∗ SpoilsofWar: TradeShocks&SegmentedLaborMarketsinSpainduringWWI SimonFuchs(AtlantaFed) December2021 Abstract Howdoesdomesticfactormobilityshapethewelfareeffectsoftrade? Tostudythis,Iemployanevent- study design to show that during WWI a large trade shock caused uneven labor reallocation, wage and price growth across Spanish provinces. Employing a fully estimated spatial equilibrium model featuring imperfectspatialandsectorallabormobility, IshowthatduringWWIincreasesinconsumerpricesoffset nominal income gains. Afterwards, the effects of persistent labor reallocation increased welfare by 2.93 pc. Industrial centers benefited from sectoral reallocation, while spatial flows disseminated gains across provinces.Loweringthespatialmobilityfrictionsdecreasescountervailingpriceeffects. JELclassification: D5,F11,F12,F15,F16,N9,N14,R12,R13 Keywords: GainsfromTrade,LaborMobility,EconomicGeography ∗Fortheircomments,IamgratefultoKonradAdler,TrebAllen,AndyBernard,EmilyBlanchard,ToniBraun,AlbertCarreras,Thomas Chaney,KeremCos¸ar,KlausDesmet,ChrisEdmond,PatrickFève,JimFeyrer,SharatGanapati,ChristianHellwig,RobJohnson,Brian Kovak,TimLee,ThierryMayer,RoryMcGee,MartíMestieri,NinaPavcnik,FranckPortier,BRavikumar,VincentRebeyrol,JuanRubio- Ramírez, Mohammed Saleh, Chris Snyder, François de Soyres, Bob Staiger, Robert Ulbricht, Nikolaus Wolf as well as seminar and workshopparticipantsinmanyplaces.IalsowanttothankJavierSilvestreforsharinghisdataoninternalmigrationinSpainandJulio Martinez-Galarragaforsharingtheirdataonconsumerpricesaswellasprovidinghelpfulcomments. Finally,Iacknowledgefinancial supportviaERCgrantNo337272-FiNet.Allremainingerrorsaremyown.Theviewsexpressedhereinarethoseoftheauthorandnot necessarilythoseoftheFederalReserveBankofAtlantaortheFederalReserveSystem. 1 Introduction In recent years, a rapidly growing empirical literature has documented the uneven incidence and effect of tradeshocksacrosslocallabormarketswithincountries(Autoretal.,2016;Topalova,2010;Kovak,2013;Dix- CarneiroandKovak,2017;JaravelandSager,2019;McCaigandPavcnik,2018). Thesestudieshaveempha- sized the distributional consequences of uneven trade shocks on employment, wages and consumer prices across locations and occupations. However, they often employ a regression-based approach that implicitly treatsindividuallabormarketsasindependentobservations. Thisabstractsfromtherichnetworkstructure that-vialabormobilityacrosssectorsandspace-connectslocallabormarketsanddetermineshowshocks affect factor allocation and consumer prices in general equilibrium. While some studies have incorporated this feature1, important questions remain unanswered: What is the implication of spatially uneven shocks across connected local labor markets? What is the qualitative role of labor reallocation in determining the gainsfromtrade? Andwhatistherelativequantitativeimportanceofsectoralcomparedtospatialmobility? Inthispaper,Iexplorehowlocallabormarketsthatareconnectedviaimperfectlabormobilityshapethe aggregatewelfareconsequencesoftradeshockswithunevenincidence. Iarguethatwhenlabormobilityis impeded by sectoral and spatial mobility frictions, the uneven incidence of a trade shock across local labor marketsmatters. Ontheonehand, improvementsinallocativeefficiencymayariseandincreasegainsfrom trade. Ontheotherhand,theunevenincidenceofatradeshockacrossconnectedlocallabormarketsmight causeheightenedcompetitionforalimitedpoolofworkers,inducingonlylimitedreallocationoflabor,and thuslimitgainsfromtrade. Toillustratetheseopposingeffectsofuneventradeshocks,considerastylizedexampleofasimpleecon- omy with two local labor markets (i,j). Labor is imperfectly mobile and supply in i is increasing in local wages, w, but decreasing in wages elsewhere, w . Labor demand is decreasing in wages in location i, but i j increasinginaparameterthatrepresentsdemandshifts, e.2 Let ρ and ρ betheelasticityoflabordemand i i j with regard to demand shifts, and ψ and ψ be the own-wage and cross-wage elasticity of labor supply, ii ij respectively. Now, consider a (small) demand shift in both i and j (dlne > 0,dlne > 0), and solving for i j wageandemploymentchangesthatsatisfylabormarketclearinginbothiandj,weobtain,3 dlnw = α dlne +α dlne dln(cid:96) = β dlne +β dlne i 1 i 2 j i 1 i 2 j where α ∝ ρ, α ∝ ψ ρ . Furthermore, β and β are linear combinations of the reduced-form effect of 1 i 2 ij j 1 2 thedemandshockonwagesacrosslocallabormarkets,wheretheweightsaregivenbytheownandcross- wageelasticityoflaborsupply. Thereduced-formsystemclarifiestheroleofunevenshocks: First,giventhe assumptionsabove,bothα andβ arepositive,implyingthatthedirecteffectofanincreaseinlocaldemand 1 1 istoincreasewagesandlaborallocations. Ifademandshockdisproportionatelyaffectshigherproductivity sectors or locations, then efficiency gains arise. Second, α is positive and β is negative, implying that the 2 2 indirecteffectofdemandshockselsewhereinduceswagepressureandreduceslaborallocations. Thestrength of this channel depends on how connected the two local labor markets are as measured by the cross-wage elasticity ψ . Therefore, if trade shocks only affect a small set of tightly connected local labor markets, the ij consequenceisheightenedcompetitionforalimitedpoolofworkers,wagepressureandlimitedreallocation. 1Monteetal.(2018)exploretheimpactofproductivityshocksacrosslocallabormarketsthatareconnectedbycommutinglinkages inoutputandinputmarkets(tradeandmigrationfrictions). Caliendoetal.(2019)characterizethedynamicevolutionofthespatial equilibriumincorporatingmigrationlinkages.Adaoetal.(2019)revisittheimplicationsofthe’Chinashock’employingareduced-form systemthattakesgeneralequilibriumfeedbackintoaccount. 2ForsimplicityIassumethatlabordemandisindependentofwageselsewhere. Thisamountstoassumingthatoutputmarketsare completelysegmentedbetweeniandj. Thiscanberelaxedandthequalitativepredictionswillholdregardlessaslongastheindirect impactofwageselsewhereonlabordemanddonotexceedinmagnitudetheindirecteffectsonlaborsupply. 3DerivationscanbefoundintheonlineappendixSectionB.1 1 Increasedwages,inturn,maypass-throughintoincreasesinconsumerprices,offsettingincomegains. Inthe aggregate,unevenwageandpricegrowthtogetherwithonlylimitedefficiencygainsmightbetheresult.4 Inpractice,studyingtheeffectofatradeshockacrossconnectedlabormarketsischallengingfortwodis- tinctreasons.First,withoutknowledgeabouttheconnectednessoflabormarkets,itisdifficulttodisentangle thedirectandtheindirecteffect,especiallywhenashockiscorrelatedacrosslocallabormarkets. Therefore, itiscrucialtomodelandestimatethelinkagesbetweenlocallabormarketsinasufficientlyrich,yettractable way. Second,observedchangesinwagesandemploymentmightbedrivenbyunobservedproductivityim- provements that could be correlated with an observed trade shock. To disentangle the impact of demand shocks from other confounders, an exogenous trade shock is needed that affects local labor markets in an observablyunevenmanner. Toovercomethesechallengesandstudytheeffectsoftradeshocksacrossconnectedlocallabormarkets, thisstudycombinesthreedifferentelements: First,Iexamineanaturalexperiment,whereaplausiblyexoge- noustradeshockwithdiscerniblespatialandsectoralasymmetriesaffectsacountrywithhighlysegmented local labor markets. The reduced-form evidence illustrates how an international trade shock that affects closelyconnectedlocallabormarketscancauselocalizedwagepressurethatfeedsintoconsumerprices,but alsoreallocationoffactorstowardshighproductivityindustries.Second,Idevelopandestimateaneconomic geographymodelwherelocallabormarketsareconnected. Theworkerfacesareallocationchoicesubjectto switchingcoststhatimpedebothspatialandsectoralmobility. Thiscreatesatractablelaborsupplysystem that links local labor markets. I furthermore show how the historical setting can be used to estimate the model. Third, Ishowthatchangesinlaborflowsacrossspaceandsectorscanbeusedasasufficientstatis- tic to measure and decompose gains from trade taking spatial and sectoral labor reallocation into account. Thismethodologycleanlydistinguishesbetweenimprovementsintheworker’scurrentlocallabormarket- cross-sectionalwelfareimprovements-andimprovementsintheworker’soptionvaluetorelocatetoother locallabormarkets-dynamicgainsfromtrade. SimulatingWWIshockunderdifferentdegreesof(spatial) labormarketsegmentationallowsmetoquantifythesensitivityofgainsfromtradetofactorimmobility. Attheheartofthisstudyistheanalysisofahistoricalnaturalexperiment:Aninternationaltradedemand shocktotheSpanisheconomythatwascausedbytheparticipationofSpain’skeytradingpartnersinthefirst WorldWar(1914-1918).Spain,however,remainedneutralthroughoutthisperiod,butwasindirectlyaffected viatradelinkages.5 Thisuniquehistoricalepisodefeaturesaplausiblyexogenousandlargetradeshock(cp. Figure1),withhighlyunevenincidenceacrosssectorsandacrossspace. Spainatthetimewasmarkedbya highdegreelabormarketsegmentation,however,despitethatthetradeshockinducedsectoralreallocation (cp. Figure 2), causing at the same time a dramatic increase in consumer prices (cp. Figure 3). A detailed analysisofthisperiodisonlypossible,becauseofauniquespatialpanelthatbringstogetherforthefirsttime hand-collecteddataontraderecords, detailedemploymentsurveysacrossallSpanishprovinces, aswellas dataonconsumerprices,coveringtheperiodbetween1910-1920. Ibeginbyexaminingthehistoricalevidence: First,Iestablishtheexogeneityoftheshock. Iexaminethe historicaltraderecordsandshowthatanincreaseinexportsisassociatedwithdemandfactorsinbelligerent countriesthatcoincidewiththeoutbreakofthewar. Thisexportshockwasmarkedbysectoralasymmetry and the composition was in line with products that would have been needed for the sustained war effort. Second, I then examine the shock’s impact on wages, labor allocations and consumer prices. The shock 4TheonlineappendixSectionB.2providesanextensionofthismodelforanarbitrarynumberoflocallabormarkets.Inthatsetting theeffectonwagesandemploymentacrosslocallabormarketscanbewrittenintermsofadirectandindirect(generalequilibrium) effect. Furthermore,whilethegeneralequilibriumadjustmentsmightbedifficulttoexpressinclosed-form,anapproximatereduced- formcharacterizationintermsofownandcross-wagelaborsupplyelasticitiesisfeasible. 5TheshockwascausedbycircumstancesexternaltotheSpanisheconomy,specificallyreducedindustrialcapacityduetothelarge- scalemobilizationrequiredforthewareffortaswellasheightenedwarneedsinbelligerentcountries,particularlyFrance,whileSpain remainedneutralthroughouttheconflict. 2 Figure1: AggregateTradeLevels Notes:Aggregateexports(inmillionpesetas)bywhetherdestinationcountryisbelligerent.Belligerentcountriesareprimarybelligerentcountrieswhere tradewasnotdisruptedbythefrontlineitself,i.e. i.e. France,ItalyandtheUnitedKingdom. Thenon-belligerentcountriesexcludetheUnitedStates andotherlaterparticipantsofWWI.TheblueshadedareaindicatestheperiodofWWI.Thesourcedataarethedigitizedproduct-destinationleveltrade statistics. was highly uneven across space and sectors, and its direct effect induced limited spatial labor reallocation, but highly uneven wage and price growth. I also show that indirect exposure to the trade shock further exacerbated wage pressure: Provinces that are more closely located to other provinces that were heavily affectedbythetradeshock,experiencedadditionalwageandpricepressure. Thepresenceofindirecteffectspointstowardstheimportanceofspatiallinkagesacrossgoodsandfactor markets. Inordertoquantifythewelfareeffectsofatradeshockinthepresenceofsuchlinkages,thispaper takesanexplicitlystructuralapproach. Iincorporateimperfectlabormobilityacrossspaceandsectorsinan otherwisestandardeconomicgeographymodel. Thechallengeistodevelopaframeworkforlabormobility that is sufficiently rich to capture the details of how segmented labor markets interact, both characterizing theflowsbetweensectorsandacrossspace, butstillremainstractabletobeempiricallyestimated. Thekey innovationistorelyonasequentialformulationoftheworkers’relocationchoicethatseparatesspatialfrom sectoraladjustmentsandthusmodelscomplexinteractionsacrossspaceandsectorsinatractableway. To characterize the welfare implications of a trade shock under imperfect labor mobility, I extend the sufficient statistic approach by Arkolakis et al. (2012) and Ossa (2015) and derive a closed-form formula for the gains from trade that takes domestic re-allocation into account. The model implies an inverse and invertible relationship between the share of workers that remain in a location or sector and the spatial or sectoralex-anteexpectedutilityassociatedwiththereallocationchoice.6 Therefore,observingthechangein theshareofworkersthatremainacrosscomparativestaticsisasufficientstatisticfromwhichcommonlyused aggregatewelfaremeasurescanbeconstructed. Thesequentialchoiceimpliesaseparabilitybetweenspatial and sectoral mobility which in turn allows us to decompose and attribute welfare changes to changes in sectoralandspatialmobility. Thismethodologyallowsforasharpdecompositionofwelfareimprovements into different qualitative channel: Improvements in the current local labor market to which the worker is attachedsignifycross-sectionalstaticgains. Increasesinsectoralmobilitypindownincreasesintheoption- value of sectoral relocation, while increases in spatial mobility are associated with increases in the option- 6Conceptuallythisapproachisrelatedtothenotionthat(conditional)choiceprobabilitiesareinformativeofchoice-specificvalue functions,asiscommonlyusedintheestimationofthedynamicdiscretechoicemodels(HotzandMiller,1993).Inthissetting,remain sharesaredirectlyrelatedtotheoption-valueoftheworker’smobilitychoice. Thisoption-valueofthereallocationchoiceisrelatedto whatMcFadden(1977)termedthesocialsurplusfunctionwhichisacommonlyusedwelfaremeasure. 3 Figure2: AggregateCompositionoftheEconomy Notes:Primary(agriculture),secondary(industry/manufacturing)andtertiary(services)shareoftotalemploymentinSpainbetween1877-1930.Dataseries isconstructedfromcensusdata,usingthecalculationsinHarrison(1978)fortheyears1877-1900,andfollowsowncalculationsfortheperiodbetween1900- 1930.TheblueshadedareaindicatestheperiodofWWI.Furtherinformationonhowaconsistentdataseriesisconstructedfromcensusdataisprovidedin theonlineappendix. value of spatial relocation. These latter two channels are associated with the worker’s mobility choice and constitutedynamicgains. Toimplementthewelfareanalysistwoingredientsareneeded:First,thisapproachrequiresknowledgeof laborflowsintheshockedandnon-shockedcounterfactualscenario,whichinturnrequiresafullyestimated modeltosimulatethecounterfactualscenario. Second,thewelfareformularequiresestimatesofthespatial andsectorallaborsupplyelasticitiesaswellasthetradeelasticitytobeconstructed.Alargepartofthisstudy isthereforededicatedtoexploitingthehistoricalsettingtoobtaincredibleestimatesofkeyelasticiesandto fullycalibratethemodel,includingadetailedefforttoestimatemobilityfrictionsacrossspaceandsectors. The estimation of the model proceeds in four steps. In a first step, I derive from the model a structural reduced-formthattracesoutnominalincomegainsasafunctionofthespatialexposuretotheWWIshock. Implementingthisregressiondesignallowsmetoestimatedomestrictradecosts.Inasecondstep,Iinvertthe modeltolocation-sectorspecificfundamentalswhichcorrespondtomarket-shareshifters. Thesensitivityof thesemarketshareshifterswithregardto(exogenous)changesintheinputcostpinsdownthetradeelasticity. I exploit the differential impact of the trade shock across locations and sectors to isolate wage changes and thereby identify the trade elasticity. I then turn towards estimating the parameters that determine labor flows in the model. Typically, the estimation of mobility frictions would require data on flows of workers across space and sectors. However, in historical settings this is rarely available. In this setting, the census providesadditionaldataonthestockofresidentsdissectedbytheirplaceofbirthin1920and1930. Ibegin byexploitingthisinformationtoestimatea(spatial)gravityregression,whichidentifiesthespatialdecayof migrationflowsaswellastheaverageout-migrationshareacrossallprovinces. Inordertoestimatesectoral switching costs and labor supply elasticities I fit the model to changes in labor allocations at the province- sectorlevelfrombeforetoafterthewar. Achallengeisthatmigrationdecisionsweremadeduringthewar based on wage dynamics that are not directly observable at the province-sector level. To overcome this, I invert the model to back out baseline productivities and then feed in the observed aggregate WWI trade shock to simulate - conditional on a guess for the migration frictions that are being estimated - labor flows andwagesthatsolvethelabormarketequilibriumconditionsacrossallprovince-sectorunits. Thefrictions are being estimated by minimizing the distance of the simulated labor allocations and the observed labor allocationsjustafterthewar. 4 Figure3: EvolutionoftheSpanishCPI Notes:ConsumerpriceindexaccordingtoBallesterosDoncel(1997)between1890and1936.Normalizedto100in1913.Blue-shadedareaindicatesWWI period. AsaresultoftheestimationIobtainpredictedsectoralandspatiallaborflowsthatareconsistentwiththe observed changes in province-sector specific labor allocation. Both sectoral and spatial frictions are highly prohibitive. However, the implied reallocation strongly suggest that spatial frictions dominate sectoral ad- justmentfrictions,with76percentoftheadjustmenthappeningacrosssectorswithinprovinces,ratherthan betweenprovinces. With the fully estimated model in hand, it is possible to quantify and decompose the welfare effects of theWWIshockacrossSpain. Todoso,Ifirstsimulatelaborflowsinthenon-shockedscenario,byusingthe calibrated model to simulate the sectoral and spatial reallocation if external trade and productivity would haveremainedatthe1914level. Withthelaborflowsintheshockedandnon-shockedscenarion,thewelfare effectscanbequantified. Thisisdonebothforthescenariowherethelabormarketclearingwage(andthere- fore the prices of domestic tradeables and non-tradeables) is generated feeding in the WWI shock and for thescenariowheretheWWIshockjustdissipatedandexportlevelslevelofftoalowerpost-warexportsce- nario.Thisexerciseallowsustoexaminethedynamicsofthegainsfromtradefromatemporarytradeshock: Whiletheshockpersistedincreasesinconsumerpricesentirelyoffsetanygainsfromtrade. Aftertheshock dissipated,thereallocationalgainsincreasedwelfareby2.93percent,howeverthegainswerehighlyuneven across provinces. Lowering the spatial segmentation, increases reallocative gains and decreases offsetting priceeffects. Inafinalstep,Itraceoutthewelfareeffectsfordifferentdegreesof(spatial)labormarketsegmentation. Byvaryingthespatialmobilitycostandrecalculatingthelaborflowsinboththeshockedandnon-shocked scenarioIcantraceouttherelationshipbetweenlabormarketsegmentationandgainsfromtrade. Notsur- prisingly, as labor markets become more integrated the gains from trade increase. However, the exercise shines a role on the qualitative and quantitative importance of spatial mobility. Interestingly, the marginal gainsareequallysharedbetweenincreasesinreallocationandlessenedcountervailingpricepressure. This reinforces the insight from the theoretical model, that uneven trade shocks cause price pressure and that factormobilityplaysanessentialroleinmitigatingthis. Related literature. My paper is related to a number of different strands of research. First, there is a long- standingliteratureininternationaltradeexaminingtheimplicationsofalackoffactormobility,goingback atleasttothecanonicalanalysisusingthespecificfactormodel(Jones,1971;Mayer,1974;Mussa,1974,1982). 5 Mussa (1982) in particular pointed out that factor immobility leads to differential income gains across sec- tors with different factor endowments. More specifically related to labor adjustments, a number of papers have further examined the interaction between dynamic labor adjustments and external trade shocks with Matsuyama (1992) developing a first tractable analysis, and with a more recent set of papers exploring the phenomenonquantitatively(TombeandZhu,2019;Kambourov,2009;Artucetal.,2007;Dix-Carneiro,2010; Dix-CarneiroandKovak,2017;Kovak,2013;Caliendoetal.,2015;FajgelbaumandRedding,2014;Fan,2019; Adao et al., 2019; Monte et al., 2018; Caliendo et al., 2019). What is less explored in this literature is the in- teractionbetweenconnectedlocallabormarkets,unevenshockincidenceandconsumerprices.7 Thispaper fillsthisgapbyprovidingbothreduced-formevidencefromauniquehistoricalnaturalexperimentaswellas acompletequantitativeanalysisoftheinteractionbetweenlabormarketsegmentation,uneventradeshocks andconsumerprices. Second,mypapercontributestotheliteratureoncharacterizinggainsoftradeusingsufficientstatistics. Recent contributions sought to extend the initial work (Arkolakis et al., 2012) to allow for multiple sectors with different trade elasticities (Ossa, 2015), or workers with heterogeneous productivities across sectors (Galle et al., 2017; Kim and Vogel, 2020; Lee, 2020). This paper contributes to this literature by characteriz- ing gains from trade taking into account the imperfect reallocation of workers across domestic local labor markets8andhighlightingthatdatalaborflowscanbeusedtoconstructasufficientstatistictodoso.9 Third,thepaperaddstotheliteratureonSpanisheconomichistorybyshowingthattheWWIshockhad animportantimpactontheSpanisheconomybyreallocatingfactorsacrossspaceandsectorstoprovidethe preconditions for an economic take-off in the 1920s. As such it is a middle ground between two opposing viewsintheliterature. Thetraditionalview, representedbyRoldanandDelgado(1973), interpretsthewar asalargeturningpointforeconomicdevelopment. Themodernview,representedbyPradosdelaEscosura (2016) emphasises that the shock actually decreased real GDP and instead he points towards the 1920s as a much more important decade for Spain’s development. My analysis provides a middle ground between thesetwoopposingviews,pointingtowardssubstantialreallocationandnominalincomegains,buttracing outsubstantialcountervailingpriceeffectsthataredrivenbyreallocationcostsinthelabormarket,leading to positive but somewhat modest welfare gains despite a historically large demand shock to the Spanish economy. Outline. Theremainderofthepaperisstructuredasfollows. Section2describesthehistoricalbackground and the various data sources as well as the construction of the data set that underlies most of the analysis. Section3givesreducedformevidenceonthetradeshockanditseffectlocallabormarkets.Section4describes the theoretical model, the estimation of the model as well as the welfare quantification. Finally, Section 5 concludes. 7Whiletheliteraturegenerallydoesnotfocusontheinteractionbetweenlocallabormarkets, thestudiesbyHelm(2020);Adao etal.(2019)arenotableexceptions. InHelm(2020),theauthorexploitsemploymentspilloversbetweenlocallabormarketstoestimate agglomeration effects. In Adao et al. (2019), the authors revisit the reduced-form analysis of Autor et al. (2013), but introduce an estimationframeworkthatexplicitlytakeslabormarketlinkagesandgeneralequilibriumresponsesintoaccount. Indeedthestylized modelinthenextSectioncanbeseenasasimplifiedversionoftheirframework,butthefocusoftheiranalysisabstractsfromefficiency gainsandhowthoseareconditionedbytheunevenessoftheshock. 8KimandVogel(2020)conductasimilaranalysis,takingtheimperfectreallocationofworkersintoaccountwhencalculatingthe welfareeffectoftheChinashockacrossUSlabormarkets. However, byabstractingfrombilateralreallocationintheirsetting, they cannotcapturetherichinteractionsbetweencloselyconnectedlabormarketsthatisthecenterpieceofthisstudy. Intheirempirical implementation,theyfurthermoreabstractfromtheimpactonconsumerprices. 9Thepaperisalsorelatedandaddstoagrowingliteraturecharacterisingthewelfareimplicationsoffactormisallocation, going back at least to Harberger’s initial analysis (Harberger, 1964), with Baqaee and Farhi (2020) offering a characterisation of the effect ofmicroeconomicshocksininefficienteconomies,HornbeckandRotemberg(2019)studyingtheimplicationsofmisallocationonthe welfareeffectoftransportationimprovementsintheUShistoricalcontextandZarate(2021)doingsoinanurbancontemporarycontext. 6 2 Data and Historical Background Beforeturningtowardstheempiricalanalysis,thissectionwillprovidebackgroundonthehistoricalcontext andthekeydatasourcesthatunderlietheanalysis. IwillfirstdescribekeyfeaturesoftheSpanisheconomy justbeforetheoutbreakofWWI,focusinginparticularonthespatialandsectoralorganizationoftheSpanish economy,externaltradeandthesegmentationofdomesticlabormarkets. Iwillthenproceedbyintroducing thehistoricalspatialdatasetthatwillbeusedintherestofthepaper. 2.1 TheSpanisheconomyatthebeginningofthe20thcentury. At the beginning of the 20th century, Spain remained at a relatively low level of industrial development.10 According to census data, in 1900 roughly 70pc of the working population worked in agriculture and only 12.5pc worked in manufacturing. Industrialization only proceeded slowly, with the industrial sector only growing marginally in total employment by 3pc, adding a little bit less than 40,000 jobs nation-wide in the first decade of the century. At that time, the largest share of the industrial sector was made up of sectors associatedwithprimarygoods,suchastheexploitationofminesortheproductionofconstructionmaterial. Spatial distribution of economic activity. In terms of the spatial distribution of the population, most of the population was still concentrated in predominantly rural and agricultural areas such as Andalucía11 or Castilla y León.12 Major urban centers such as Oviedo, Valencia, Bilbao, Madrid and Barcelona concen- tratemostoftheindustrialactivityascanbeseenbythemapinFigure4indicatingthespatialdistribution of manufacturing employment. The industrial structure of those urban centers was heterogeneous. For example, Barcelona was highly specialized in the cotton textile industry, while Valencia specialized in gar- ments. Because of natural endowments mining and associated downstream industries dominated Oviedo and Jaen. The Basque country had an early advantage in the heavy metal industries, featuring numerous Martin-Siemensopen-hearthfurnacesforsteelproductionaswellasotherfixedinstallations. Internal migration. Up until the 1920s, the Spanish economy was marked by perennially low levels of internalmigration,withnetmigrationneveramountingtomorethan5pcthepopulationatadecennialrate (Silvestre, 2005). Explanations focus mainly on an insufficient release of agricultural works to urban areas, driven either by supply based factors - such as low agricultural productivity and demographic dynamism - or demand based factors - such as the lack of pull of industry and services until at least WWI.13 Either explanationisperfectlyconsistentwiththepointofviewthatsubstantialpushorpullfactorswererequired toovercometheeconomic,linguistic,orsociologicalbarriersthatimpededspatialandsectoralmobility. Externalmarkets. Finally,intermsofexternalmarkets,attheendofthe19thcentury,(former)coloniesand otherLatinAmericanmarketsplayedaparticularlyimportantrole,whileafterthelossofthecoloniesSpain’s 10Aftermissingthefirstwaveoftheindustrialrevolutioninthefirsthalfofthe19thcentury(Harrison,1978),theSpanisheconomy underwentaperiodofrapidindustrializationinthesecondhalfofthe19thcentury,fueledbymarketintegrationduetotheexpansionof therailroadnetworkwhichinturnresultedinthedevolutionofindustrialcapacitytotheperipheralprovinceswiththecottonindustry inCataloniaandMetallurgyintheBasquecountrydevelopingespeciallyrapidly(Nadal,1975). However,industrializationsooncame toanearlyhaltwiththecensusdatashowinglittleincreaseinindustrialemploymentfrom1887onwards.Thisisalsomirroredbyvery lowGDPperheadgrowthratesaveraging0.6percentbetween1883-1913(PradosdelaEscosura,2017).Someauthorsattributethelow levelsofgrowthtolimiteddemandformanufacturinggoodsdomesticallyaswellaslittlecapacitytocompetewithgoodsfromcountries suchasGermany,FranceandtheUKthataremoreadvancedintermsoftheirindustrialization(Harrison,1978). 11Andalucíacompriseseightprovinces:Almería,Cádiz,Córdoba,Granada,Huelva,Jaén,MálagaandSeville,withmajorindustrial activitylocatedinSevilleandMiningemploymentinHuelva 12CastillayLeóncomprisesnineprovinces: Ávila,Burgos,León,Palencia,Salamanca,Segovia,Soria,ValladolidandZamorawith majorindustrialactivitycenteredinValladolid. 13Foracompletediscussionandreferencesofdemand-basedandsupply-basedexplanationseeSection2inSilvestre(2005). 7 Figure4: SpatialDistributionofManufacturingEmployment Notes:Mapoftotalmanufacturingandminingemploymentbyprovincein1910(excludingCanaryIslandsandNorthAfricanpossessions).Sourcedatais the1910census. exportsshiftedmoretowardsEuropeancountrieswithFranceandGreatBritaintakingupthebiggestshare ofexports(comparetheright-hand-sideinFigure5). Mostoftheexportswererawmaterialsoragricultural productsconsistentwiththelowdevelopmentalstatusofSpainatthetimeasdepictedontheleft-hand-side inFigure5. Ingeneral,Spainranatradedeficitformostofthebeginningofthe20thcenturyexceptforthe shortperiodunderconsiderationinthispaper. 2.2 AspatialdatasetforSpainbetween1910-1920. To examine the impact of WWI on both trade flows and local labor markets, I construct a regionally disag- gregateddatasetforSpainbetween1910-1920thatcovershandcollectedinformationonwages,employment levels,pricesandexportsacrosslocallabormarkets. Thisdatasetallowsmeforthefirsttimetoanalyzethe impact of the trade shock taking both external trade and internal labor reallocation into account. I rely on sixprincipaldatasourcesthattogetherdescribemanufacturingandagriculturalemployment,externaltrade, migrationpatterns,consumerprices,thetransportationnetworkandthehousingmarket.14 Manufacturing employment. I obtain disaggregated information regarding wages and labor quantities across local labor markets. At the beginning of the 20th century, the plight of the working class and their working conditions became a more prominent political issue in Spain. In order to better understand and 14Seetheonlineappendixfordetailedinformationonreferencesfordatasourcesanddetailsondataconstruction. 8 Figure5: TopExportSectorsandDestinations(1910,1915,1916) Notes:Aggregateexports(inmillionpesetas)bysector;aggregateexports(inmillionpesetas)bydestinationcountry.Exportsreportedfortopsevensectors andtopsixdestinationsrespectivelyaccordingtotheirrankin1915.Thesourcedataarethedigitizedproduct-destinationleveltradestatistics,asdiscussed intheonlineappendix. tracktheworkingconditionstheInstituteforSocialReform-anentitythatwouldlatermorphintothemin- istryoflabor-startedconductinglarge-scalesurveysonworkingconditionswiththefirstannualreportbeing released in 1907. The institute continued to publish yearly reports covering the whole period of 1910-1920. The surveys were conducted at all public firms and large private enterprises in cities that are larger than 20,000inhabitants(Casanovas2004). Theycovered23differentindustries15 and48differentprovinces.16 In theannualreports,theinstitutionreportedwages,workinghours,andnumberofemployeesacrosslocalla- bormarkets. Theresultsareavailableintwodifferentformats. Ontheonehand,industry-specificresultsare availableacrossthemoregeographicallyaggregatedunitofregions,ontheotherhand,provincialwagesare reported but with the industry-specificresults missing. Additionally, the Ministry of Labor laterpublished a compilation that offers a more complete picture across local labor markets with employment and wages beingreportedacrossprovince-sectorpairsfortheyears1914,1920and1925(MinisteriodeTrabajo,1927). Agriculturalemployment. Iaugmenttheindustrysurveywithadditionaldatafromthecensus. Whilethe industrysurveycoversalargerangeofthemanufacturingsector,itdoesnotgivefurtherinformationonthe remainingeconomy.Asmentionedbefore,acrucialfeatureoftheSpanisheconomywasthelargeagricultural sector. Toaccountforthat, Idigitizedtheoccupation-provincespecificSectionofthecensusfor1900, 1910, 1920, and 1930. I use the 1920 data on agricultural employment to augment the 1920 data. For the 1914 data,Iusethe1910province-specificagriculturalemploymentdataandextrapolatebycalculatingprovince- specificfertilitytrendsuntil1914. Finally,IusedatacontainedintheofficialSpanishstatisticalyearbookson province-specificagriculturalmeanwagesfor1915and1920. Externaltrade. Iobtaineddetaileddataregardingexportsandimportsfromannualtraderecordsreleased by the Spanish custom agency. I digitized the trade statistics for the years 1910-1919. For those years, the 15The industries included are called: Books, Ceramics, Chemicals, Construction, Decoration, Electricity, Food, Forrest, Furniture, Garments,Glass,Leather,MetalWorks,Metallurgy,Mines,Paper,Public,PublicIndustry,Textiles,Tobacco,Transport,Varias,Wood. 16Thecensusfor1910lists49differentprovinces. Theymostlycorrespondtothemodernadministrativeunitscalledprovincias- provinces-whichareinturnroughlytheNUTS3leveladministrativeunitsofSpain. Therearesomeminordifferences,e.g. inhow differentoff-continentaladministrativeunitsarebeingtreated. FormyanalysisIdroptheCanaryislandsfromthesamplesincetheir distancefromthemainlandmakesithardtoarguethattheyaresimilarlyintegratedasotherprovinces. 9
Description: