – the role of boards, risk committees and risk managers – were often inadequate, as sometimes was supervision by regulatory authorities. Rating agencies were beset by conflicts of interest. Complex structured products were sometimes sold to investors who failed to understand the embedded options; and in derivatives markets, huge counterparty exposures appeared, creating severe risks of interconnected failure. The policy response now being designed at European and global level needs to address, and is addressing, these clear deficiencies. But even if these deficiencies are addressed, the future financial system could remain dangerously unstable. Regulatory reform needs to address more fundamental issues. To do that effectively it must recognise that financial markets and systems have highly specific characteristics which distinguish them from other markets within a capitalist economy. In particular: (i) financial markets are different because inherently susceptible to de-stabilising divergences from equilibrium values; (ii) credit contracts create highly specific risks which increase economic volatility, and different categories of credit perform different functions and create different risks1; (iii) banks are highly specific institutions which introduced their own specific risks into the economy. Understanding these distinctive characteristics is central to understanding the potential dynamics of modern market economies; too much of modern economics has ignored them almost completely, treating the financial system as neutral in its macro-economic effect. This chapter considers their implications. Its key conclusions are that: (i) There is no clear evidence that the growth in the scale and complexity of the financial system in the rich developed world over the last 20 to 30 years has driven increased growth or stability, and it is possible for financial activity to extract rents from the real economy rather than to deliver economy value. Financial innovation and deepening may in some ways and under some circumstances foster economic 1 Three features of credit contracts carry important implications for cyclical tendencies within a market economy: specificity of tenor; specificity of nominal value; and the rigidity and irreversibility of default and bankruptcy. See Adair Turner Something Old and Something New: Novel and Familiar Drivers of the Latest Crisis, lecture to the European Association of Banking and Financial History (May 2010) for a discussion of these features. 6

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.