ebook img

The origins of the Federal Reserve PDF

122 Pages·2009·1.715 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The origins of the Federal Reserve

T H E O R I G I N S O F T H E FEDERAL RESERVE T H E O R I G I N S O F T H E FEDERAL RESERVE by M R URRAY OTHBARD LvMI Ludwig von Mises Institute Selected from A H M B U ISTORY OF ONEY AND ANKING IN THE NITED S : T C E W W II TATES HE OLONIAL RA TO ORLD AR © 2009 by the Ludwig von Mises Institute and published under the Creative Commons Attribution License 3.0. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/ Ludwig von Mises Institute 518 West Magnolia Avenue Auburn, Alabama 36832 www.mises.org ISBN: 978-1-933550-47-3 Contents SECTION ONE The Progressive Movement . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 SECTION TWO Unhappiness with the National Banking System . . . . . . . . . . . 11 SECTION THREE The Beginnings of the “Reform” Movement: The Indianapolis Monetary Convention . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 SECTION FOUR The Gold Standard Act of 1900 and After . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 SECTION FIVE Charles A. Conant, Surplus Capital, and Economic Imperialism . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 SECTION SIX Conant, Monetary Imperialism, and the Gold-Exchange Standard . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 SECTION SEVEN Jacob Schiff Ignites the Drive for a Central Bank . . . . . . . . . . . 71 SECTION EIGHT The Panic of 1907 and Mobilization for a Central Bank . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 79 SECTION NINE The Final Phase: Coping with the Democratic Ascendancy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97 SECTION TEN Conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103 5 The Progressive Movement1 The Federal Reserve Act of December 23, 1913, was part and parcel of the wave of Progressive legislation, on local, state, and federal levels of government, that began about 1900. Progressivism was a bipartisan movement which, in the course of the fi rst two decades of the twentieth century, transformed the American economy and society from one of roughly lais- sez-faire to one of centralized statism. Until the 1960s, historians had established the myth that Progressivism was a virtual uprising of workers and farmers who, guided by a new generation of altruistic experts and intellectuals, surmounted fi erce big business opposition in order to curb, regulate, and control what had been a system of accelerating monopoly in the late nineteenth century. A generation of research and scholarship, however, has now exploded that myth for all parts of the American polity, and it has become all too clear that the truth is the reverse of this well-worn fable. In contrast, what actually happened was that business became increasingly competitive during the late nineteenth century, and that various big-business interests, led by the powerful fi nancial house of J.P. Morgan and Company, Originally published as “The Origins of the Federal Reserve,” Quarterly Journal of Austrian Economics 2, no. 3 (Fall): 3–51.—Ed. 7 8 The Origins of the Federal Reserve had tried desperately to establish successful cartels on the free market. The fi rst wave of such cartels was in the fi rst large-scale business, railroads, and in every case, the attempt to increase profi ts, by cutting sales with a quota system and thereby to raise prices or rates, collapsed quickly from internal competition within the cartel and from external competition by new competitors eager to undercut the cartel. During the 1890s, in the new fi eld of large-scale industrial corporations, big-business interests tried to establish high prices and reduced production via mergers, and again, in every case, the mergers collapsed from the winds of new competition. In both sets of cartel attempts, J.P. Morgan and Company had taken the lead, and in both sets of cases, the market, hampered though it was by high protective tariff walls, managed to nullify these attempts at voluntary cartelization. It then became clear to these big-business interests that the only way to establish a cartelized economy, an economy that would ensure their continued economic dominance and high profi ts, would be to use the powers of government to establish and maintain cartels by coercion. In other words, to trans- form the economy from roughly laissez-faire to centralized and coordinated statism. But how could the American people, steeped in a long tradition of fi erce opposition to government- imposed monopoly, go along with this program? How could the public’s consent to the New Order be engineered? Fortunately for the cartelists, a solution to this vexing prob- lem lay at hand. Monopoly could be put over in the name of opposition to monopoly! In that way, using the rhetoric beloved by Americans, the form of the political economy could be maintained, while the content could be totally reversed. Monopoly had always been defi ned, in the popular parlance and among economists, as “grants of exclusive privilege” by the government. It was now simply redefi ned as “big business” Murray Rothbard 9 or business competitive practices, such as price-cutting, so that regulatory commissions, from the Interstate Commerce Com- mission to the Federal Trade Commission to state insurance commissions, were lobbied for and staffed by big-business men from the regulated industry, all done in the name of curbing “big business monopoly” on the free market. In that way, the regulatory commissions could subsidize, restrict, and cartelize in the name of “opposing monopoly,” as well as pro- moting the general welfare and national security. Once again, it was railroad monopoly that paved the way. For this intellectual shell game, the cartelists needed the support of the nation’s intellectuals, the class of professional opinion molders in society. The Morgans needed a smoke screen of ideology, setting forth the rationale and the apolo- getics for the New Order. Again, fortunately for them, the intellectuals were ready and eager for the new alliance. The enormous growth of intellectuals, academics, social scien- tists, technocrats, engineers, social workers, physicians, and occupational “guilds” of all types in the late nineteenth cen- tury led most of these groups to organize for a far greater share of the pie than they could possibly achieve on the free market. These intellectuals needed the State to license, restrict, and cartelize their occupations, so as to raise the incomes for the fortunate people already in these fi elds. In return for their serving as apologists for the new statism, the State was prepared to offer not only cartelized occupations, but also ever increasing and cushier jobs in the bureaucracy to plan and propagandize for the newly statized society. And the intellectuals were ready for it, having learned in gradu- ate schools in Germany the glories of statism and organicist socialism, of a harmonious “middle way” between dog-eat- dog laissez-faire on the one hand and proletarian Marxism on the other. Instead, big government, staffed by intellectuals

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.