ebook img

The Perverse Economy: The Impact of Markets on People and the Environment PDF

218 Pages·2003·0.86 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The Perverse Economy: The Impact of Markets on People and the Environment

T H E P E R V E R S E E C O N O M Y This page intentionally left blank T P H E E R V E R S E E C O N O M Y T I HE MPACT OF M P ARKETS ON EOPLE AND E THE NVIRONMENT Michael Perelman THEPERVERSEECONOMY © Michael Perelman,2003. Softcover reprint of the hardcover 1st edition 2003 978-1-4039-6271-3 All rights reserved.No part of this book may be used or reproduced in any manner whatsoever without written permission except in the case of brief quotations embodied in critical articles or reviews. First published 2003 by PALGRAVE MACMILLAN™ 175 Fifth Avenue,New York,N.Y.10010 and Houndmills,Basingstoke,Hampshire,England RG21 6XS. Companies and representatives throughout the world. PALGRAVE MACMILLAN is the global academic imprint of the Palgrave Macmillan division of St.Martin’s Press,LLC and of Palgrave Macmillan Ltd.Macmillan® is a registered trademark in the United States,United Kingdom and other countries.Palgrave is a registered trademark in the European Union and other countries. ISBN 978-1-4039-7087-9 ISBN 978-1-4039-8026-7 (eBook) DOI 10.1057/9781403980267 Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Perelman,Michael. The perverse economy :the impact of markets on people and the environment / Michael Perelman. p.cm. Includes bibliographical references. 1.Economics.2.Economics—Sociological aspects.3.Economic development—Environmental aspects.4.Income distribution.5.Labor productivity.6.Labor economics.7.Smith,Adam 1723–1790—Views on labor economics.8.Scarcity.9.Value.I.Title. HB71.P467 2003 330—dc21 2003046735 A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. Design by Newgen Imaging Systems (P) Ltd.,Chennai,India. First edition:November,2003 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Contents Introduction 1 One Adam Smith and the Farm Worker Paradox 7 Two Resources 21 Three Value 79 Four Patience 119 Five Environmental Efficiency 133 Six Back to the Farm Worker Paradox 145 Seven A New Direction 175 References 185 Index 207 Introduction Walking along a city street, I look up at a gleaming office building filled with busy people. Hundreds, perhaps thousands of them are manning computers, telephones, fax machines, or copiers or maybe just shuffling paper—work that is coming to occupy the majority of employ- ees in advanced market economies. Many seem to be working at a fran- tic pace. For many of these people, prosperity must seem almost like a birthright. Others, working long hours trying to get ahead, also expect at the very least a middle-class lifestyle. Great wealth flows to some of the people who occupy these offices, and even more to those who employ them from afar. But what exactly do they do? How do their activities contribute to society? In what seems to be a world apart, in the countryside, a number of immigrant laborers are working hard amidst a toxic soup of agricultural chemicals. Yet, without these people or others like them, the economy would grind to a halt. What would people eat without such workers sac- rificing their own health in the fields? Despite their undeniable contribu- tion, these people earn pitiably little. So little that one small study of North Carolina farm workers found that 47 percent of them were food insecure, including 9.8 percent with moderate hunger and 4.9 percent with severe hunger (Quandt et al. 2003). During the 1990s, the median income of individual farm workers remained less than $7,500 per year while that of farm worker families has remained less than $10,000 (United States Department of Labor 2000)— a mere pittance compared to the privileged workers who occupy the spacious offices. Certainly nothing compared to those who give the orders to the crews in the offices. At one point, during a series of lectures to young women, the young Alfred Marshall, who would become the dom- inant figure in economics during the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, raised the question, “how is it then that men consent to remain 2 THE PERVERSE ECONOMY agricultural labourers?” (Marshall 1873, p. 103). Marshall let the question drop; so too did the economics profession as a whole. What explains this disparity between the office workers and the field workers? You can look for an explanation in the books that supposedly explain the workings of the labor market. There you can read that every- thing follows from the inexorable laws of the market. Supposedly everyone earns a reward commensurate with his or her productivity. Economists can tell you with assurance that the farm workers live in poverty only because their productivity lags far behind the average level for the economy as a whole. In contrast, many of the people who work in the more spacious offices enjoy enough rewards to lead a life of comfort, or even luxury. Economic theory proposes that they earn their elevated station in life because of their high productivity, even though you may have a hard time identifying exactly what they produce. Press the economists further and they may explain that the people in the offices who market and distribute the goods and services must be productive—no, highly productive—since their wages are so high. People who get these jobs often have some higher education, which supposedly augments their productivity, even though their educational training probably has little or nothing to do with their actual responsibilities on the job. How does this productivity manifest itself? These office workers figure out ways to wrap products in layer after layer of packaging. They devise advertising that makes people feel a necessity to buy goods. They may even calculate the extra profits that will accrue to their employer by cutting corners on their products. The economists’ circular logic concludes that high wages are evidence of superior productivity and that superior productivity necessarily earns high wages. In effect, then, whatever exists is necessarily rational, unless something somehow interferes with the natural workings of the market. Even the excess education is rational because it serves as a signal of a workers’ commitment to work productively. Within this framework, the employees in the offices who shunt money around—sometimes in stocks, sometimes in bonds, and sometimes for directly productive investments—must be even more productive. Indeed, these people must be extraordinarily productive. After all, they appropriate the lion’s share of the wealth. In contrast to the successful members of the economy, the lowly farm workers have little education. Economic theory teaches that their skills are widely available. Many more people living in poor countries would Introduction 3 willingly take their jobs. How could a person like that possibly be worth as much as a successful worker occupying a lavish office? Besides, the food that the farm workers grow is not worth very much, giving further proof of their meager productivity. Of course, this con- ventional image could possibly have a different interpretation. What if their low salary partially explains why the food they grow is inexpen- sive? What if the high salaries that some professional workers earn merely reflect the fact that they happen to represent sectors of society that enjoy special privileges? After all, circular logic can work in both directions. Finally, what if the much-vaunted productivity of these highly compensated workers depends, in large part, on the continuing ability to draw down scarce resources? Or even worse, what if economic produc- tivity, in general, would actually be negative if proper account were taken of the resource costs of production? Plan of the Book The purpose of this book is to call for a wholesale rethinking of the way that markets treat both labor and the resource base upon which we all depend. Many excellent books already exist that make the case that workers should be treated with justice and resources handled with care. I concur with that view, but this book has a different objective. The unique contribution of this book is, I believe, in analyzing the relationship between the environmental crisis and the social crisis within the context of modern economic thinking. Economists see the global economy moving ahead at breakneck speed. Each year, millions of people enjoy the opportunity to move up into the ranks of the middle and upper classes. Even so, all is not well in this world. The comfortable lives of the fortunate minority rest upon a precarious foundation. The environment cannot sustain the increasing demands that modern technology places on it. In addition, appalling inequality strains the social fabric. I am concerned that formal economic analysis justifies self-defeating policies. The wanton use of the environment and callous abuse of the least advantaged will undermine the very objectives that economists see them- selves as furthering. This claim will probably not make sense to most trained economists, who tend to believe that market forces will inevitably lead to desirable outcomes. 4 THE PERVERSE ECONOMY Of course, economists are not inhuman brutes who welcome the mistreatment of human beings or nature. Most see themselves as further- ing a scientific analysis of human activity. Many of those mainstream economists who have an interest in policy sincerely believe that a greater reliance on markets can correct both social and environmental problems. Unfortunately, the method that they use to understand the world is rigged in such a way that market solutions either give the best of all pos- sible outcomes or that with a little jiggering markets will produce com- parable results. Within the economics community critical assessment is most unwelcome, and for good reason. Economic theory rests upon a foundation of embarrassingly unrealistic assumptions. This book will explore how economics narrowed its scope so radically that it was left with tunnel vision; how it separated its view of the world so radically that it is at odds with the prevailing view of the natural sciences; and how continuing to accept market discipline threatens to undermine both human capacities and nature—the very forces upon which our future depends. Chapter 1 sets the stage by showing how Adam Smith tried to grapple with the wretched conditions of farm workers. Smith’s discussion is still relevant today. Those who supply the most essential products for human life still receive the least reward—what I will call the farm worker para- dox. Although Smith’s treatment of the subject was unsatisfactory, to his credit, at least he stumbled upon it, where virtually all later economists have successfully avoided any discussion of the farm worker paradox. Unfortunately, he let the matter drop quickly. Chapter 2 discusses how economics treats scarcity. Just as most econ- omists have avoided the farm worker paradox, they have steered clear of the subject of scarcity. This approach is surprising since many economists regard their discipline as the theory of the allocation of scarce resources. Chapter 3 looks at the nature of economic theory rather than the eco- nomic theory of nature. It analyzes how the core of economic theory works to eliminate any concern with either scarcity or the conditions of the least favored workers. Chapter 4 extends the discussion of economic theory, concentrating on the way that economic theory discounts the future, ensuring that con- cern about future scarcity would be outside the ambit of conventional economics. The subject of chapter 5 is environmental efficiency. The purpose of this chapter is to illustrate the complexity of environmental processes and to show how ill-equipped economics is to analyze such processes.

Description:
The purpose of this book is to call for a wholesale rethinking of the way that markets treat both the labour and natural resources on which we all depend. It reveals how economic analysis justifies self-defeating policies that encourage wanton use of the environment and callous abuse of the least ad
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.