ebook img

Tooley, T. Hunt. " Merchants Of Death Revisited: Armaments, Bankers, And The First World War." Journal Of Libertarian Studies, Vol. 19, No. 1, Winter 2005, Pp. 37 78 PDF

2005·0.48 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Tooley, T. Hunt. " Merchants Of Death Revisited: Armaments, Bankers, And The First World War." Journal Of Libertarian Studies, Vol. 19, No. 1, Winter 2005, Pp. 37 78

MERCH~OTF SD EATH REVISITED: A , B , RMAMENTS ANKERS F W W AND THE IRST ORLD AR THE YEAR 2004 MARKS the seventieth anniversary of the publication of Engelbrecht and Hanighen's Merchants of Death: A Study of the Inter- national Armament Industy,l a book that made it into the general consciousness of most thinking Americans by the mid-twentieth century. The stark language of the title no doubt contributed to its fame. Moreover, the theme of arms merchants pushing for war is both easily understood and easily discussed, even by those who have not read it. Engelbrecht and Hanighen presented a convincing historical argument that armaments manufacturers, working hand-in-hand with governments, have played a malign role in the modem world, in particular in the period of World War I. Writing in a popular for- mat for a broad readership, the authors traced the rising influence of arms manufacturers and merchants over the last several hundred years in order to put into context the dreadful conflict of 1914-1918, which is at the core of the book. The book's thesis resonated well in 1934, the early thirties forming the high-water mark of the interwar offensive against the "war system" in the United States and against intervention in foreign wars. Merchants of Death was perhaps the best known piece of this offensive.2 T. Hunt Tooley is professor of history at Austin College, Sherman, Texas; author of The Western Front: Battleground and Home Front in the First World War (Houndmills, Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan, 2003); and adjunct fac- ulty member of the Ludwig von Mises Institute. ~H.c. Engelbrecht and F.C. Hanighen, Merchants of Death: A Study of the International Armament Industry (New York: Dodd, Mead, 1934). 20ther works in this tradition include Justus Doenecke, Storm on the Hori- zon: The Challenge to American Internention, 1939-1941 (Lanham, Md.: Row- man and Littlefield, 2000); Wayne S. Cole, Roosevelt and the Isolationists, 1934-1945 (Lincoln:U niversity of Nebraska Press, 1983); and Wayne S. Cole, Senator Gerald P. Nye and American Foreign Relations (Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press, 1962). Engelbrecht and Hanighen's story connected the rise of com- plex, long-range armaments with the rise of the modern state.3 Yet it is also a story of particular individuals and companies who dealt with and against each other. Many of the arms merchants had laid the basis for their twentieth-century wealth in the nineteenth cen- tury and even earlier. The Du Pont family arms business stemmed from a powder factory opened in 1802. The Krupps had a small steel business until the middle of the century. Thomas Vickers served an apprenticeship in the Krupp company and subsequently followed the Kmpps in producing first peacetime products, and then, from the 1860s, armaments. The Vickers firm was as colorful and as sinis- ter, perhaps, as any of the arms producers, at least after joining forces with Sir Basil Zaharoff, the mysterious Greek arms merchant whose connections extended across the globe.4 One key to the success of all the arms merchants was that they held few national prejudices when it came to selling munitions and arms. So, for example, Irenee Du Pont in some cases supplied both sides with munitions in the Latin American wars for liberation after the Napoleonic period.5 The Krupp family followed a similar pat- tern, as did Schneider-Creusot in France. The Vickers Company, the most politically powerful arms company in Britain, under Sir Basil Zaharoff's leadership supplied weapons to both sides in the Boer War, despite the company's position as a kind of national treasure. Despite this tendency to supply all comers, the great arms com- panies all managed to secure a role as staunch patriots who enjoyed a special place in the "national" economy. Alfred Kmpp had expanded the family steel business to arms production by the 1840s, and was selling cannon abroad. When the Prussian army underwent reorganization in the late 1850s and early 1860s, it adopted the new Krupp artillery. The company ballooned, through the Wars of Unifi- cation, from a small plant at Essen covering two-and-a-half acres and employing a few dozen workers to a complex of 250 acres which employed 80,000 workers in 1914. The Krupp concern indeed, while continuing to sell weapons abroad, became a kind of unofficial part of Imperial Germany's government, protected from both economic 3~ number of modem scholars have explored this association, especially William H. McNeill, The Pursuit of Power: Technology, Armed Force, and Soci- ety Since A.D. 1000 (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1984); and Martin van Creveld, The Rise and Decline of the State (Cambridge: Cambridge Uni- versity Press, 1999). 4~ngelbrechat nd Hanighen, Merchants of Death, pp. 108-10. On Zaharoff, see Robert Neumann, Zaharoff the Armaments King (London: George Allen & Unwin, 1938). 5~n~elbrecahntd Hanighen, Merchants of Death, pp. 24-26. competition and the scandals produced by some of the company's leaders.6 Most of the other great arms companies behaved in the same way. As they did so, arms merchants almost always used the nature of their trade to achieve monopolistic relationships with govern- ments and a free hand at fixing prices and delimiting markets throughout their industry. By 1905, Du Pont provided all the pow- der ordered by the United States government, and the company was able on its own to "fix" prices across the board. The government charged Du Pont with violating antitrust laws in 1907, calling for price-fixing and related practices to stop, but by this time, Du Pont had eliminated most American competitors with the assistance of the government. The company supplied an enormous share of the gunpowder used by the Allied forces in World War 1.7 Similarly, the Schneider family of the French company Schnei- der-Creusot came out of the French defeat at Prussia's hands in 1871 with huge profits. Having supported Napoleon 111, the company was now equally supportive of the various Third Republic govern- ments, especially those of a nationalist coloring. Meanwhile, the company relied on the state to suppress strikes and manage discon- tent at its factories, as it supplied the army with weapons. The Schneiders eventually managed to place one of their own, Eughne Schneider, in the Chamber of Deputies, where he served throughout a period crucial to arms makers: 1900 to 1925.8 Hence, a pattern is clear: increasingly close association with the state, especially from the period of intense nationalism following the 1860s, and a ten- dency toward gaining access to public support for private profits. Already high before World War I, profits soared during it. Before the third year of World War I, Krupp had more than doubled its huge profits of the immediate prewar period-to the level of 66 mil- lion marks annually. In Austria-Hungary, Skoda likewise doubled its profits during the early war years. On the other side of the Atlantic, profits surged still higher. U.S. Steel netted $105 million annually before the war, $239,653,000 during it. Du Pont's numbers in the same two categories were $6,092,000 annually before the war, to a staggering yearly average of $58,076,000 during the war. These results were repeated in dozens of smaller and subsidiary arms com- panies throughout the belligerent countries.9 Such are the episodes which Engelbrecht and Hanighen trace. %id., pp. 71-84. On the Krupp empire, see also William Manchester, The Arms of Krupp (Boston: Little, Brown, 1964). 7~ngelbrechatn d Hanighen, Merchants of Death, pp. 22-37. gIbid., pp. 121-25. 9Ibid., pp. 159-79. The revisionist historian Harry Elmer Barnes wrote the book's Foreword, praising it as an expos6 of the armaments industry and the willingness of the American government to be persuaded and manipulated by it. But he does make a proviso about the topic which is fairly dramatic, coming as it does in a part of the book itself: Even though the armament makers have played a prominent part in encouraging wars, rebellions and border raids, they never exerted so terrible an influence upon the promotion of warfare as did our American bankers between 1914 and 1917. Through their " pressure to put the United States into the War, these bankers brought about results which have well nigh wrecked the contem- porary world.10 As a matter of fact, J.P. Morgan & Co. and other American bank- ing institutions come into Engelbrecht and Hanighen's story in ways consistent with the behavior mentioned by Barnes, but they do not play the central role, at least not in their capacity as banks per se. The focus of the book is arms and munitions manufacturers like Du Pont, but the authors are clear on the role of the banks: All arms makers have important financial connections. In the Mor- gan group will be found the Du Pont Company, the Bethlehem Steel Corporation, the U.S. Steel Corporation, together with cop- per, oil, electric appliances, locomotive, telephone and telegraph interests. This tie-up also leads over into the great banks, including the National City, Corn Exchange, Chase National, etc. It is the Morgan group of corporation clients and banks which dominates the American arms industry.ll Engelbrecht and Hanighen point out that internationalization of boards and companies allowed banks and arms companies to have a purchase on any situation, no matter what ties of "loyalty" might be invoked. At the same time, their more-or-less constant relation- ship with any foreign government to which they sold arms allowed them easy access to the local press. Influencing the populace, and hence public policy, through propaganda became commonplace. When a war scare was needed, it was quite possible to create one by maximizing reports of existing tensions in the press.12 In evaluating Merchants of Death, it is important to emphasize that the topic of the bankers' influence on American intervention into the First World War was very much a public issue in 1934. For one thing, the extensive investigations of the Senate Munitions lo~bid.p, . viii. lll'bid., p. 141. %id., pp. 14143. Inquiry (the Nye Committee)-a congressional investigation of the role of arms manufacturers in the war--completed in early 1936 an expos6 of bribery and corruption among American arms manufac- turers such as Du Pont, Whitney Aircraft Company, Sperry Gyro- scope, and others. Most of these companies had indeed provided arms to a wide range of customers, sometimes on both sides in the same war.13 From another direction, it was also in the early and mid-1930s that dissident Marine General Smedley Butler began criticizing the interventionist activities of international bankers, drawing on his personal experience at the sharp end of empire and war. His book on the topic appeared at the same moment as did Merchants of Death. His central point is summed up in a famous passage from his speeches and publications: War is just a racket. A racket is best described, I believe, as some- thing that is not what it seems to the majority of people. Only a small inside group knows what it is about. It is conducted for the benefit of the very few at the expense of the masses.14 Indeed, the whole array of financial arrangements of the inter- war period, from the Paris Peace and reparations to the Young Plan to the trade wars of the 1930s revolved around the names of Morgan, the Rockefeller interests, Kuhn, Loeb & Co., and related banking and commercial concerns. Apart from Hitler and Hindenburg, perhaps no German individual was better known in the United States than Hjalmar Horace Greeley Schacht, the banker and wizard of the Ger- man economy from World War I to the late thirties.15 Certainly, the study of both groups-arms makers and bankers-finds not only similar behaviors but often the same indi- viduals. Broadly speaking (and this goes for arms makers and bankers throughout the European world), both groups constituted international operations that justified influence over their own gov- ernments by their supposed patriotism. Yet both used their own governments to subsidize their operations and produce enormous profit. Both arms makers and bankers were active in handing out 13~ohnE . Wiltz, In Search of Peace: The Senate Munitions Inquiry, 1934-1936 (Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press, 1965). The report of the Nye Committee, often called the Nye Report, is in U.S. Senate, Special Commit- tee Investigating the Munitions Industry, 73rd Cong., 2nd sess., 1936. 14Smedley D. Butler, War is a Racket (New York: Round Table Press, 1935). 15Schacht's 1953 memoirs appeared in translation in the United States with the title Confessions of the Old Wizard: The Autobiography of Hjalmar Horace Greeley Schacht (New York: Houghton Mifflin, 1956). subventions to the press in order to shape public opinion in needed ways. Perhaps most importantly, the interests of both groups lay in a cycle of conflict. The arms makers needed conflict for huge demand and close relations with the governments being supplied. But they also needed bouts of armed peace or cold war to upgrade technologies and sell their new goods. The bankers likewise needed conflict as a way of financing governments' war efforts overall, forg- ing all kinds of ties with those governments, and gaining govern- ment help in crushing their business rivals or taking them over. Yet times of peace were especially important for bankers, because even greater profits were forthcoming from reconstruction efforts after a conflict was over, counted then not by millions but by billions. The nature of armaments technology before and during the First World War made the terms of the "destruction-reconstruction" nexus far more extreme. Advances in artillery, above all, made shellfire more powerful, more accurate, and more destructive of lives and property. Artillery stood at the center of war tactics in 1914, and became even more predominant as the war progressed. The result was maximum destruction. For interests which combined arms production with investment banking, maximum destruction meant maximum oppor- tunity for profits from reconstruction after the war.16 A few figures will give an idea of the scope of destruction. At the Armistice, the Entente powers on the Western Front and the Italian Front had in their lines 29,315 artillery pieces.17 Shelling was more- or-less constant along all fronts, especially the Western Front. It intensified with attacks, and the pre-attack explosives expended in shells or mines tended to increase as the war went along. Artillery shells came in many varieties, and by the end of the war, they were raining high explosive, shrapnel, burning heavy metals, gas, and other death-dealing substances down on enemy positions. The zone of destruction on the Western Front alone was roughly 400 miles long by 50 miles wide. Of these roughly 20,000 square miles, some substantial segments remain today so thoroughly impregnated with chemicals, live explosives, and other detritus of war that they are still "red-zoned" by the French government-that is, habitation is simply forbidden, and no economic activity is allowed, except log- ging in some cases. Some villages are today remembered only by reunion associations, since the families have been scattered to live elsewhere since 1914.18 l6~ooleyT,h e Western Front, pp. 88-93. 17~andaGl ray and Christopher Argyle, Chronicle of the First World War (New York: Facts On File, 1991), vol. 2, p. 288. l8~oar general description of the zone itself, see Tooley, The Western Front, pp. 258-63. The destruction was enormous, and the inefficiencies of "recon- struction" combined government bureaucratic highhandedness with the "reconstruction" elements of "reparation" deals which con- tinued for over a decade after the war. Indeed, the little-investigated story of the actual reconstruction of France, Belgium, and the other reparation recipients is beyond the scope of this study, but it is a story that contains elements one might expect from nearly a century of experience with such processes: politicization of "reconstruction," monopolistic relationships between governments and companies chosen to do the reconstructing, and various other financial tech- niques associated with government programs.19 Engelbrecht and Hanighen worked against this background, and also from the perspective of the populist historical revisionism which formed an important component of the intellectual move- ment against aggressive war. During the vibrant discussions of American intervention in the war, imperialism, and militarism dur- ing the 1930s and afterward, most of the "mainstream" historians in American academe were missing in action. Indeed, under the renewed waves of war and destruction which began only five years after the publication of Merchants of Death, all but the staunchest American critics of the warfare state were overwhelmed. The name of the book lived on, it is true, but in caricature form, so that by the 1960s and 1970s, college professors could assert, without having read it, that the Merchants of Death "theory" was that World War I had come about solely because of the makers of munitions and armaments-a simplification which the authors explicitly rejected.20 Since the Second World War, scholarly historical literature on armaments and the origins of World War I have tended to cast the issue in terms of an armaments competition among the Great Pow- ers of Europe. Historians have argued over whether naval arma- ments were more significant in this regard, or whether land-based weaponry played the major role in the ~om~etition.2S1ti ll, the assumption at the heart of any such interpretation is that the arms 19The best study of reconstruction is the recent work by Hugh D. Clout, After the Ruins: Restoring the Countryside of Northern France After the Great War (Exeter, U.K.: University of Exeter Press, 1996). 20~ngelbrechatn d Hanighen, Merchants of Death, pp. 5-11. 21~enxt ensive argument for the importance of naval armaments in the com- ing of the war is Paul Kennedy, The Rise of the Anglo-German Antagonism (New York: Allen & Unwin, 1980). Two recent works speak convincingly for the primacy of land-based weapons in the arms competition: David G. Herr- mann, The Arming of Europe and the Making of the First World War (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1996); and David Stevenson, Armaments and the Coming of the War: Europe, 1904-1914 (New York: Clarendon Press, 1996). "race" which preceded World War I was in a sense automatic: Euro- pean states built more arms when they observed other states build- ing more arms. Engelbrecht and Hanighen examine more convinc- ing historical instrumentalities in that they provide at least a history which is full of contingencies and individual motivations, rather than a history which seems predetermined. Yet, by and large, his- torical scholarship has paid little lasting attention to the idea that armaments makers encouraged states to go to war. Likewise, in terms of the bankers and their role in armaments and the making of war, the great crusade of the Second World War wiped out much of the existing interest in this topic as well as many others. The earlier critique was largely forgotten in the heady war for freedom against the Axis Powers. Perhaps, in addition, the finan- cial elites themselves did more in the way of publicity to make them seem a necessary and important part of the American struggle for "freedom" here and abroad. The general subject of the influence of international banking and business has been at the core of some prominent dissenting inter- pretations of the modern world, including interpretations from widely separated points on any given political spectrum. Large bod- ies of popular literature on the malign influence of the bankers and big business exist and have existed since at least the late nineteenth century. A thorough and satisfying scholarly treatment of this his- torical subject has yet to be written, but many parts of this story have been investigated, both from within academia and outside it. The following sections of this essay constitute an attempt, first, to assess Engelbrechtfs and Hanighen's insights into the broad topic of bankers and big business in World War I in light of the serious liter- ature which has emerged in the seventy years since its publication. From the components of this historiography, we will explore as well the outlines of a broad reconstruction of the relationships involved. OTHER SCHOLARS CONSIDER THE ISSUE From the scholarly world, a mainstream historical literature on the enormous influence of big business and banking on United States intervention in the First World War began to emerge only in the 1960s, and it was fairly limited even then.22 221 am using the terms "mainstream" and "scholarly" in this article to indi- cate the academic world of university-trained historians (and economists and political scientists, etc.). It is worth noting that the graduate education of a large percentage of academics writing the history discussed herein have been supported by foundations related to many of the companies men- tioned in this article. For example, the present writer was a Du Pont Fellow at the University of Virginia during one stage of his doctoral work. Gabriel Kolko and the New Left New Left revisionism, especially the work of Gabriel Kolko, made it into the mainstream of the historical and political con- sciousness at this time, but the Marxist biases of many New Left revisionists rendered their work off-putting to many scholars who might have been interested in broadening the discussion and taking up the topic of international banking and its relationship to World War 1.23 As the New Left critique of American interventionism, or parts of it, entered the mainstream of the American historical pro- fession in the 1970s and 1980s, the whole topic of the banks tended to drop out of the argument. Some interest in the influence of bankers on the First World War has reemerged with younger scholars in the 1990s, but hardly any note of disapproval remains in these works, in which monopolistic business and international bankers in particular are seen to be pow- erful, but well-intentioned and altr~istic.~~ Georges-Henri Soutou Recent works on the economic diplomacy of the First World War have been few, but Georges-Henri Soutou's magisterial monograph on the economic war aims of all the belligerents should be men- tioned here. Soutou's work is not especially critical of the role of 23~olkhoa s dealt with this theme repeatedly, but his classic statement of the problem is Gabriel Kolko, The Triumph of Conservatism: A Re-Interpretation of American History, 1900-1916 (Chicago: Quadrangle Books, 1963). Some stu- dents of New Left revisionists such as Kolko, William Appleman Williams, and Lloyd Gardner continued to work on these topics for some time. See, for example, Harry N. Scheiber, "World War I as Entrepreneurial Opportunity: Willard Straight and the American International Corporation," Political Sci- ence Quarterly 84 (September 1969): 486-511; Gail L. Owen, "Dollar Diplo- macy in Default: The Economics of Russian-American Relations, 1910-1917," Historical Journal 13, no. 2 (1970): 251-72; and Roberta A. Dayer, "Strange Bedfellows: J.P. Morgan & Co., Whitehall, and the Wilson Admin- istration During World War I," Business History 18 (1976): 127-51. 24!%e, for example, Priscilla Roberts, "Willard D. Straight and the Diplo- macy of International Finance during the First World War," Business History 40 (1998): 16- 47; Martin Horn, Britain, France, and the Financing of the First World War (Montreal: McGill-Queen's University Press, 2002); Martin Horn, "A Private Bank at War: J.P. Morgan & Co. and France, 1914-1918," Business History Review 74 (Spring 2000): 85-112; and Jeffrey Frieden, "The Econom- ics of Intervention: American Overseas Investments and Relations with Underdeveloped Areas, 1890-1950," Comparative Studies in Society and His- tory 31 (January 1989): 55-80. business on national policy in one way or the other, but his study- based chiefly on archival materials-is massive, and his conclusions are in many ways consistent with the thesis of Merchants of Death. Soutou's analysis of American bankers and American policy is particularly useful here. He attributes a great deal of direct influence by investment bankers and business on the decisions of Wilson and his administration. In Soutou's interpretation, almost all the Ameri- can political and financial elites viewed the war as an opportunity for the expansion of American capital and American influence. The pre-intervention phase of the war represents for Soutou a period in which Wilson tended to be swayed by "hemispheric" arguments that the United States should continue and indeed expand its political and economic power in Latin America, argu- ments which came to Wilson most significantly through William Gibbs McAdoo, a former corporate lawyer who was Wilson's Secre- tary of the Treasury and son-in-law. McAdoo was associated with a specific group of banks and corporations who stood to gain if their activities in Latin America received even more subsidizing from the American public. Yet after late 1916, Soutou argues, Wilson became convinced by the arguments for an "Atlantic" (Anglo-American) outlook repre- sented by Secretary of State Robert Lansing, the Federal Reserve Board, and the Morgan group. In the end, according to Soutou, American entry into the war was not solely due to economic causes, although many influences from circles of high finance influenced policy. On the other hand, he says, American entry had very direct and massive economic consequences, and it signaled an expansion of American economic goals from the old hemispheric plans to the world scale.25 Carroll Quigley On the other hand, Carroll Quigley, a longtime professor of his- tory at Georgetown University and establishment historian contem- porary with the New Left revisionists-but very far from any revi- sionist camp-attributed a great influence to Anglo-American banking concerns. One of Quigley's research specialties was the his- tory of banking and finance in the nineteenth and twentieth cen- turies, and this research is reflected in his books Tragedy and Hope (1966) and The Anglo-American Establishment (written in 1949). In these works, Quigley described explicitly a kind of secret, benevo- lent "network consisting of international bankers and connected 25~eor~es-~eSnourito u, L'or et le sang: les buts de guerre kconomiques de la premi2re guerre mondiale (Paris: Fayard, 1989), pp. 35-11.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.