ebook img

The urban village, agrarian transformation, and rentier capitalism in Gurgaon, India PDF

24 Pages·2017·2.7 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The urban village, agrarian transformation, and rentier capitalism in Gurgaon, India

Thomas Cowan The urban village, agrarian transformation, and rentier capitalism in Gurgaon, India Article (Published version) (Refereed) Original citation: Cowan, Thomas (2018) The urban village, agrarian transformation, and rentier capitalism in Gurgaon, India. Antipode. ISSN 0066-4812 (In Press) DOI: 10.1111/anti.12404 © 2018 The Author CC BY 4.0 This version available at: http://eprints.lse.ac.uk/89699/ Available in LSE Research Online: August 2018 LSE has developed LSE Research Online so that users may access research output of the School. Copyright © and Moral Rights for the papers on this site are retained by the individual authors and/or other copyright owners. Users may download and/or print one copy of any article(s) in LSE Research Online to facilitate their private study or for non-commercial research. You may not engage in further distribution of the material or use it for any profit-making activities or any commercial gain. You may freely distribute the URL (http://eprints.lse.ac.uk) of the LSE Research Online website. A Radical Journal of Geography The Urban Village, Agrarian Transformation, and Rentier Capitalism in Gurgaon, India Thomas Cowan Department of Geography andEnvironment, London School ofEconomics andPolitical Science, London,UK; [email protected] Abstract: Gurgaon, India’s “millennium city”, is today synonymous with India’s embrace of global real estate capital and private sector-led urban development. This paper asserts that Gurgaon’s spectacular urbanisation has been fundamentally under- pinned by an uneven process of land acquisition, exemption and agrarian transforma- tion. Shifting away from dispossession-centred analyses of contemporary urbanisation in India, this paper explores Gurgaon’s “urban villages” to consider the uneven integration of agrarian classes into emerging urban real estate markets. Through an examination of differential experiences of land acquisition and agrarian social change among Gurgaon’s landowning classes, the paper seeks to trace complex and nonlinear processes of agrar- ian transformation whichmakepossiblelandscapes of globalaccumulation. Keywords: India, accumulation by dispossession, urban studies, agrarian transitions, urbanvillages, articulation Inlate2015,IsatwithMukeshYadavinBadshahpururbanvillageinGurgaoninthe north Indian state of Haryana. Badshahpur had been incorporated into the city in theGurgaon-ManesarUrbanDevelopmentplan2021,bringingexpansesofthevil- lage’s agricultural land into the urban real estate market. In 2010, agricultural land salesinBadshahpurspikedafteragroupofdeveloperslobbiedtheHaryanagovern- ment to expand the urbanisable area to include a further 2000 acres of land in neighbouringSohna(TimesofIndia2015).Mukeshsoldhisfouracresofagricultural landin2008toUnitech,oneofthelargestrealestatedevelopersinthecountry,for 30 lakh rupees per acre, earning himself 1.2 crore from the land sale.1 Haryana’s urban planning legislation exempts all residential [abadi] village land from urban landacquisitionandplanninganddevelopmentregulations,leavingpocketsofrural “urban village” land, like that of Badshahpur, peppered across cities like Gurgaon. SeekingtocapitaliseonrumoursofSohna’spendingurbanisation,Mukeshusedthe cashfromhisagriculturallandsaletobuyeightacresoflandinnorthernSohna.He remarked: “I built myself a pukka house and bought some land over in Sohna, let’s seeifwecansellit...landistheonlywaywecanmakemoneythesedays”. Along with his investment in peri-urban agricultural land, Mukesh had joined a group of fellow villagers to invest in a new shopping mall development in central Gurgaon. The developer leading the project had drawn in 160 crore rupees of investment from around 350 small landholders like Mukesh across south Gurgaon. AntipodeVol.0No.02018ISSN0066-4812,pp.1–23 doi:10.1111/anti.12404 ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd. This is an open access article under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits use, distributionandreproductioninanymedium,providedtheoriginalworkisproperlycited. 2 Antipode Unbeknown to Mukesh, the developer had not received a license for the develop- ment. Three years after their initial investment the shopping mall was nowhere to be seen. Mukesh remarked: “We were scammed, looted. All of us here invested, each of us gave five lakh, ten lakh, twenty lakh ... the developer’s in jail now”. Mukesh and his friends who I sat and discussed real estate business with that afternoon were eager to impress that, despite their active participation in real estate markets across the city, Gurgaon’s rapid urbanisation was no success story for the landowners who remain in the exempt urban villages. Mukesh insisted: “Listen son, we are peasants, we are in a situation without future nor past. We should never have sold our land”. Gurgaon, India’s “millennium city”, is today synonymous with India’s embrace of global real estate capital and privatised modes of urban development (Gururani 2013; Searle 2016). This paper argues that, the “Gurgaon model” of urbanisation, which has transformed 35,000 acres of agricultural land into urban property since the 1980s (Gururani 2013), has been fundamentally underpinned by an uneven process of agrarian transformation, involving the exemption of residential abadi land from urbanisation, the designation of “urban villages” as rural, and the dif- ferentiated integration of landowning communities into emerging networks of urban rentier accumulation (see Figure 1).2 As my encounter with Mukesh suggests, Gurgaon’s story is not one of wholesale agrarian transition, led by a unitary “carrier class” of landowning capitalists (Byres 1991), nor one of dispossession and the violent expropriation of land by the state andglobalcapital(Levien2013).RatherurbanandindustrialdevelopmentinIndia’s “millennium city” has been facilitated by an uneven process of land acquisition, exemption and agrarian transformation. This highly differentiated process of agrar- iantransformation intheregionhasmediateddominantlandowningcommunities’ Figure 1: New residential developments on Kherki Duala village land in Gurgaon ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd. The Urban Village: Gurgaon, India 3 opposition to rapid agrarian change, unevenly integrated well-placed villagers into urban land markets, while constraining others like Mukesh to petty rentiership and speculativeinvestmentsinlandandpropertyacrossthecity.3 Nowhere is this process of differentiation more evident than in the peculiar space of the urban village. In this paper I conceptualise the “urban villages”, areas of land deep within the city designated “rural”, as social and spatial articulations of Gurgaon’s uneven capitalist development (Hall 1980). In doing so, this paper explores how Gurgaon’s contemporary urbanisation is underpinned by both specific histories of agrarian reform which paved the way for the emergence of urban villages in the early 1980s, and differentiated experiences of agrarian change among Gurgaon’s landowning communities. As Mukesh’s statement sug- gests, processes of “global” urbanisation, characterised by some as “planetary” in nature (Brenner and Schmid 2014), are not defined wholly by logics of an eternal “urban” capital, but are rather constituted through the uneven articulation of multiple, unequal logics of land, territory and value. In this paper I draw on Hall’s (1980) influential work on capitalist development in South Africa, alongside the Marxist agrarian transition debates (Byres 1991; Chari 2004; Hart 1998), to disrupt analyses which understand India’s “remarkable urban moment” as either coherently “urban” or dispossessive in nature, empha- sising the differentiated and subversive internal relations (Hart 2006) that under- score Gurgaon’s spectacular production as a site of “global” capital accumulation. The production of differentiated landscapes of accumulation in Gurgaon, in this respect, are not simply a consequence of the uniform development of a global capital, but rather hold to an uneven “molecular existence” (Gidwani 2008), a dominating structure that articulates with a variety of contingent social relation- ships, modes of (re)production, and forms of value to produce uneven and differ- entiated landscapes of accumulation. In order to explore this differentiated and spatially uneven process of agrarian change, I will first examine the agrarian transition debates which have long chal- lenged Eurocentric dispossession-centred understandings of capitalist urban devel- opment and examine the multiple, nonlinear and locally mediated ways in which capitals develop in different contexts. Building from this, the first half of the paper will explore how Haryana’s urban planning legislation, alongside the state’s uneven agrarian transition throughout the post-Independence period came to produce “urban villages” across Gurgaon, a phenomenon which would shape the agrarian social structure in ways crucial for urbanisation from the early 1980s. The second half of the paper will then explore how the Gurgaon’s spatially uneven process of urbanisation is expressed in both uneven articulations of “urban” and “rural”, and differentiated processes of rentier accumulation engaged in by the city’s former landowning classes. Beyond Dispossession Dispossession is something of a master narrative within contemporary urban stud- ies.FromMarx’sformulationof“primitiveaccumulation”inhisstudyoftheEnglish enclosures, to the “new enclosures”literatures (DeAngelis2001;Sanyal2007) and ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd. 4 Antipode Harvey’s (2003) influential expansion in “accumulation by dispossession”; dispos- sessionshavebeenunderstoodasfoundationaltoprocessesofurbanandindustrial development the world over (Sassen 2014). Within the Indian context, this schol- arlytraditionhasbeenmobilisedtounderstandtheIndianstate’sattemptstofacili- tate capital’s access to large swathes of rural land through eminent domain in the post-liberalisation period (Banerjee-Guha 2013; Bhattacharya and Sanyal 2011). Sanyal (2007), for example, mobilises Marx’s primitive accumulation to conceptu- alise “postcolonial capital” in India as a dual process of violent capitalist expulsion and state-led developmental rehabilitation, productive of the hyper-exclusionary and unequal landscapes of new urban India (Bhattacharya and Sanyal 2011). For Sanyal, “postcolonial capital” is as such constituted as a “complex” of a stable, dis- possession-centredcapitalandadistorting andmarginalisednon-capital. Yet what sets Gurgaon apart from these narratives of dispossessive urbanisation is the leading role the private real estate sector has played in land acquisitions. In Gurgaon there are few outright “dispossessions”, 85% of urban land in the city was bought by developers on the real estate market. Indeed an examination of the manner in which land was acquired by the real estate sector over the past 30 years (see Table 1) reveals a process of urbanisation mediated by the complex articulation of emerging real estate actors, agrarian land reforms, urban planning regulations and existing inequalities in the agrarian social structure. In this paper, against analyses which foreground dispossession as a universal attribute of a stable capitalist urban, I seek to develop an understanding of the dialectical and uneven internal relations which constitute landscapes of capital in specific historical and geographical milieus. In doing so, I seek to draw from the Marxist agrarian tradition which has long sought to break from conceptions of capitalist development which centre on the unfolding of a stable European form within multiple, different contexts (Chari 2004; Gidwani 2008; Hart 1998). Articulation and Agrarian Transitions The classical “agrarian question” as discussed by Lenin (1964) and Kautsky (1988) was concerned with how, in different historical contexts, predatory landed prop- erty, the peasantry and feudal agrarian relations are overcome and capitalist social relations established. Central to the agrarian tradition as such has been the quest to break from the canonical English model of primitive accumulation and map out the multiple ways in which capitalism has developed in differing contexts. In this regard, Byres’ (1991, 1996) influential development of the agrarian question was concerned with the particular, differential conditions which lead to “success- ful” agrarian transition; the conditions within agriculture which contribute to pri- mary accumulation for the purposes of industrialisation (Byres 1991:11–12). This, according to Byres, does not always require the development of capitalism within the countryside, rather for Byres the agrarian question can be effectively “re- solved” when the agrarian social structure no longer presents significant obstacles to capitalist development (Byres 1991:11–12). Crucially, this may be achieved through any number of means not limited to the English model of enclosures. ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd. The Urban Village: Gurgaon, India 5 More recently, in an influential essay, Bernstein (2006) challenges the enduring relevance of the “agrarian question of capital” in the wake of post-colonial agrar- ian reform and the advent of globalisation. For Bernstein, both colonial interven- tion and post-colonial agrarian land reforms enacted throughout through the 19th and 20th centuries had resolved the question of non-capitalist agrarian rela- tions globally. As such, for Bernstein non-capitalist social relations in the coun- tryside no longer pose an obstacle to processes of proletarianisation nor agricultural capitalist development. Further, Bernstein (2006) following Byres (1996) argues that the “developmental” agrarian question, that of how to gener- ate agricultural-industrial linkages to spur capitalist development, a preoccupation of many post-colonial governments throughout the 20th century, is today largely bypassed by the wide availability of global capital. Upon the opening up of global markets in the late 20th century, the imperative to develop national agricultural linkages to spur industrial development have weakened; the agrarian question of capital, according to Bernstein, resolved by global capital. Indeed it has been argued that such a “resolution” can be seen in dynamics of economic transformation in contemporary India. Since formal liberalisation of the Indian economy in the early 1990s, there has been a dramatic growth in Finance, Services and Real Estate (FSRE) sectors and collapse in agriculture. In 1951 the ser- vices sector contributed a 30% share of total GDP, a figure that rose to 38% in 1981 and 60% in 2014. Within that same period, agriculture declined from 52% to 14%, while industry increased modestly from 16% to 26%.4 It is in this sense that scholars argue India has experienced industry-less growth (Maurya and Vaishampayan 2012). While organised manufacturing accounted for 14% of GDP and 13% of the workforce in 2012, the FSRE sector accounted for 20% and 2% respectively (Chandrasekhar and Ghosh 2014). Such phenomena, Lerche (2013) argues, indicates that by the 1990s the Indian economy had little need for agri- cultural capital transfers nor rural primary markets. Yet such capital-centric understandings of agrarian change which purport a “resolution” to the agrarian question and successful “completion” of agrarian transition ignore the enduring internal contradictions which riddle the uneven development of capital, and underestimate the crucial ways in which historically and geographically specific agrarian determinates continue to be deeply impli- cated into contemporary capitalist development (Watts and Goodman 1997). Byres’ contributions to debates on the agrarian question are so useful precisely because they allow us to think about “transitions” not as unilinear, nor as unfold- ing from a stable economic logic, but rather as the multiple, heterogeneous social and spatial articulations of capitalist development within particular historical and geographical milieus. As Watts and Goodman (1997:13) argue, the intersectoral surplus flows of agrarian transitions are not only “surplus value via terms of trade ... but in social, cultural and institutional terms as well ... [their] origins are prefig- ured in agrarian settings”. In this regard, postcolonial Marxist agrarian scholarship (Chari 2004; Gidwani 2008; Hart 1998) draws attention to the central role in which “difference” plays in constituting capitalist social relations, and the impor- tance of locally specific histories and social dynamics in obstructing or facilitating urban and industrial development. ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd. 6 Antipode The postcolonial Marxist agrarian literature (Chari 2017; Hart 2006) produc- tively speaks to and at times explicitly draws from Hall’s (1980) influential work on capitalist development in Apartheid South Africa. Here Hall explores the ways in which race is put to work within a specific historical conjuncture to actively structure uneven development of capital in South Africa. Against analyses which understand economic and social relations as distinct, coherent phenomena, Hall calls for an understanding of capitalist hegemony as articulated through multiple, historically specific practices of race, class and capital. Crucially, Hall expands an Althusserian reading of “articulation” by focusing on the articulation of materiality with historically specific meanings, experiences and practices (Chari 2017). For Hall, the racialization of modes of production in South Africa is not “eternal”, but under constant renewal through discourses, lived experiences and practices. In the remainder of this paper I seek to show the ways in which Gurgaon’s “ur- ban villages” materially and discursively articulate the city’s uneven and differen- tial urbanisation; deeply entangled and augmented by regionally specific agrarian histories. As Roy (2016) notes, the agrarian question in India today is deeply entangled in the urban land question; that of translating complex histories of agrarian settlement into urban property relations legible to global and domestic capital. While sectoral linkages from the agricultural sector may have been “by- passed” in the advent of liberalisation in India, Gurgaon’s agrarian transition con- tinues to have enduring material and discursive relevance to the particular development of urban and industrial accumulation in the city. In the following section, I will explore the particular social forces which aug- mented real estate capital’s access to rural land on market prices. Gurgaon’s pecu- liar agrarian change has magnified fractures within the dominant landowning caste, between those fully incorporated into urban land markets and those who tentatively participate in petty rentiership and land and property speculation. Such fragmentation draws attention to the ways in which agrarian transitions implicated in Gurgaon’s urban and industrial development are highly differenti- ated, laminated by existing agrarian inequalities, meanings and practices. In order to understand these articulations we must first explore the particular conditions which gave rise to Gurgaon’s urban villages. The Urban Village Planning the Urban Villages The presence of urban villages in Gurgaon can be traced to agrarian land reforms and urban planning regulations in Haryana from the 1960s. In 1963, while Har- yana remained a region of the state of Punjab, the influential Chief Minister Par- tap Singh Kairon passed the Punjab Scheduled Roads and Controlled Areas Restriction of Unregulated Development Act (PSRCA). The PSRCA sought to con- trol and regulate urban development in the state by identifying urbanisable areas within which the transferral of agricultural to urban land would be managed by a parastatal urban development authority. In the Haryana region, this was dele- gated to the Haryana Urban Development Authority, hereafter HUDA. ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd. The Urban Village: Gurgaon, India 7 Crucially, the PSRCA excluded all village residential abadi land from urbanisa- tion. Abadi lands, what are today termed urban villages, are demarcated from urbanisable land by the lal dora, a boundary line between agricultural and village residential land invented by colonial governors to distinguish residential from agricultural taxable areas. As a consequence, as rapid urbanisation began in earn- est in Gurgaon in the early 1980s, the state and private sector were only able to purchase agricultural land, leaving pockets of urban village land deep within urban areas excluded from land acquisition and HUDA’s development and plan- ning regulations. In Gururani’s (2013) exposition of the “flexible” planning tech- nologies which ensconced the development trajectory of Gurgaon, the author notes that amidst the fervent political jockeying between Haryana politicians and real-estate developers in the early 1980s, the boundary lines of PSRCA-designated urban areas were routinely redrawn and improvised to accommodate the inter- ests of various political pacts. As of 2011, there were 94 urban villages within the Gurgaon-Manesar Urban Complex (see Figure 2). The PSRCA is characteristic of Nehruvian developmentalism that sought to pro- tect landowners from state land acquisition, and regulate urbanisation through modernist planning and development technologies (Roy 2007). This protection is especially pertinent in Haryana, where dominant landowning caste communities, the Jats and Yadavs, are both politically and socially dominant. In 1975 the Haryana Chief Minister, Bansi Lal, passed the Haryana Development and Regulation of Urban Areas Act (HDRUA) that allowed landowners to acquire development licenses from the State government for the purchase and develop- ment of land within controlled areas. While under the short stewardship of Bansi Lal licenses were reserved for HUDA projects, after the 1979 election of pro-business Bhajan Lal, licenses were opened up to the private sector, initiating a process of private sector-led urban development which would later come to be known as the “Gurgaon model”. HDRUA allowed developers to directly negotiate and purchase land from landowners within controlled areas. During this period Gurgaon had no municipal level government; instead the city was governed directly by municipal council through the Chief Minister’s office. As Gururani (2013) notes, this centralisation of jurisdiction provided the Chief Minister significant power in negotiating with real- estate developers, improvising urban planning codes, and issuing development licenses. In this manner, while the HDRUA’s initial purpose was to introduce a for- mal system of land development to be managed and regulated by HUDA, from the 1980s onwards successive Haryana Chief Ministers, who had sole discretionary power to authorise development licenses, utilised the legislation to authorise the sale of vast tracts of agricultural land5 in the region (Hiro 2015). Bhajan Lal, for example, allocated 6000 acres in development licenses to the private sector between 1979 and 1996. The HDRUA is significant to the contemporary landscape of Gurgaon for at least two reasons. First, while the PSRCA gave the state government “powers of relax- ation” in land use change, the HDRUA bypassed the requirements for land use change approvals within the urbanisable area altogether. The urbanisable areas of Gurgaon—at the time agricultural land—were at once prefigured as urban, ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd. 8 Antipode DU ED36S511A27A4 89 0EI0000SS000L 00PS N0S000S000 0E 0 0T R T ATI 0 (D T GOR H H STT8IPPR SMOC5558366763366778 8 T444AR.O.NMKRMCSWV N N-GRR K9E..2135 413 1234526212125 GTUP5TU A UUREALAAIOEGOEE.0P000 00000000000000TD000 ALU A DA O NDTTU SNCTI EW B TTT N BLEOLT BBSA T R E RRMIC O I N W ITT ARUARNWD TMON E C CE SN WG ADWGLLINMSCMLELFHMSMCDPWMRBTGHONLDGGOEWRIUGRDT MNIUNSAIAO:CETDPAB UIILFHEUEPAIIRAIEEAGRTAAHAANEOSS EB- A NCCAANYNREANL RBOROEURAFTAIST ALAISCDDRE)IE TTHP UOPRLRLY DLIRNE APIDTODOOTELVKPLS N CERU LCE.IIEKWRNLAOTSL TSPPAR CUNAUPIYOBUL H NINYSSUODS NLMOOGATNEURRECIRU ANATESSLZAHPAMIL AITAR.IC TUANTSCTITNFDTFTD NE O/AAGOINIECNAATAEYAWLB DRONNN OT A EIE AIB DNDU C AN ILICADOGRLHANDRS GINNAA LNOOLANIMDNLAL RSO AATEUR NDLN SDE P WOENRRAREWN NFDDECO/UNE LTEMIINNRRAOS Y ,TRLOESTNAORTEN DDWUIN EROASDAENS OLADNSKETIEAAS RLSRA(DN-RU EIYSAAT. MRTRIOSRCODSXTGNF, R,HELTT AEG EA RNTGN BYIMCY/CMKORCHTIEIY OLTNSDRIAYDT R DORRAZGNSHU/HKUMAA IIT NUYT/TISO IGUR ELO AOULK BCVM/P,STCT,P N TNDTARO NE,SRUJPEISH EUANUOH UD,OHUO SUGEIBLH ETIORVSRN NSAT-DWPT EAOEIA 6/BMCEPNIL(AS HRUSIDIDD LU(( CIR,I SOLJVLTMH AYPARWIIIMILN.LICNN,TUII ALIAL JEITIPBMNORDOCTEIKGEMAO ULRTU .ANP OEANENR S SUSU GKTCAANZLRL DUCPSLHT,TIHIOTI NOASEDYOEEAGHPIIH N SUO MACRGRN NR LII EPITS NNHRO NENEMPA(SAMSNARADHALEUSEFLYAITEGTRAENAATTE)S I ERWV GDOGCRLXRI /CLIEILHEOPANRNS O(N, NS)T DB JOSLH-OWN-),A5CO E TUMUO0OEIH 0RIRLNGEB UTP2ET,)HDD U 5RE &PR0MTTHSNTAIR OEAN0HXIAENAON LA-NTRT 7IDIN(HC)TIOPE YN SROE)OFDL AA5OS AUAC0.RCRNY0SSN-HAI AGHEL NEIEISNN POIC:A1 N- 0N2LK L0 G 0D1EHA: R ADEU5G00SB N1.0BO5S00TYN00N TOL S3 TY WI( ).T 2ND0.NC01 I0A H.RG&GAEU C,2RCP( 5HHOT0YTRO0AAU AOMS2A, 4ENNIHRATIRTEAS A2R5DR)R0SY YS IANPGLNHG).A FROM FJRAOM I PPALUORWBARILT A(L 50R AIMLT .)COR60RI LMDV NS O - 1R333GA((((( (((((((((((EO234a(Rxixiivvxixxvvxi)iivx)000xEi)Rivi)v)iiiiN .E)i)))iiiv i N)ii) i)) ))I)) 8 BA D 2E L0 L T R F V E VV VOVV AVVKF V -KVVAVVV-----S3--URAZ-1321212----RA4- 23N B32 2 (LP E RRR((c((WU R IaeDbdM(((()(RTAOOROFbaba c))OO))SLRA R))K)))VAAARRRRI VA KA-VOL-RRORRR12DDULD6OOMOO(DGW a0KAOOAMOOOR) WRMAAAAAA8PDASAAAA AAAT0 DDCPDDNULG0IDDI1LDDD7ROA0LLIEA0EROVTW AMEIS.2C TNASHWKA IVNOB21UHDS0EREA0 RLD RMIKT. -FF KGIRPMVA8R IP 2E2ORCIAP E0D I N 5 LA61666BEROV3012W4EXT2L0000P0RTVP0R I 2AEOOMSN 1SLVPNB2WO AATE6YHB XASJIPSDVPOLE2HPA4IRLMVVL2R22SBE8I1P5S0 00SRVS03E8A125V.0ICOWR2010O.RA00CBW0IA10TVAA02AYN0L 0D R8 R5A 8INB3 R0SL50 AA T8 0 MBIC5S1 N 0R 08OKGWMV 05VA8RRA2 00A5 E-1 RSBI210L E0AA81(DN00E583b9N1FKE7 2B023076BOB671V5B0BCB)WBI0BB060XER0580RP5405X0 E055L0E5(EEEU 0OE TEE 0OI 50IM M 0 RMILSMMMLD0M MLLMMLVMS LLL-RMM M6T1T1ET(TTMEMTMET0EETTEET8aEE 0EEE)TR .E5 MMI R0TE T) OT ITO 0NTTEO333OTTO 0TTOTOOGNI1333T3234GEEDETEDE0EEN234ETE000GEENERN1NHN0NEGWNNR000REARERRO01ARRERR RRR E 5 1R BN ER LBASWN0BBSBSBSR SSGR SSASSSMVBOABOSR EO SOO O 2 O E S W I W U W WOFWWNILWD WO 1UNWWNTW TMTTTWTM 0TWSHBRRWID.0HTTIT INHTE IAHHIIHDIIHIDI0BID8DNODDTDIGDS2DD2H9DHIE V VD RI. DH ER SMEE9EOSEDSMSEEBSEEOSEEA RAE 2M333VEASEIL E333 R 234I 6II3 EN33I MIDS R O RD234 R000DDRR3ID2R RT34DTRRIR ASKS000AR40 00DREEOHONEAORNE EOOEOOEOOIOEOUOE EDOMSOSA-SJSAOSVS6SASSAAAAR3AAHAM5NSLAAEA.RUD.DI.0D.ADDADDRDDVV81NDDMM. DE.3D5U2D B VVD20 3A33 W VS WE2BH333W WW324W A2OP5W1234 1WT000R.51AW02000R333MIIAV0T0I3V0TITII234IT333I0AL0TI2 TTO TI000MAA234IT0IV .HHT 8H BV000GHTH72HHH30MMRAUNH333AHE 0 MD E.H2349Z S 3 N 43L3I3 33000 V56B1 PN0333M5E2120 34306I7ULI0A0234120031T0000D R0 00005U 0.VR4 . M 0V0M0032RM 01MEMM2 V12M AOM40.25EM.ME..SVNME0EE001MEAG0ETT.EETTTM333 CVTPDET1E23433M3V333-ETT2EEU100032432VE234ER RR000N5(E0006ERRRWK1b3AR)d(2V1RAV08)SMS333H3RRSSSS05324ASI1A2S00 000RTS0NS WP1W V1022WWW HUW0 05 WRW0W0DI333I BIIIKD234DI1VDDD2IHR7A000DIID0AE0SK3335DDE0EEE0234- NR2EM72E0 000W0EGOE GI1G 0DGGU29 RLEH0GM8 2 G 57A7G1O70RG1G5R7002RTRR0B0E0L0R0005EER0090NAE5IRL0R0E EEBLAVET2EEFLREVREKTEEEEIO2HR2E1METHHE NF5T0EEANNNNRS0R0DNYU6N666OK8ON6NH123477NSLRA00000GA7K7A0R770A8800D05S7000H)b0(A21-9VA802IDN00VA32110P(V0FANa950)UA8W22121AV00T5050RW22A810000H1-5MS0MA74E0M0E1D0OPV9ET008A21V7UHW-R7504V2RA51OKV2002VSS9T09M-A5 82HHM24 210R0OAAUV6II50A 2O2KK( LD000d)TOOU0KPI THH U8VUU21EH TR502PPINI21L600L(UUKVIDc502L9TVRRH2)O00LYW8I9 FAC8 50CA8R82I21K21H0OZNBV05O0050S502IARBTR00A20001M00R2MA D0PI 5DVVFWI0UHR0OA2221RSAA7RPR9(50eISUU21K00BV)507K3RAA-800H2SN21DV(2N6b50UD1HM5-7H5A)0004L0E800AAG0TU000RYA9A0VA2PNRNT UB4IVP9P7CRV8UVO0U21-RI20-54V50RPU2232(00dVA()02NAd0L)21DV 50VVC-A0022821-1O(R4506b08000)RY90SVA-40210UPN4502LND00V-0T47 .V0BA220V0IN02R120(78P0D5d58U)0S70B MS06 RA2H A A 8S0 D2DBI TMLPIAMK0D8HOSROLVA-N0RH4420EE(BRAOLLa1U)612T0IETRSPATV2AUP0C0R00URIRA O0HN8UL0AKIDRKOS0IITAR21NSAYIT 950RRSD 00FBACT787AARIA10OVLR200OTWM7I5IVM0O2 PPA 30UNLYSA0R8E7VO20-2X(e0mSH)9V)e(02H-0VAN13282AA0D57666B6667A60R211202VH62384423155002570SH00R0V0000050000)a666AV6G(32AVAVAA0V12344RV2AR-m-N-0000123URS(2A(e(A)0aaHR9)V0)01IU 324MV81V1-271 2- V01 22405S0MP60220O 50(000N(K0PUUONbJ0aM8BTVA)2mUH)BRU-HH4O0RAUERR ARJ80RUSPN21NHMS2U 2IN50IP3332NAAC610BERM000D4325VR0GR0GI0IA00P002PA5V0V8SOH-3D0AR24E0A5V5 PRLMY31M3VY 2A3 - C3330R 0V(43 LGO4332G33OVd372 VAR5003P042)-50DRER30BV640 00VUEM026BEP(21UC 2N-2W6 R0a(2E00NI5DDHB0Vd2)E90(V0NE-.0) EAe7G 2-L44 RVRITLDN)B0ED77KAB333EB292R E AANDOHV342TE0 6B3VTL-V34U0E0002A0G(20bL T9)SMT-TR0A4 M OG.MEASRTLBE.RP6AEAO211G8UN218D V2500 0A7R77B7570R07SK5000OE2D1036420100THH3L33L0USE50O0E0BT001DT A2NU34ISE00E5L EH0 R3P0TV3700RMG O7IWBIR0DU DN0B5DE OG AMRHRE0M30VEE3.0NV 2M3BAE0VL HT-2 2GN(G1Pd217R)IANRVR50VARA2E002LODHM(KVAEb2(PH)bFPH3N33)J33OV032AH36U A 14B2303330SZM2A4RN00 1E 734V23GI57E60R60LD333LG666967070000TD0H-0R43PN55502S 21123S41M222E0A001230 A450U7000A0AE9A0L5 (46000 V00SNRVbI0G 00LAN-BOBGR)5-4A8EWKVU555421ELLS13NHN 123ATLA0CHAE0THD000280NAOHN700N V721V9BE 2002SLM1(50EV31AeC0O00)LETBDT74HIV2DD01K2AC155NHVA0 5RV0M 0OK9A 0W2A00I M3-PmR7 73N2V6 5A0B U00R0-V(UK 271M1S380b0A33R301I62 V5T5O0V0D 9)G34S2V2-0I300R02TO0L000A E-01(33bFIE4MVVR IT0 )N 7M3A9G -10YB KA75 A4RETE0E 5 0LA 6E0ETT20B6 40NVMD 13R122H00 0B1G-0EI23055RO00P05LPE102(0T30001Ee U5MUN05 W)R 1GB1R00R2VURI09O2FR0VE05F0E0E0UE65550N 2VR1GM213 -L5123BRT40U E10NE7 160000Q12EE F I210 1S0F5SNA00 S05E50A7B0SHR0LOE0V3M005.LD 0 AA2TSMU H2GNWRIRAE3ATMTVED3NLIA6 BPEADRAHUV1F3PFHE19U2TRE02A 87UE0P0I32R6R0VO5Y500RUVVN022NXA35 R0 PTM1CIEE7P0HETS2FR7S0U6DIA VF0911IVSGD12T0S21PT332N2AR7L00A0A5EE5H06R0V0UVN1NV307IAD100TVC0M210E30AE0U-TEN-300AMII4KMR50R7ANU 4ALVL0L0UH00Y52EIAATMGASNAV38E JT3RLIW 0RRAPAO 10VAK5RDAUTDA52I123IESH50DRA70O00L TMVAM20H1 EGNIW R1 3-E6315W 21V 123E56N46 1J2N60HN850505731H12 02ANO352A1B102A19090005U000V05L705A06P0RRF32A01VF00A0YRU0ET1H2R 1A2MHS12R5N0B (0AE 00A21G021dI0BOR0N R5050B)EEN001LDO003EVHD4 U34A1NP- NR72 0PVMEB3V332D5VV0AEUR0V.V33ALOC2MV 3RITRMP.LYP 3DHL 3DV1 UBIGE1AM 22U5MRM55R403R15V21ISU123320TY.10EO0C1 05005S0L 0AE0R0A.0TH0 T0NLO18A0VA5AI NVA41MGB2331MDBD502VU53E71I3V36305T05V52R0A50666L61WRU700G110T123425DN8ADB0A00020S5A62V5LZ2103AO0001A-102250HI 750H1NH02R0A1500S500R50K7VEA00I280LA23AB1R220V OB0MN0VAK5240I01H30K02HD80VHP32V23V0V5VIH5GAUEMV130V103802EHIRRG5-0NAR12J4I05A00AM T054VLIVAPDD6WA65A6R200A1H-1E9832V 2UH2154THA0V01050A(0512AReA30P1NI000110311K 305 V)2T4027S0W7RA66006621EH000H0585634052150M0WAA0VE02U0010V000V2LPV2E2M3306AS5IL3T033V030E BLMLRME323T4RAO 5 1A R00A01OU UTGE0BR 042VSV21P31 03E2UV0A02320A00E75ULV00PN0R502A R3ABU4W1E2I9R0L51A6T3VV0R00R23-SR025D(UT6aI12SK5)61B2A0HV020U00021M15VR062N0500M2AD-120092V3045H0LU5I00N71V313VI0T126V421 1I0M7123O5030M05O7 0R0F2N8 00G55N DADBRDV0I RAFAV2GEE2 6JPO(EV 2e5VANO)L0 F3VF- 2(e)TB CG30 MDE1 GRE3E2N B8OEL T0L1EAS725DNU0T 0LT5R5R09AARRA0A0H0 VHSUSITAD02I EDMIL2OA R VA A0RV ND21LA12MVR03T2 IC 0-3NH5BR BP4S0H8US0E21 1AAA66TU3O 50AIDAA 23RNRI00RVK RT06100U1NHAIIVKO52YO21IC182ONNV320AU350A1(N1010A11LAd3NI2 R00MDV000B(0P076YD5)Nc 02A5)0e03P( 5A2A0AVA)RAU2ATCJR UL2K10R GSHT0P 0HYTIC0A2U VHV1EUA30URORTD23EV01M4EY0A66616RR32 233O A3B12304M58O231PA4GV00000VU202-500N1 03 4DO212S10G1A137V21R50I0300K317Y55RR00060A501VE21MAN2150EDUT00NEL3IR AOB PHVEVNUE3LRV22R1T33S(M01A7 e2E(A005cT)3VHR0)O0P1 RNU 6FOAV3 R9JU5 A33TR3 0FFEV 23G4N1 A 00O(0 RbAR) 2HT M OHR OU5 A M DPDAU2 R21EF1B323V00751BRLR40IT05D0IJOROHUO WT2M-1N233DSIE0M5D23IH0A0V000RAEA HSVDURE2L SAI(RWIeTAN)3YVA P7RA92TR00KO0K VA2 (be )DeEeL TT HnO O I DtD YRADNUOB ANAYRAH - IHLEDaEELkLHeHInI to Figure 2: The Gurgaon-Manesar Urban Complex 2031 marks out the city’s urban villages in bordered white areas across the city (reproduced with permission of Town and Country Planning Department, Haryana) thereby bypassing deeply politicised and bureaucratic procedures that had sty- mied urbanisation processes in other states (Balakrishnan 2013). Second, the HDRUA together with the PSRCA set urbanisation apart from those in many neighbouring states where large urbanisation projects were pri- marily undertaken by parastatals that utilised the highly controversial and liti- gious Land Acquisition Act 1894 to acquire land (Levien 2013). Through the exemption of the urban villages and the introduction of a license system it was the private sector and not the state that acquired and developed 85% (35,000 acres) of urbanisable land in Gurgaon between 1981 and 2014. In enacting the PSCRA and HDRUA, the state government both passed on acquisition responsi- bilities to the private sector, and mediated political tensions with landowners by cordoning off urban village land, nominally “non-urban”, from corporate capi- tal. As a result, opposition to land acquisition, while not completely absent (Kennedy 2014), has been much more muted than in other parts of the coun- try. This is in part facilitated by the creation of a differentiated landscape of agrarian change, articulated through the urban villages, wherein certain factions of the dominant landowning communities have been able to instrumentalise inequalities in the agrarian social structure, temporalities of the urbanisation processes and the “flexible” local state (Gururani 2013) to disproportionately benefit from land acquisitions.6 ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd. The Urban Village: Gurgaon, India 9 Land Tenure and the Green Revolution Finally, both historic land tenure systems and the uneven impacts of the Green Revolution across Haryana from the 1950s fundamentally shaped Gurgaon’s uneven urbanisation. Land ownership in Gurgaon has historically been dominated by two communities, the Yaduvanshi Ahirs, or Yadavs, and Jats. While Jats are a much more powerful political force within Haryana as a whole, Yadavs are numer- ically and politically dominant in the Gurgaon district, returning Yadav politicians to both national and state assemblies in every election since the state was inaugu- rated. In 2015, I carried out a household survey of 198 households across Gur- gaon’s urban villages (see Table 1). The survey recorded data on land sales, compensation, investments of landowning households over the past 30 years. According to the survey, Yadavs own the largest plots of land in the city, with average individual landholdings of 11 acres compared with Jats’ nine acres, Guj- jars’ six and a half acres and Scheduled Castes’ three acres. Historically, Jats in Gurgaon have held their land on bhayacharya tenures where land is formally subdivided non-ancestrally across the village, leading to highly fragmented, small landholdings. In contrast, Yadavs have historically held their land through pattidari tenures where land is held through ancestral lineage and family mem- bers own large, discontiguous plots of land, and cultivate land or supervise farm workers in common. Successive colonial land settlement reports from 1872 note that the commonly owned, large landholdings of the Yadavs pro- duced high yields and with it high tax revenues (Channing and Wilson 1882). This system of land tenure, which favoured revenue extraction, played into colonial governors’ construction of the Yadavs as an “industrious, thrifty and prudent” landowning caste (Channing and Wilson 1882). The priming of the Yadav community as a dominant landowning force, evocative of Chari’s (2004) work on Tiruppur’s Gounder caste, is perhaps explained by the high levels of participation of Yadav men in the colonial military and, unlike Meo and Gujjar castes who were much derided by colonial officials, low levels of participation in the 1857 mutiny in the region (Channing and Wilson 1882). Formal land consolidation was carried out across Haryana under the East Punjab Holdings (Consolidation and Prevention of Fragmentation) Act 1948. The act intended to reduce land fragmentation and produce more productive, gridded and legible agricultural farmland, yet was itself a highly uneven and politicised process, tending to provide dominant landowning communities with larger, more productive plots and significantly reducing the availability of village common land which landless communities relied upon (Bonner 1987; Narain and Vij 2016; Oldenburg 1987). Equally important, as Gururani (2013) notes, was the highly uneven impact of the Green Revolution across Haryana. The Indian state’s attempts to induce “suc- cessful” agrarian transition in north-west India through the introduction of new technologies and high-yield seed varieties produced an uneven development of agrarian capitalism across the state. As such, the land consolidation and increases in farm work that the Green Revolution brought to other parts of the state largely bypassed Gurgaon, which was considered to have unproductive and barren soil ª2018TheAuthors.AntipodepublishedbyJohnWiley&SonsLtdonbehalfofAntipodeFoundationLtd.

Description:
Abstract: Gurgaon, India's “millennium city”, is today synonymous with India's embrace of global real estate capital and private sector-led urban
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.