ebook img

Usury in Christian Middle Ages. A Reconsideration of the Historiographical Tradition (1949–2010) PDF

16 Pages·2012·0.191 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Usury in Christian Middle Ages. A Reconsideration of the Historiographical Tradition (1949–2010)

FONDAZIONE ISTITUTO INTERNAZIONALE DI STORIA ECONOMICA “F.DATINI” PRATO RELIGIONE E ISTITUZIONI RELIGIOSE NELL’ECONOMIA EUROPEA. 1000-1800 RELIGION AND RELIGIOUS INSTITUTIONS IN THE EUROPEAN ECONOMY. 1000-1800 Atti della “Quarantatreesima Settimana di Studi” 8-12 maggio 2011 a cura di Francesco Ammannati Firenze University Press 2012 INDICE Domenica 8 maggio – APERTURA DEI LAVORI ERIK AERTS,La religione nell’economia. L’economia nella religione. Europa 1000-1800 ........................................................................................................... pag. 3 Lunedì 9 maggio – TRA DOTTRINA E PRATICA DELLA VITA QUOTIDIANA: FINANZA & CAPITALE/BETWEENDOCTRINEAND PRACTICE OF EVERYDAY LIFE: FINANCE & CAPITAL Relazioni GIACOMO TODESCHINI, Usury in Christian Middle Ages. A Reconsideration of the Historiographical Tradition (1949-2010) .......................................................... pag. 119 MARKUS A.DENZEL, The Curial Payments System of the Late Middle Ages and the Sixteenth Century: Between Doctrineand Practice of EverydayLife ....... » 131 JOHN MUNRO, Usury, Calvinism and Credit in Protestant England: from the Sixteenth Century to the Industrial Revolution ........................................... » 155 JUANM.CARRETEROZAMORA, Les Collectories de la Monarchie Hispaniqueet la banque Italienne aux XVIe-XVIIe siècles (1506-1614)........................................... » 185 Comunicazioni JORDI MORELLÓ BAGET, Searching the “Veros Valores” of Some Religious Centresof Barcelona(About the Ecclesiastical Subsidy of 1443) ........................... pag. 207 DAVID KUSMAN, Le rôle de l’Église comme institution dans la contractualisation des opérations de crédit en Brabant, XIIIe-XVe siècle ................................................ » 227 Martedì 10 maggio – TRA DOTTRINA E PRATICA DELLA VITA QUOTIDIANA: FINANZA & CAPITALE/BETWEENDOCTRINEAND PRACTICE OF EVERYDAY LIFE: FINANCE & CAPITAL Comunicazioni MAREKS�O�, Die Rolle der kirchlichen Institutionen imGeldumlauf zwischen Stadt und Umland. Das Herzogtum Breslau im Spätmittelalter .......................................... pag. 249 ELISA SOLDANI,DANIEL DURAN I DUELT, Religion, Warfare and Business in Fifteenth-Century Rhodes .......................................................................................... » 257 GIOVANNI CECCARELLI, Concezioni economiche dell’Occidente cristiano alla fine del medioevo: fontie materiali inediti ............................................................ » 271 MORITZ ISENMANN, The Administration of the Papal Funded Debt: Structural Deficiencies and Institutional Reforms ...................................................... » 281 FABIENNE HENRYOT, La quête franciscaine aux XVIIe et XVIIIesiècles : théories et pratiques d’une économie de l’Evangile .................................................... » 293 PRESTON PERLUSS, From Alms to Investments: Monastic Credit Structures in 17th and 18th Century Paris......................................................................................... » 307 VIII INDICE Martedì 10 maggio – RELIGIONE E SVILUPPO ECONOMICO /RELIGION AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Relazioni RICHARD D.ORAM, Breaking New Ground: the Monastic Orders and Economic Development along the NorthernEuropean Periphery c.1070 to c.1300............... pag. 331 STEPHANE BOISSELLIER, Capitauxecclésiastiques, croissance économique et circuits épiscopaux dans la formation du Portugal, XIe-XIIIe siècles................... » 345 MURATÇIZAKÇA Long TermCauses of Decline of the Ottoman/Islamic Economies ........................................................................................ » 361 CÁTIA ANTUNES,FILIPA RIBEIRO DA SILVA, In Nomine Domini et In Nomine Rex Regis: Inquisition, Persecution and Royal Finances in Portugal, 1580-1715 .... » 377 Mercoledì 11 maggio – RELIGIONE E SVILUPPO ECONOMICO/RELIGION AND ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT Relazioni MONICA MARTINAT, Un modello cattolico di sviluppo economico? La riflessione teorica e la pratica degli scambi nell’Europa mediterranea (secc. XVI-XVIII)....... pag. 413 THIJS LAMBRECHT, “NineProtestants Are to Be Esteemed Worth TenCatholics.” Representing Religion, Labour and Economic Performance in Pre-Industrial Europe c. 1650-c. 1800 .................................................................................................................. » 431 Comunicazioni HANNELORE PEPKE-DURIX, L’économie monastique bourguignonne en quête d'organisation rationnelle (XIIe-XVe siècles) ................................................................ pag. 451 ANTONIO JOSÉ MIRA JÓDAR, La propiedad agraria eclesiásticaenValencia en la baja Edad Media. Rentas, gestión de la tierra y explotación campesina.......... » 465 GUIDOALFANI, Reformation, “Counter-reformation” and Economic Development from the Point of View of Godparenthood: an Anomaly? (Italy and Europe, 14th-19th Centuries) .......................................................................... » 477 LOREDANA PANARITI, “Non si acquista la scienza se non si studia”. La componente ebraica nel sistemaassicurativo triestino .......................................... » 491 MARIA GRAZIAD’AMELIO,MANUELVAQUEROPIÑEIRO, Devozione e risorse monetarie: aspetti del finanziamentodegli edifici religiosi tra Medioevoe età Moderna.......... » 499 ROMINA TSAKIRI, L’istituzione della cessione dei monasteri ortodossi nella Creta dei secoli XVI e XVII ed il suo contributo alle attività economiche degli ambienti circostanti................................................................................................ » 511 SAMIA CHERGUI, Institutions religieuses des habûs : nature, fonctionnement et impact sur les investissements immobiliersen Alger ottomane ............................................. » 529 MANON VAN DER HEIJDEN,ELISE VAN NEDERVEENMEERKERK,ARIADNESCHMIDT, Religion, Economic Development and Women’s Agency in the Dutch Republic .. » 543 MARIA CIE�LA, Between Religious Law and Practice. The Role of Jewish Communities in the Development of Town's Economy in the Grand Duchy of Lithuania in the 17th and 18th Centuries.............................................................................................. » 563 MARÍA DOLORES MUÑOZ DUEÑAS, La formación de un discurso secularizado sobre el sistema económico de la Iglesia: la cuestión del diezmo en Córdoba, 1750-1820 .. » 575 NICOLAS LYON-CAEN, Les jansénistes, le commerce et l’argent au 18e siècle ........ » 585 INDICE IX Giovedì 12 maggio – RELIGIONE E CONSUMI /RELIGION AND CONSUMPTION Relazioni PHILIP SLAVIN, Church and Food Provisioning in Late-Medieval England, 1250-1450: Production Costs, Markets and the Decline of Direct Demesne Management...... pag. 597 Comunicazioni TIMOTHY P.NEWFIELD, Epizootics and the Consumption of Diseased Meat in the Middle Ages.......................................................................................................... pag. 619 LAUREANOM.RUBIO PÉREZ,OSCAR FERNÁNDEZ ALVAREZ, Religion, Culture and Eating: Believes, Consumption Ways and Collective Practices in the Northwest of Spain from the 16th to the 18th Centuries..................................................................... » 641 ISABEL DRUMOND BRAGA, Les familles de chrétiens nouveaux et la possession d’objets religieux (XVIIe et XVIIIe siècles) ................................................................................. » 655 BRECHTDEWILDE,JOHAN POUKENS, Confraternities, Jansenism and the Birth of a Consumer Society in 17th-18th-Century Leuven .................................................. » 671 Giovedì 12 maggio – MOBILITÀ E MIGRAZIONE: PERSECUZIONE, PELLEGRINAGGI E TURISMO RELIGIOSO /MOBILITY AND MIGRATION: AGGRESSION, PILGRIMAGE AND RELIGIOUS TOURISM Relazioni DAVID JACOBY, The Economic Impact of Christian Pilgrimage on the Holy Land, Eighth-SixteenthCentury – a Long-Term Overview ................................................. pag. 697 CHRISTOPHEDUHAMELLE, Pèlerinage etéconomie dans l’Empire au XVIIIe siècle................................................................................................................ » 713 Comunicazioni JUDICAËL PETROWISTE, Pèlerinages et essor commercial dans les pays occitans médiévaux (XIe-XIIIe siècle)........................................................................................... pag. 729 FEDERICO PIGOZZO, I denari dei pellegrini. Oblazioni votivee istituzioni ecclesiastiche nell’Italia centrale alla fine del XIV secolo ................................................................... » 743 CLÉMENT LENOBLE, Investimenti religiosi, civici edeconomici. Diritto e teologia in alcuni aspetti degli scambi tra mercanti italiani e fratiminori (Avignone secc. XIV-XV) . » 755 MICHAELA.PENMAN, The Economics of Faith: Approaches to Monastic Saints’ Cults in Medieval Scotland ........................................................................................................ » 765 YVES JUNOT, Les migrants, unenjeu? Pacification religieuse et relance économique de part etd’autre de la frontièreentre la Franceet les Pays-Bas espagnols (c. 1580-c. 1610) ............................................................................................................... » 779 MARIA MARTA LOBO DE ARAUJO, Les pèlerinages au Sanctuaire de Notre Dame de Porto de Ave en tant que moteurs de changement : la dynamisationde l’économie locale (XVIIIe siècle) ........................................................................................................ » 793 MARIA ENGRACIA LEANDRO, Quand la religion et l’économie se mêlent. Triomphe des croyances autour du Sanctuairede Notre Dame da Nazaré, triomphe de l’économie locale....................................................................................... » 805 Abstracts ........................................................................................................................... » 823 Giacomo Todeschini Usury in Christian Middle Ages. A Reconsideration of the Historiographical Tradition (1949-2010)* “The Idea of Usury. From Tribal Brotherhood to Universal Otherhood” by Benjamin Nelson, a well known American sociologist and historian, was published in 1949. It was an outline of the historical development of biblical (Dt 23)1 forbid- ding of lending on interest aiming at underlining, on the one hand, the central role of “usury” in the economic formation of western European society, and, on the other hand, the opposition between Christian religious ethics and economy that Nelson, on a weberian basis, supposed to be at the core of the difference between pre-modern and modern economy. The radical change of the notion described through the word “usury,” and the transition from a forbidding to the liberalization of lending on interest would have been the same, in this perspective, than the evo- lution from the “tribal brotherhood” to (capitalistic) “universal otherhood.” As Wim Decock2 puts it, the problem would be to discover when “the breakdown of the Scholastic paradigm” actually happened. The idea that “usury” and its forbidding were the heart of the medieval “eco- nomic doctrine,” and at the same time the idea that something like a coherent me- dieval “economic doctrine” had existed, are however two very typical interconnected and complementary historical assumptions widely represented by European economic historians since the beginning of the past century, and firmly recapitulated in the Fifties and Sixties by historians devoted to explain, on the whole, the transition from “feudal” to “capitalistic mode of production.”3 * This paper is strictly connected to my until today unpublished presentation in the Harvard Workshop Christian relation to Jewish Finance in Europe (12th-16th centuries ) (Harvard University, Centre of Middle Eastern Studies, February 18-19, 2011): “Judas and the Christian common people: Jewish “usury” and ordinary Christian economic behaviors inthe perspective of the late-medieval building of an economy ofthebonum commune (14th-15th C.).” 1 See J.NEUSNER, The Mishnah: social perspectives, Leiden-Boston 1999 (Brill), pp. 115 ff., 156 ff. 2 W. DECOCK, Lessius and the Breakdown of the Scholastic Paradigm, in “Journal of the History of Economic Thought”, 31, 2009, n. 1, pp. 57-78. 3 H. CONTZEN, Geschichte der volkswirtschaftlichen Literatur des Mittelalters Berlin 1869, 18722; F.X. FUNK, Geschichte des kirchlichen Zinsverbotes, Tübingen 1876; H. GARNIER, De l'idée du juste prix chez les théologiens et canonistes du moyen âge,Paris 1900; F. SCHAUB, Der Kampf gegen den Zinswucher, ungerechten Preis und unlauteren Handel im Mittelalter. Von Karl dem Grossen bis Papst Alexander III, Freiburg 1905; O. SCHILLING, Reichtum und Eigentum in der ethisch-rechtlichen Literatur, Freiburg 1908; H. BREY, Hochscholastik und 'Geist' des Kapitalismus, Leipzig 1927; A. FANFANI, Le origini dello spirito capitalistico in Italia, Milano 1933; J.T. NOONAN, The Scholastic Analysis of Usury, Cambridge Mass 1957; J.W. BALDWIN, The Medieval Theories of the Just Price: Romanists, Canonists and Theologians in the 12. and 13. Centuries, Philadelphia 1959; E. SALIN, Politische Ökonomie: Geschichte der wirtschaftspolitischen Ideen von 120 GIACOMO TODESCHINI The entire problem and its historiographical formalization, as well as the incon- gruities depending on an anachronistic economic sketch of medieval societies representing them in terms of obligatory opposition between “economic theory” and “economic practice,” basically depend on the misunderstanding of what, in fact, the word usura4 and the legal, theological and economic definitions connected to this word truly signify in the variegated medieval textual universe. Actually, a close analysis of Christian textual sources normally used to detect the medieval Christian “doctrinal” attitude on wealth, profit and fertility or sterility of money, as well as their contextualized reading and comparison, clearly indicates that a systematic and coherent economic Christian doctrine absolutely allowing or forbidding specific forms of economic interplay never existed. On the contrary, what historians between nineteenth and twentieth century have described as the beginning of an increasingly coherent Christian social philosophy is most likely a slow and progressive (and so not necessarily coherent) stratification of linguistic habits aimed, firstly, to describe the religious Christian notions of spiritual fructifi- cation and final salvation through economic and financial metaphors, and, second- ly, to represent gain and profit, namely to shape Christian economic interplay, as inner phases of a more wide social and ecclesiological project founding the recogni- tion of everyone's economic credibility on the authentication of a faith intended as factor of social identification and basis of each legitimate kinship. In this perspec- tive, the medieval representation of the economic interplay is hardly reducible to a theoretical system shaping economic games as individual relations whose meaning is readable only in ethical terms.5 The western construction of economic lexica and the western economic repre- sentational strategies concerning economic objects and relations appear, in a pers- pective not opposing (in an anachronistic way) “personal” and “impersonal” economic games, as deeply depending on the political identity and administrative objectives of the literate minority both writing the economic metaphors or eco- nomic prescriptions we today read, and concretely governing the monasteries, ab- beys, bishoprics, castles and cities geographically shaping what we today call the western medieval market space, namely the markets ruled by the multiple European powers.6 In other words, the representation of biblical and ancient Jewish economic space in terms of “brotherhood” contradicted by the commercial and anonymous namely impersonal (that is to say non-political) modern “otherhood,” on its turn Platon bis zur Gegenwart, Tübingen-Zürich 1967; J. GILCHRIST, The Church and economic Activity in the Middle Ages New York 1969 ; R. DE ROOVER, La pensée économique des Scolastiques Montréal-Paris 1971; R. DE ROOVER, Business, Banking and Economic Thought in Late Medieval and Early Modern Europe, ed. J. KIRSHNER, Chicago-London 1974. On these authors and writings see G. TODESCHINI, Il prezzo della salvezza. Lessici medievali del pensiero economico, Roma 1994 (La Nuova Italia Scientifica). 4 See H. SIEMS, Handel und Wucher im Spiegel frühmittelalterlicher Rechtsquellen, Hannover 1992 (Hahn, MGH Schriften). 5 G. TODESCHINI, I mercanti e il tempio, Bologna 2002 (Il Mulino); IDEM, Theological Roots of the Medieval/Modern Merchants’ Self-Representation, inThe Self-Perception of Early Modern Capitalists, M.J. JACOB, C. SECRETAN eds., New York 2008 (Palgrave), pp.17-46. 6 M. ARNOUX, Vérité et questions des marchés médiévaux, in L'activité marchande sans le marché?, A. HATCHUEL, O. FAVEREAU, F.AGGERIeds., Paris 2010 (Presses des Mines), pp. 27-40. 121 USURY IN CHRISTIAN MIDDLE AGES gradually defined by the attenuation of the medieval Christian forbidding of usury, was and is rooted in an imprecise cognition of the different meanings the medieval condemnation of usura could assume in different political and historical contexts. At the same time, the widely diffused historiographical representation of Jewish medieval economic role as obviously identical everywhere, since the High Middle Ages, to the specialization of the “Jews” in lending activities7 (a representation al- ready developed by Sombart’s Die Juden und das Wirtschaftsleben in 1911) matches with the historiographical representation of Christian condemnation of credit trans- actions as a condemnation of the “Jewish” notion of “brotherhood,” namely as condemnation of the distinction made by the Book of Deuteronomy between lend- ing to brothers and lending to strangers that, in turn, was and is perceived by many historians as typically Jewish.8 The historiographical idea shaping “usury” as the medieval summary and syn- onym of “credit,” an idea depending on some common places very typical of 19th century historiography, is, in other words, based on a stereotyped representation of Jews and Christians as economic performers: the ones represented as the founders of an archaic economic “brotherhood,” the others described as the dramatic initia- tors of modern, universalistic kinship forms opening the way to the “market” after the crisis of the so-called ethical “Scholastic paradigm.” In this light the absolute historiographical conviction concerning the existence of a long-lasting and indis- putable medieval Christian prohibition of lending on interest was and often is the outcome of an interpretation of western economic rationality as a linear process de- layed by the (Christian) denial of money’s productivity. The inner meaning of this denial was however generally interpreted as directly functional to the crossing of the obstacle represented by a (Jewish) “brotherhood” defining the fruitfulness of money as a main consequence of the exclusion from “tribal” belonging. Through the refusal of the abstract notion of money’s fertility the Christian community would have shaped an idea of productive work activating the capital, an idea cha- racterizing – in the historiographical perspective well represented by Sapori and de Roover – the western development of the Christian universalistic “market.” Actually, at the origin of Nelson’s depiction of Christian rejection of usury it is possible to see the simplified denotation of “usury” performed by historiography between nineteenth and the first half of the past century.9 Analogously, Nelson’s description of the Christian attenuationof this forbidding as a main consequence of 7 See the final counterarguments presented in Wirtschaftsleben der abendländischen Juden. Fragen und Einschätzungen, ed. M. TOCH, München 2008 (Oldenbourg,). See also IDEM, Jews and Commerce: Modern Fancies and Medieval Realities, in Il ruolo economico delle minoranze in Europa. Secc. XIII-XVIII. Atti della XXXI Settimana di Studi, ed. S. CAVACIOCCHI, Firenze 2000, pp.43-58; G. TODESCHINI, Les historiens juifs en Allemagne et le débat sur l’origine du capitalisme avant 1914, in Écriture de l’histoire et identité juive. L’Europe ashkénaze XIXe-XXe siècle, D. BECHTEL, E. PATLAGEAN, J.-C. SZUREK, P. ZAWADZKI eds., Paris 2003 (Les Belles Lettres), pp. 209-228 ; IDEM, Christian Perceptions of Jewish Economic Activity in the Middle Ages,” in Wirtschaftsgeschichte der mittelalterlichen Juden. Fragen und Einschätzungen, cit.,pp. 1-16. 8 F. RAPHAEL, Judaïsme et capitalisme. Essai sur la controverse entre Max Weber et Werner Sombart, Paris 1982 (Presses Universitaires de France). 9 I discussed this historiographical line in a book published seventeen years ago: G. TODESCHINI, Il prezzo della salvezza, cit. See the excellent survey by H. SIEMS, Handel und Wucher im Spiegel fru�hmittelalterlicher Rechtsquellen, Hannover 1992 (Hahn, MGH Schriften). 122 GIACOMO TODESCHINI the wide medieval diffusionof a notionof holy war (exemplified, according to Nel- son, by the circulation of a dictum of Ambrose translating the idea of “right war” in economic terms: it is licit to lend on interest to the enemies, ubi ius belli ibi ius usu- rae)10 appears today as an argumentproduced by a form of historical reasoning sub- stantially unconcerned by the different linguistic structure of the sources. This simplifying logic is primarily rooted in a reading of the sources establishing the im- probable continuity of the meaning of usura from Patristic Age until the thirteenth century, as well as the improbable semantic homogeneity of this concept in very different textual fields as those defined by the writings of theologians like Clemens of Alexandria and Ambrose and Augustine, or Robert de Courçon and Thomas Aquinas, ecclesiastical polemists as Hincmar of Reims and Humbert of Silvacandi- da, canonists and civil lawyers like Gratian and Etienne de Tournai, or Henry of Susa, Accursius and Bartolo of Sassoferrato, local jurists or penitential authorities as Thomas of Chobham and Raymond of Peñafort, each one of them representing, on the contrary, a different and specific namely discontinuous phase of the histori- cal development of what we today tend to roughly imagine as the beginning of western economic thought. Actually, if we closely consider these different authors, or, to be more exact, these very different written sources and their own specific vocabulary, it becomes immediately clear, firstly, that the forbidding of “usury” had in different contexts very different meanings, secondly that “usury” never was intended as an automatic synonym of “credit,” and, thirdly, that the relation between debtors and creditors was changing its sense according to the social and institutional role of debtors and creditors. At the same time the abstract problem of the productivity or sterility of money, so frequently described by historiography, from Benjamin Nelson to Jac- ques Le Goff until the systematic description of the sources by Odd Langholm, as the theoretical fundament of the medieval forbidding of usury,11 played a minor role in the linguistic definitions and regulations of the real core of late medieval economic discourse: the political managing of the violence implicit in social ex- change as it was mirrored in the economic games.12 Actually a clear understanding of what Scholastics intended to say through their reasoning on the fact that pecunia can not bear as the pecus does, should be connected to their variegated representa- tion of money as sign of value, as symbol of power, as metallic coin. From the late- medieval point of view, as well as in other pre-modern economic perceptions of money,13 it was perfectly clear that the measure of value expressed through the ab- stract namely mathematical notion of money was neatly different both from money symbolizing the power of a ruler and from money reified by coins. Obviously this 10 AMBROSIUS, De Tobia 15, 51; Decretum Gratiani C. XIV q. 3 c. 12, ed. A. FRIEDBERG, Leipzig 1879 (Tauchnitz), 738. 11 The historiographical idea of a medieval “doctrine” (directly rooted in Aristotle’s writings) focussed on the “sterility of money” is a sort of historiographical dogma, already present in MAX WEBER’s The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism (1904-5), New York 2003 (Dover), p. 82. This assumption generally based on a simplified reading of some Thomas Aquinas’ passages, is finally repeated by O. LANGHOLM, Economics in Medieval Schools. Wealth, Exchange, Value, Money and Usury According to the Paris Theological Tradition, 1200-1350, Leiden 1992 (Brill.) 12 R.DUMOUCHEL-J.-P. DUPUY, L’enfer des choses. René Girard et la logique de l’économie, Paris 1979 (Seuil). 13 See M. GODELIER, L’enigme du don, Paris 1996 (Fayard), pp. 39 ff. 123 USURY IN CHRISTIAN MIDDLE AGES third type of “money” could not be imagined as bearing a fruit (for the same reason than each artificial object); on the contrary money as an idealization of value pos- sessed and used by specific economic performers could be activated and so become fertile through their competence: in other words when money was not perceived as an unanimated metallic thing but as a sign of possible value managed by well identi- fiable entrepreneurs, its nature could appear as full of potential fruits, a capitale and not simply a sors.14 It is possible indeed to distinguish in the textual and economic Christian history of usura, both as economic notion and linguistic definition of a practice hardly ever so clear as often historians believed, three approximate stages corresponding to the patristic age, to the age of formation of Canon Law, between seventh and twelfth century, and finally to the development of a legal definition of credit transactions, after the thirteenth century. A main problem in the study of these different percep- tions and descriptions of what in any case is deceptively called usurais caused by the fact that historiography rarely has considered the relation between these phases of meaning. So, we can find some important studies on the economic language of the Fathers, Clemens of Alexandria or Ambrose of Milan or Augustine, and on the other side some clever analysis of the conflicting economic interplay between eccle- siastic and imperial powers summed up by the key-word simony (simonia).15 At the same time, the textual flow developed after 1140, namely the first codification of Canon law, about the illicitness of the activities performed by the so-called usurarius manifestus, the public seller of money, was considered by many scholars specialized in the study of Canon Law only for the period going from the first commentators of Gratian’s Decretum to the redaction of the second part of Canon Law, the De- cretals of Gregory the Ninth and its first commentaries (as it is possible to see in the first essays by Giuseppe Salvioli and Franz Schaub as well as in the articles and books by Terence McLaughlin and John Baldwin and, more recently, Harald Siems.) Finally the so-called Scholastic doctrine on usury and just price was studied with subtlety by many well known scholars and synthesized in many huge books from the Studien by Wilhelm Endemann in the eighties of the nineteenth century to the Scholastic Analysis of Usury (1957) by John Thomas Noonan in the fifties of the last century, until Raymond De Roover’s La pensée èconomique des Scholastiques (1971), and lastly Odd Langholm’s Economics in Medieval Schools (1992).16 Especially this last kind of studies seems to be on the one hand totally founded on the presumption that Christian representations of the economic interplay after the beginning of the 13th century are definitely rooted in the forbidding of “usury.” On the other hand, these studies are absolutely pervaded by the idea that the last two centuries of the medieval era are the beginning of an ambiguous new way of economic thinking: 14 See J. KAYE, Economy and Nature in the Fourteenth Century: Money, Market Exchange, and the Emergence of Scientific Thought, Cambridge 1998 (Cambridge University Press); G. CECCARELLI, Risky Business: Theological and Canonical Thought on Insurance from the Thirteenth to the Seventeenth Century, in “Journal of Medieval and Early Modern Studies”, 31, 2001, n. 3, pp. 607-658; G. TODESCHINI, Franciscan Wealth. From Voluntary Poverty to Market Society, New York 2009 (St. Bonaventure University.) 15 See now J.-M. SALAMITO, Christianisme antique et économie: raisons et modalités d’une rencontre historique, in “Antiquité tardive”, 14, 2006, pp. 27-37. 16 A commentedbibliography in G.TODESCHINI, Il prezzo della salvezza, cit., pp. 39-113. 124 GIACOMO TODESCHINI that, in fact, as Joseph Schumpeter wrote around fifty years ago, the fundament of each future economic science “is all in the Scholastics.”17 The absence of a scholarly attention for the relation between the different meanings assumed in different periods by the word-concept usura, as well as by the universe of economic practice it could indicate, is verisimilarly at the origin of a sys- tematic misunderstanding of what credit relations could actually signify in different political contexts like, for example, the Carolingian empire, late medieval kingdoms or Italian cities between 12th and 13th centuries. The categorical assumption of the forbidding of usury as fil rouge connecting these and others institutional realities made impossible on the whole to see the evidence of a distinction, basic in Canon Law since twelfth century, between credit performed by ecclesiastic institution or other public subjects, and selling of money performed by “private” subjects, namely unauthorized individuals. With the end of the myth of modern free market as arriv- al point of the mythological history of the market written by neo-liberist econo- mists in terms of progressive edification of a perfect independence of economy from politics and institutional powers and choices, the late-medieval and early modern economic discourse can finally be considered through a more limpid and less ideological lens.18 In fact, the idea that licit and socially useful forms of credit were linked to the institutional visibility of the entrepreneurs namely to their participation in the polit- ic and social networks shaping the so-called bonum commune was widely circulated by highly authoritative textual tools like conciliar canons and Decretals. Licit forms of credit were at this point well separated from usurious contracts, and, although his- toriography rarely admits it, the system of exceptions gradually introduced by ca- nonists to define legal types of credit contracts became a precise economic strategy aimed at facilitating the development of specific economic behaviors assumed as a- priori honorable. From the middle of the 13th century this kind of exceptions com- posed a system of economic rules in itself more clear and understandable than the forbidding of a practice, “usury,” whose traditional ambiguous meaning appeared now, in the light of a credit life manifestlydetermining the fiscal revenues of Sacred powers such as the Holy See, even more blurred. Matrimonial credit deriving from the retarded payment of a dowry, commercial credit in the form of society or com- menda, commerce of public and ecclesiastical rents, selling on credit when this busi- ness was formalized as connected to the politically significant economic activities of relevant merchant-bankers: these and others formalizations became typical repre- sentations of the lay credit forms recognized as an ordinary way of economic ad- ministration in consequence of the public importance of the subjects performing 17 J. SCHUMPETER, History of Economic Analysis, London 1986 [1954] (Routledge), p. 294. 18 D.C. NORTH, The rise of the western world: a new economic history, Cambridge 1973 (Cambridge University Press); IDEM, Structure and Change in Economic History, New York 1981 (Norton); IDEM, Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance, Cambridge 1990 (Cambridge University Press); D. C. NORTH, JOHN JOSEPH WALLIS, BARRY R. WEINGAST, Violence and Social Orders: a Conceptual Framework for Interpreting Recorded Human History, Cambridge 2009 (Cambridge University Press); M. GRANOVETTER, Economic Action and Social Structure: The Problem of Embeddedness, in “American Journal of Sociology”,91, 1985, pp. 481-510; V.ZELIZER, The Social Meaning of Money: Pin Money, Paychecks, Poor Relief, and Other Currencies, New York 1994 (Basic Books).

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.