ebook img

The London School of Economics and Political Science China as a Post-Socialist Developmental ... PDF

289 Pages·2013·1.2 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The London School of Economics and Political Science China as a Post-Socialist Developmental ...

View metadata, citation and similar papers at core.ac.uk brought to you by CORE provided by LSE Theses Online The London School of Economics and Political Science China as a Post-Socialist Developmental State: Explaining Chinese Development Trajectory Andrzej Bolesta A thesis submitted to the Department of Government of the London School of Economics for the degree of Doctor of Philosophy Declaration I certify that the thesis I have presented for examination for the MPhil/PhD degree of the London School of Economics and Political Science is solely my own work other than where I have clearly indicated that it is the work of others. The copyright of this thesis rests with the author. Quotation from it is permitted, provided that full acknowledgement is made. This thesis may not be reproduced without the prior written consent of the author. I warrant that this authorization does not, to the best of my belief, infringe the rights of any third party. 2 Abstract This thesis is intended to contribute to the discussion on China’s socio-economic development during the post-socialist period of reform and opening up. It is aimed at providing an explanation of the Chinese contemporary development trajectory, by establishing an institutional and policy model, which China is believed to have been following. This model is also believed to offer some general solutions to the underdeveloped countries in systemic transformation. The thesis argues that China’s post-socialist development trajectory has been determined by the provisions of the Developmental State (DS) model, as far as state development policies, state ideology, and state institutional arrangements are concerned, and to the extent, that China has become a genus of the Post-Socialist Developmental State (PSDS) model – this model being an alternative to the post-socialist neo- liberalism. In the course of scholarly enquiry, China’s development trajectory is analysed against the paths of historical developmental states, and against the general and developmental aspects of the process of post-socialist transformation. I start by analysing the features of the historical developmental states and by investigating whether the provisions of the DS model are viable contemporarily and how the model extends to the discussion on China’s development. I then examine China’s post-socialist transformation, partly in its DS context. Next, I analyse the features of China’s development trajectory in comparison with the features of historical developmental states, as far as ideology and political and economic arrangements as well as state development policies are concerned. Finally, based on the previous analyses, I explain the DS-determined post- socialist development trajectory of China, address the causal relation between the DS institutionalisation and post-socialist transformation, and construct the PSDS model, as a general guideline for states in transition. 3 List of Contents Introduction ………………………………………………………………………. 7 1. China and the Relevant Models of Socio-Economic Development ... 7 2. Post-Socialist China and the Developmental State Model: Explaining Chinese Development Trajectory ……………………… 11 3. The Methodology and Chapter Composition ………………………. 15 Chapter 1: The Developmental State: Its Conditionality and Its Future …... 20 1.1. The Definitions ……………………………………………………... 20 1.1.1. The Geographical and Temporal Limitations ……………. 22 1.1.2. The State-Society Relations: From “Embedded Autonomy” to “Subordinate Society” ……………………. 26 1.1.3. The State Development Policies: From Import Substitution Industrialisation to Export Oriented Industrialisation …………………………………………... 31 1.1.4. The State Ideology: Economic Nationalism ……………… 33 1.1.5. The Quantitative Definition ……………………………… 35 1.2. The Political Conditionality ………………………………………… 38 1.3. The Economic Conditionality ………………………………………. 47 1.4. The Future of the Developmental State ……………………………. 58 1.5. China and the Developmental State ………………………………… 67 Chapter 2: Post-Socialist Transformation in China …………………………. 71 2.1. Post-Socialist Transformation – The Overview ……………………. 71 2.2. Post-Socialist Transformation – The Debate ……………………….. 78 2.3. Post-Socialist Transformation in China ……………………………. 83 2.3.1. China during the State Command Period ………………... 84 2.3.2. China in the Process of Post-Socialist Transformation ….. 87 2.3.3. Political Reforms and the Gradual Path ………………….. 93 2.3.4. Economic Reforms ………………………………………. 99 2.3.5. The Chronology ………………………………………….. 107 2.3.6. The Chinese Perspective …………………………………. 111 4 Chapter 3: China’s Development Trajectory and the Developmental State Model: Ideology, Political and Economic Arrangements ………. 117 3.1. Economic Nationalism in China ……………………………………. 118 3.2. The Political Arrangements of the State ……………………………. 129 3.3. The Interaction of the Four Actors of the Developmental State – “The Relational Aspects” …………………………………………... 136 3.4. The Economic Arrangements of the State ………………………….. 147 Chapter 4: China’s Development Trajectory and the Developmental State Model: Comparative Policy Analysis …………………………….. 157 4.1. The Perceptions on Industrial Policies and the Developmental State Model ………………………………... 157 4.2. Agrarian Reforms and Rural Industrialisation ……………………… 166 4.3. The DS Policy of Industrial Development …………………………. 169 4.3.1. Industrialising by Learning and by Innovating …………... 170 4.3.2. The Targeting …………………………………………….. 179 4.3.3. The Business Actors ……………………………………... 191 4.4. The DS Policy of Import Discrimination and Export Support ……... 193 4.5. The DS Financial Policy of Support for Industrial Development and Export …………………………….. 202 4.5.1. The Monetary Policy and the Banking Sector …………… 203 4.5.2. Indirect and Direct Subsidies …………………………….. 207 4.5.3. Price Control, Investment Policy and Foreign Direct Investments ………………………………………………. 213 Chapter 5: China – The Post-Socialist Developmental State ………………... 217 5.1. The Unordinary Character of China’s Post-Socialist Development Trajectory ………………… 217 5.2. China’s Post-Socialist Development and the Developmental State Model ………………………………... 223 5.3. Post-Socialist Developmental State Model: The Natural Choice of Systemic Transformation? …………………. 236 Bibliography ……………………………………………………………………… 247 5 Appendix ………………………………………………………………………….. 281 1. National Development and Reform Commission’s (NDRC) Main Duties ………………………………………………………… 281 2. Ministry of Commerce’s (MOFCOM) Main Duties ……………….. 284 3. Socio-Economic Indicators ………………………………………… 288 List of Tables Table 1: Development-related Indexes of Post-Socialist States (1990-2005) .. 288 Table 2: HDI Change in Historical Developmental States …………………... 289 List of Figures Figure 1: Four Actors of the Developmental State …………………………… 136 Figure 2: HDI Change in Post-Socialist and Developmental States ………….. 289 6 Introduction 1. China and the Relevant Models of Socio-Economic Development In the course of economic history, various civilisations have risen and fallen and the gravity of mankind’s socio-economic development has shifted from one region to another. There is an abundance of often interconnected factors which constitute a successful developmental model, among which are institutional arrangements, systemic environment, state policies, societal capacity, as well as geo-political and geo-economic locality. This thesis concerns the contemporary developmental model China has been following during the post-Mao period of reforms and opening up (gaige kaifang). Up until the nineteenth century, China was the largest economy in the world and Adam Smith (2003) would see it more appropriate to compare the Chinese economy with that of the entire Europe, rather than separate European states. Maddison (2007) claims that China owed its position to the intensive economic growth between the seventh and the thirteenth centuries and this was attributable to the development of an intensive and sophisticated agrarian production sector, to the creation of an internal market to trade goods, and to the well-organised and effective state1 supported by a highly qualified state bureaucracy. At least until the end of the fifteenth century, China’s civilisation was considered to be more advanced than European civilisation. Smith pointed out in 1776 that ‘no other country has yet arrived at this degree of opulence [and that] China had probably long ago acquired that full complement of riches’ (Smith 2003, p.132). Nevertheless, the overall progress of mankind in terms of socio-economic development in the first eighteen centuries A.D. was relatively slow as compared with the subsequent time periods. Kolodko (2008, pp.68,70) points out that it is estimated that the aggregated output of the world’s economy between year 1 and 1000 did not increase and between 1000 and 1800 increased by a meagre 50%, with an average annual economic growth of 0.05%. 1 The state, defined by Max Weber as a compulsory association claiming control over a territory and the people therein (cited in Evans 1995, p.5), is considered here to be the structure of governance institutions (Wade 1990, p.8). In keeping with Wade (1990), the term state is often used interchangeably with the term government. 7 The consequences of the Industrial Revolution of the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries2 allowed for a significant acceleration of socio-economic development and subsequently firmly established the representatives of the so-called Western world as the leaders of developmental advancements, first – the United Kingdom, then the United States, Germany and other European countries. The Industrial Revolution marks perhaps the establishment of the first effective developmental model of the modern era. This model was characterised by capital-driven economic expansion. The capital was generated through production increase, enabled by technological advancements. At the same time, economic expansion was facilitated by military means. China seemed not to be affected by the Industrial Revolution and, as a consequence, the developmental rift between Europe and the “Middle Kingdom” continued to increase. It is believed that the initial waves of Industrial Revolution failed to have an effect on China, otherwise a relatively well-developed state with well- educated elites and efficient bureaucracy, because of its 300-year policy of isolationism, which limited the diffusion of foreign technologies, domestic incentives for modernisation and the effective exchange of ideas related to economic policies. The militarist model of capitalist development of Western Europe was soon to affect the political stability of China, which as a result of several wars and domestic rebellions, became a semi-colonial state with 92 “treaty ports” with extraterritorial rights.3 The beginning of the Industrial Revolution prompted a critique of mercantilism, until then broadly considered to be world’s main economic doctrine, which advocated state- controlled foreign trade monopolies as paramount for developmental advancements (Skousen 2007). Adam Smith and then David Ricardo among others, supported the idea of trade liberalisation leading towards international production specialisation and utilisation of comparative advantage (Haakonssen 2006). However, their classical economy theory of “natural liberty” met opposition among the representatives of less developed countries. For example, a German economist Friedrich List believed that Smith’s ideas would bring benefits to more affluent countries and leave the less developed vulnerable. His perception was influenced by Alexander Hamilton’s (2008) American school, developed by the president of the United States, John Quincy Adams and senator Henry Clay into the American system – an economic plan to support the US 2 Preceded by 300 years of pre-capitalist development which had commenced with the Renaissance epoch in Europe. 3 Subsequently, 19 foreign nationalities residing in the treaty ports were granted effective diplomatic immunity from the Chinese legal jurisdiction (Maddison 2007). 8 domestic industries development by providing the necessary physical and financial infrastructure, as well as by protecting them from foreign competitors through tariff barriers. Hamilton, the first US Secretary of Treasury, believed that those state interventions and protectionist measures are necessary for overall socio-economic development. As a result, List saw politics and economics as inseparable. He argued that ‘economies need to be seen in their political context, if their relative successes and failures are to be understood. […] It is only when a polity gains the status of a geographically substantial nation-state that it can become and remain a successful manufacturing and commercial entity’ (Winch 1998, p.302). The model of capitalist development brought enormous wealth to the industrial elite, whereas the labour force employed in the newly established factories and manufactories suffered the problems of low wages and difficult working conditions. Social marginalisation and exclusion as well as widespread industrial exploitation4 became urgent issues, with the long-term potential capacity to politically destabilise many countries. This prompted considerations for a new economic model, based on Marxist critiques of capitalism, labelled as socialism or, due to the fact that the proposals for new systemic arrangements were presented in the document called The Manifesto of the Communist Party – communism. In its socio-economic form the model advocated the abolishing of private property and therefore eliminating the capitalist elite. It eventually evolved into advocating the abolishing of the market mechanisms in economic affairs and the establishing of a state-command mechanism in which the decision on the quantity and assortment of production, goods allocation and price would be met by the state (see: Schumpeter 1942). This model had a significant impact on China’s development trajectory, since the state ideology of Mao Zedong – the founder of the People’s Republic of China (PRC) – drew significantly from Marxism. Without subsequent extensive acceleration of socio-economic development, the implementation of the new model nevertheless reversed the trend of economic decline, as a result of which, the ‘Chinese GDP per capita was lower in 1952 than in 1820 [and] China’s share of world GDP fell from a third to one-twentieth’ (Maddison 2007, p.43). However, the second half of the nineteenth century was also marked by the enforcement of the Listian political economy into the systemic arrangements in continental Western Europe and thus by creation of what perhaps can be seen as initial institutional 4 As opposed to the earlier agrarian exploitation related to the feudal system. 9 fundamentals for what would later become a developmental state – a model believed to be largely responsible for the effective developmental catching up of some countries from the so-called group of late developers. This model denied the capitalist class the dominant role in development, entrusting the guiding of the process of socio-economic development to the state. Its origins can be traced from the institutional arrangements of Bismarck’s Prussia and the nineteenth century period in Japanese history referred to as the Meiji restoration,5 influenced by the ideas presented by List in his study entitled The National System of Political Economy (originally published in 1841) and by the “American system” of early nineteenth century. In this model the state elite, supported by effective state bureaucracy, would guide the process of the industrialisation of national economies. It was consistent, to some extent, with the perception prevalent after the Great Depression until the late 1970s and motivated by the Keynesian theory, that the role of the state or the public sector is crucial in the developmental endeavour, especially among underdeveloped countries. In the mid twentieth century, when Western countries, comprising predominantly of Western Europe and North America, distanced the rest of the world in terms of the level of development and continued to rely on what evolved from the model of capitalist development and the Prussian interventionist state, and, at the same time, Eastern Europe was coerced into adopting the state-command economic system, the so-called developing countries, many of which were emerging from colonialism, were in desperate need for a developmental model to enable significantly better developmental dynamics in order to establish a sound trajectory of “catching up”. By the end of the twentieth century, among the most successful late developers were those countries who became developmental states, i.e. South Korea, Taiwan and Singapore, as well as Japan – considered a prime example of the developmental state model, despite a rather “early” start to “late development”. This however, did not secure its position as a feasible developmental option for less developed countries worldwide. In fact, the political competition between the Western world and the communist parties’ controlled Eastern bloc, especially between the superpowers of both structures, i.e. the United States and the Soviet Union, affected 5 The Meiji restoration was the process of significant changes in Japan’s political, social and economic structures, which accelerated the country’s industrialisation. 10

Description:
material wealth, and the capability approach which refers, according to Amartya Sen, to. 'a person's consideration, such as Human Development Index (HDI), and Human Poverty Index, which also The period between 1963, when the famine effectively ended and premier Zhou Enlai called for four
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.