Understanding the Aggregate Effects of Anticipated and Unanticipated Tax Policy Shocks ∗ Karel Mertens1 and Morten O. Ravn2,3,4 Cornell University1, University College London2, University of Southampton3, and CEPR4 February 12, 2009 Abstract We evaluate the extent to which a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model can account for theimpactof“surprise”and“anticipated”taxshocksestimatedfromU.S.time-seriesdata. Mertens and Ravn (2009) show that surprise tax cuts have expansionary and persistent effects on output, consumption, investment and hours worked. Prior to their implementation, anticipated tax liability taxcutsgiverisetocontractionsinoutput,investmentandhoursworked. Aftertheirimplementation, anticipated tax liability cuts lead to an economic expansion. A DSGE model with changes in tax rates that may be anticipated or not, is shown to be able to account for the empirically estimated impactoftaxshocks. Theimportantfeaturesofthemodelincludeadjustmentcosts,variablecapacity utilizationandconsumptionhabitsbutwedonotrelyonpreferenceswithlowshortrunwealtheffects onlaborsupplythathavebeenhighlightedinthetechnologynewsliterature. WealsoderiveHicksian decompositions of the consumption and labor supply responses and show that substitution effects are key for understanding the impact of tax shocks. Key words: Fiscal policy, tax liabilities, anticipation effects, structural estimation. JEL: E20, E32, E62, H30 Partsofthispaperwasearliercirculatedunderthetitle“TheAggregateEffectsofAnticipatedandUnanticipatedU.S. ∗ TaxPolicyShocks: Theoryand EmpiricalEvidence”. WearegratefultoPeterClaeys, StephenCoate,BobDriskill,Jordi Galì, Eric Leeper, Juan Rubio-Ramirez, and seminar participants at SED 2008, ESSIM 2008, Cornell University, Penn State University, University College London, Universite’ Catholic de Louvain, University of Warwick and at the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago for comments. The responsibility for any errors is entirely ours. 1 Introduction In this paper we ask how changes in taxes affect the economy in a dynamic stochastic general equi- librium model. We contrast a DSGE model with U.S. postwar time-series evidence on the impact of unanticipated and anticipated changes in taxes. The distinction between anticipated and unanticipated tax changes is based upon the use of timing assumptions that we apply to Romer and Romer’s (2007, 2008) narrative account of federal U.S. tax liability changes. We show that implemented exogenous tax cuts give rise to a prolonged expansion of the economy while announced but yet not implemented tax cuts are associated with a decline in aggregate activity, investment and hours worked. This evidence on anticipation effects is particularly helpful in evaluating economic theory because it allows us to evaluate the impact of tax “news” shocks. We follow Mertens and Ravn (2009) and measure tax shocks using Romer and Romer’s (2007a) narrative account of legislated federal tax liability changes in the U.S. Based upon official government reports, presidential speeches and Congressional documents, these authors provide a detailed account of all significant federal tax bills during the post-war period. We study the impact of those tax changes that according to Romer and Romer (2007a) can be assumed to be exogenous. We make a simple yet informative classification of tax changes into anticipated and unanticipated tax shocks by using information on the timing differences between the dates of the announcement of tax changes and the implementation of these tax changes. Specifically, tax liability that were to take place within (later than) 90 days of the law being signed by the president are classified as unanticipated (anticipated). These tax shocks are embedded in a vector autoregressive analysis in order to derive estimates of the dynamic effects of tax policy shocks assuming that the tax liability changes are exogenous. We study the impact of the tax shocks on aggregate output, consumption of nondurables and services, purchases of durable consumption goods, investment, and hours worked. We find that unanticipated tax cuts give rise to significant increases in output, consumption, and investment which peak around 2.5 years after the introduction of the tax cut. There is also a rise in hours worked but it occurs more gradually. Assuming thatanticipated tax shocks are announced 6 quarters before their implementation, themediananticipationhorizoninthedata, wefindthatananticipatedtaxcutisassociatedwithapre- implementation drop in output and investment while consumption remains roughly constant during the pre-implementation period. Once the tax change is implemented, its impact on these variables becomes 1 similar to the effects of an unanticipated tax change. There is also a significant pre-implementation drop in hours worked. In order to evaluate the extent to which the empirical estimates of the impact of changes in federal taxliabilitiesareconsistentwitheconomictheory,weconstructadynamicstochasticgeneralequilibrium model in which variations in distortionary tax rates give rise to changes in tax liabilities. We allow for variations both in labor income tax rates and in capital income tax rates and for unanticipated as well as anticipated tax shocks. Key parameters are estimated by matching the theoretical impulse response functions of the observables with those estimated in the U.S. data. We show that the DSGE model accounts very well for the shapes and sizes of the response of the observables to implemented changes in tax liabilities and for the announcement effects that we estimate in the U.S. data. Interestingly, we find that the anticipation effects can be accounted for using a model with standard preferences and without liquidity constraints. These results are interesting because the literature on “news shocks” to technology, c.f. Beaudry and Portier (2004, 2006, 2007) and Jaimovich and Rebelo (2006), has shown that wealth effects on labor supply must be weak in order to generate an “anticipation expansion” of the economy in response to current good news about future productivity. This literature, however, provides no direct empirical evidence on such news effects in the data. Our empirical results show that good news about taxes lead to a pre-implementation decline in aggregate activity and that this effect can be accounted for by standard preference models. On the other hand, consistently with the technology news literature, we find that adjustment costs and variable capacity utilization are pertinent to account for the impact of tax shocks. The importance of adjustment costs shows the relevance of Auerbach’s (1989) analysis of the impact of anticipated tax changes on aggregate investment. Another important insight relates to the anticipation effects on consumption of nondurables and services. Our empirical results complement earlier studies of the consumption impact of anticipated tax changes. Poterba (1988) tests whether aggregate U.S. consumption reacts to announcements of future tax changes and fails to find robust evidence in favor of this hypothesis.1 Heim (2007) studies data from the Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) and tests for announcement effects of state tax 1Poterba (1988) identifies five such episodes: February 1964, June 1968, March 1975, August 1981, and August 1986. We exclude the second and third of these episodes because Romer and Romer (2007a) categorize these tax changes as endogenous. 2 rebates. He finds no significant household consumption response to rebate announcements. Parker (1999)andSouleles(1999,2002)alsostudyCEXdataandtestwhetherhouseholdconsumptionresponds to actual changes in taxes when these were known in advance of their implementation.2 They find significant impacts of tax changes at the implementation dates. These results are often interpreted as evidence of lack of forward looking behavior, the presence of binding liquidity constraints or other aspects that prevent consumers from adjusting consumption plans to predictable changes in income. Our empirical results are consistent with this earlier literature, but we show that the lack of a strong response of consumption to announcements about future taxes, and a significant consumption response to actual changes in taxes when these were pre-announced, are not necessarily inconsistent with a rational expectations DSGE model that abstracts from liquidity constraints. We also extend the literature in terms of understanding the impact of tax changes. First, we show that, in contrast to e.g. Yang (2005), that the impact of anticipated changes in capital and labor income taxes are not fundamentally different. Assuming an anticipation horizon of 4 quarters, Yang (2005) shows that in response to an anticipated cut in the labor tax rate, consumption rises during the pre-implementation period while output, investment and hours worked contract; in response to an anticipated cut in the capital income tax rate instead, the opposite pattern is implied. We show that these results do not hold through in an economy with a more rigorous modeling of production and preference structures and with reasonable degrees of adjustment costs. In the face of such aspects, the anticipation effects of capital income and labor income tax changes are quite similar. Secondly,inordertounderstandhowtheeconomyrespondstochangesintaxes,wederiveaHicksian decompositionofthehoursworkedandconsumptionresponsestochangesintaxes. Wedecomposethese responses into wealth effects, substitution effects that derive from changes in wages and interest rates, and a “wedge”. The latter arises because of adjustment costs. The responses of hours worked and consumption to changes in taxes are dominated by the substitution effects while the wealth effects are very small due mainly to the fact that the wealth effects are associated with Harberger triangles (i.e. with a change in distortionary taxes). We show that the key to understanding why hours worked respond sluggishly to surprise changes in taxes are the opposing effects of the substitution effects due to wages and due to changes in interest rates. 2Parker(1999) examines the impact ofSocial Security changes during the 1980’s while Souleles (2002) investigates the Reagan tax cut of the early 1980’s. 3 The remainder of this paper is structured as follows. The next section describes our estimation approach and discusses the dynamic effects of tax shocks. Section 3 contains the description of the DSGE model. The estimation of the structural parameters is contained in Section 4. In Section 5 we discuss and analyze the results. Finally, Section 6 concludes and summarizes. 2 Estimation InthissectionwepresenttheestimationresultsregardingtheimpactoftaxshocksintheUnitedStates. A detailed analysis of the data and robustness analysis is contained in Mertens and Ravn (2009). It is this empirical evidence that we shall later examine whether the DSGE model can account for. 2.1 Identification We identify tax shocks using Romer and Romer’s (2007a, 2008) narrative account of federal U.S. tax policy acts. A key advantage of the narrative approach is that it allows one to make a distinction between anticipated and unanticipated tax shocks based on timing assumptions. Romer and Romer’s (2007a) base their account on analyses of official government documents, presidential speeches, and Congressional documents. They identify 49 significant legislated federal tax acts in the period 1947- 2006 and a total of 104 separate changes in tax liabilities. Some of these tax liability changes were introduced to address concerns about the state of the economy or motivated by the need to finance of government spending plans while other changes in tax liabilities were exogenous in nature. We focus on the tax liability changes that Romer and Romer (2007a) classify as exogenous. This corresponds to 70 tax liability changes in total. The tax data allows us to introduce a natural timing based distinction between unanticipated and anticipatedtaxshocks. Foreachtaxliabilitychangewedefineanannouncementdatewhichcorresponds to the date at which the tax legislation became law, i.e. when it was signed by the President, and an implementation date which is the date at which, according to the legislation, the tax liability changes were to be introduced. We define a tax liability change as anticipated if the difference between these two dates exceeds 90 days. We use a 90 days window because it strikes a balance between robustness of the results to the date within a quarter that a tax change became law, and the ability to measure anticipation effects. 4 Basedonouruseofa90daywindow,38ofthetaxliabilitychangesareanticipatedand32aredefined as surprise tax shocks.3 The median implementation lag in the data is 6 quarters. This relatively long median anticipation lag implies that identification schemes of tax policy shocks based on the existence of decision lags are not easily implemented, see Blanchard and Perotti (2002). The impact of tax shocks are estimated from the following regression model: K X =A+Bt+C(L)X +D(L)τu+F (L)τa + G τa +e (1) t t 1 t t,0 i t,i t − i=1 X where X is a vector of endogenous variables, A and B control for a constant term and a linear trend, t C(L) is P-order lag polynomial, and D(L) and F (L) are (R+1)-order lag polynomials.4 τu and τa t t,i arethetaxshocks. Theformerofthesecorrespondstotheunanticipatedtaxshockswhicharemeasured astheimplieddollarchangeintax liabilitiesinpercentagesof currentpriceGDPattheimplementation date. K Thevector τa denotestheanticipatedtaxshocksthatarepartoftheinformationsetatdatet. t,i i=0 h i Specifically, τa measuresthepre-announcedtaxchangeswhich areknownatdatet andwhicharetobe t,i implemented at date t+i. This is thesum of tax liabilitychangesannounced today or in the past which have the same implementation date.5 The regression model then implies that the current realization of X depends on lags of current and past changes in taxes through the terms D(L)τu and F (L)τa , t t t,0 and on currently known but yet not implemented changes in taxes through the terms K G τa . This i=1 i t,i latter terms therefore corresponds directly to “news” shocks. P We study U.S. quarterly data for the sample period 1947:1 - 2006:4. We consider the following set of endogenous variables: 0 Xt = yt, ct, dt, it, ht ∙ ¸ where y denotes the logarithm of U.S. GDP per adult in constant (chained) prices, c is the logarithm t t of the real private sector consumption expenditure on nondurables and services per capita, d is the t logarithm of private sector consumption expenditure on durables per capita, i is the logarithm of real t 3Alternatively,Lustig,SleetandYeltekin(2007)useinformationon“abnormal”returntomeasureexpectedgovernment defense spending changes. 4The results are robust to allowing for a break in the trend in 1973:2, see Ramey and Shapiro (1998) and Burnside, Eichenbaum and Fisher (2004). The results are also robust to first differencing the X vector. t 5In order to measure these we assume that pre-announced tax shocks enters agents’ information sets at the earliest M quarters before their implementation. We set this maximum lag equal to 3 years. 5 aggregate gross investment per capita. h is the logarithm of average hours worked per adult. Precise t definitions and data sources are given in Table A.1 in the appendix. The VAR above assumes that the tax shocks have persistent but non-permanent effects on the vector of observables (under the condition that the lag-polynomial C(L) does not contain unit roots). We also checked the results when allowing for permanent effects of the tax shocks using a VAR in first differences. The results are very similar to those that we derive with the VAR in equation (??) and are therefore not reported. 2.2 Empirical Results We assume that K = 6 which corresponds to the median implementation lag in the data that we study, that R = 12, and that P = 1 (the results are robust to assuming longer lag structures). We report the impulse response functions to a one percent decrease in the tax liabilities (relative to GDP) along with 68 percent non-parametric non-centered bootstrapped confidence intervals computed from 10000 replications. The impulse response functions are shown for a forecast horizon of 24 quarters for unanticipatedtaxliabilityshocks, and for 6quartersbefore itsimplementationto24 quartersthereafter in the case of anticipated shocks. The left column of Figure 1 reports the impact of an unanticipated tax liability cut. The decrease in taxes sets off a major expansion in the economy and the effects on the endogenous variables are very persistent and follow hump shaped dynamics. Investment and consumer durables purchases display by far the largest elasticity to the cut in tax liabilities. Upon impact, investment increases by around 1 percent point and continues to rise until 10 quarters after the change in tax liabilities where it peaks at 7.6 percent above trend. Consumer durables purchases respond much the same way and peaks at 7.25 percent above trend 9 quarters after the tax cut. Output increases gradually and reaches a peak increaseof2.17percentabovetrend10quartersafterthetaxcut. Theimpactonhoursworked, instead, isestimatedtobeclosetozerountilaroundayearandahalfafterthechangeintaxes. Afterthat,hours worked increase gradually and peak at 1.16 percent above trend 12 quarters after the tax shock. The impact on consumption of nondurables and services is qualitatively different from the other variables. In particular, the increase in private consumption stabilizes at a new higher level already 6 quarters after the tax cut. The peak response of consumption of nondurables and services corresponds to a 1.07 percent rise above trend. 6 OurestimatesoftheimpactofunanticipatedtaxliabilitychangesaresimilartotheresultsofRomer and Romer (2007b) who find large and protracted responses to changes in tax liabilities. The shape of the responses are similar to the impact of a “basic government revenue shock” estimated by Mountford and Uhlig (2005). Relative to the estimates of Blanchard and Perotti (2002), the response of output to tax liability shocks occurs more gradually than the output response to the tax shock that these authors identify with a structural VAR approach. However, our results are similar to theirs in terms of the persistence of the output response. The right column of Figure 1 shows the impact of anticipated tax liability changes. There is strong evidence in favor of anticipation effects: The announcement of a future tax liability reduction sets off a downturn in the economy that lasts until the tax cut is eventually implemented. The most dramatic result pertains to investment which falls 4.9 percent below trend one year before the tax cut is implemented. The peak drop in investment is highly statistically significant. Output drops by up to 1.16 percent three quarters before the tax liability cut is implemented. The decrease in output is statistically significant from zero during almost the entire pre-implementation period. Hours worked also drop significantly below trend throughout the announcement period peaking at 1.9 percent below trend 4 quarters before the tax cut. The response of consumers’ purchases of durable goods to the announcement of a future tax cut is not very precisely estimated. We find a 3.5 percent drop in consumer durables purchases 5 quarters before the tax cut is implemented but the confidence interval is quite wide throughout the announcement period. Consumption of nondurables and services are instead approximately unaffected by the announcement of a future tax cut and is basically at trend when the tax cut is eventually implemented. Thus, the anticipation effects on the consumption variables are very different from the other variables that we investigate. Theactualimplementationoftheanticipatedtaxcutisassociatedwithanexpansionintheeconomy similar to the impact of an unanticipated tax cut. Apart from hours worked, the increase in activity occursslightly faster than in response to unanticipated tax cuts. Atforecast horizons beyond two years, anticipated and unanticipated changes in taxes have very similar effects. The maximum increase in output (a 1.5 rise above trend) occurs 9 quarters after the tax cut is implemented, while investment booms at 7.1 percent above trend (also 9 quarters after the cut in the taxes). As in the case of unantic- ipated tax cuts, the consumption response reaches its new higher level relatively quickly. The response of hours worked is somewhat weaker than the other variables in the post-implementation period (and 7 imprecisely estimated). The sizes of the implementation-to-peak responses of the endogenous variables in response to the anticipated tax cut are very similar to the peak impacts in response to unanticipated taxcuts. Thus, themaindifferencesbetweentheimpactofananticipatedandanunanticipatedchanges in taxes is that the peak response occurs earlier in the latter case. Our estimation approach gives strong support to the presence of anticipation effects. Romer and Romer (2007b) examine whether the expected present value of future not yet implemented tax changes affect the current level of key macroeconomic aggregates. They find that the pre-implementation re- sponse is oppositely signed of the post-implementation response. They conclude that there is mild evidence in favor of expectational effects. The advantage of our approach is that we analyze the full path of the adjustment of the economy from when the tax liability changes are announced until several quarters after its implementation. Mountford and Uhlig (2005) identify the impact of a pre-announced government revenue shock using an “ex-post” identification approach based on sign restrictions. In particular, they examine the impact of an government tax revenue shock which takes place one year out in the future with the restriction that the shock is orthogonal to “business cycle” shocks and monetary policy shocks. In contrast to us, they find that a pre-announced revenue increase is associated with a pre-implementation increase in output while their estimates of the impact on investment agree with our results. Their identification strategy is fundamentally different from ours since they do not include currently available information about future tax liability changes. For that reason, it is perhaps not surprising that they find a different impact of pre-announced fiscal policy shocks.6 Our results are consistent with the line of papers that have examined how anticipated tax changes affect consumption choices. Poterba (1988) and Heim (2007) fail to derive a significant consumption response to announced future tax cuts while Parker (1999) and Souleles (2002) find that consumption reactstotheimplementation ofpre-announcedtaxchanges. Theseresultsareconsistentwithoursgiven the lack of response of consumption of nondurables and services during the pre-implementation period and the increase in consumption when the tax cut is implemented. Mertens and Ravn (2009) demonstrate that the results above are extremely robust. The results do 6Moreover, as discussed by Leeper, Walker and Yang (2008), their identification is applied to government tax revenue rather than to tax liabilities relative to GDP. Thus, to the extent that tax revenue is derived from income taxation, the pre-implementation increase in output that they estimate in response to a future tax revenue increase implies that tax rates must adjust during the pre-implementation period. 8 not hinge on particular tax acts. In particular, the anticipation effects and the effects of implemented tax changes are roughly the same when we remove the Kennedy tax act, the Reagan tax acts or the Bushtaxacts. Nordotheresultsdependcruciallyonthefactthatwedonotcontrolforotherstructural shocks. When we control for either government spending shocks or for monetary policy shocks, we find much the same impact of the tax changes on the vector of observables. Importantly, Mertens and Ravn (2009a) also show that there are little if any signs that the unanticipated tax shocks have any impact on the economy before their implementation. In other words, the results do support the timing based distinction that we make between anticipated and unanticipated tax shocks. The analysis above assumes pre-announced tax changes can impact on X from a maximum 6 t quarters before their implementation. Figure 2 illustrates the impact of an anticipated tax liability cut when we vary K, the maximum anticipation horizon, between 4 and 10 quarters. Regardless of the value of K, the pre-implementation period is characterized by a recession and once the tax cut is implemented, the economy goes into a boom. However, the depth of the pre-implementation downturn and the size of the post-implementation expansion are sensitive to K. In particular, the longer the assumed maximum anticipation horizon, the deeper isthe pre-implementation downturn and the milder is the post-implementation expansion. In Section 4 we will examine whether these results are consistent with economic theory. The sensitivity of the anticipation effects to the assumed length of the maximum anticipation horizon reconciles our findings with those of Blanchard and Perotti (2002) who find little evidenceofanticipationeffectsbutallowonlyforaonequarteranticipationhorizon. Ourresultsindicate that for longer, and empirically relevant, anticipation horizons, there are significant pre-implementation effects of pre-announced tax liability changes. 3 Theory We examine whether a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium model can account for the empirical results derived above. We extend earlier DSGE models of distortionary taxation, see e.g. Baxter and King(1993),Braun(1994),McGrattan(1994)orHouseandShapiro(2006),byintroducingfeaturessuch as habit formation, adjustment costs, consumer durables, and variable capacity utilization. Burnside, Eichenbaum and Fisher (2004) also stress the importance of habit formation and adjustment costs for 9
Description: