ebook img

The impact of intermediate advertising effects on advertising effectiveness and profitability PDF

58 Pages·2011·0.78 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The impact of intermediate advertising effects on advertising effectiveness and profitability

The impact of intermediate advertising effects on advertising effectiveness and profitability Daniel Klapper ∗ Goethe-University Frankfurt, School of Business and Economics, Department of Marketing German Zenetti † Goethe-University Frankfurt, School of Business and Economics, Department of Marketing Abstract In this study, we introduce a new approach to measuring the impact of TV advertising on the demand for consumer goods. We combine three data sources (i.e., store-level scanner data, advertising spending data and advertising tracking data) to assess the impact of ad- vertising on demand. We estimate demand by employing a random coefficient logit model that uses aggregate data, in accordance with Berry, Levinsohn & Pakes (1995). We model the effect of advertising on consumer utility by applying an individual goodwill production function that is calibrated based on a firm’s advertising efforts and tracking data. In turn, the tracking data assess individual responses to various measures of intermediate advertising effects which are related to consumers’ product experiences, advertising knowledge and ap- preciation of advertising. These intermediate advertising effects help to improve researchers’ ability to identify the goodwill production function and to estimate the effects of advertising on sales via goodwill. Our empirical findings show indeed that experience, cognition and the appreciation of advertising significantly influence goodwill production and advertising effectiveness. In other words, these factors determine how a company’s advertising strategy ∗Address: Grueneburgplatz 1, 60323 Frankfurt am Main, Germany, telephone: ++49-69-798-34648, e- mail: [email protected]. †Address: Grueneburgplatz 1, 60323 Frankfurt am Main, Germany, telephone: ++49-69-798-34642, e- mail: [email protected]. 1 translates into a stock of goodwill and how this goodwill stock influences sales and profits. We then assume thatfirms set their advertising budgets strategically according to an Markov perfect equilibrium and study the influence of exogenous shocks to intermediate advertising effects on firms’ price and advertising strategies and their profitability in equilibrium. 2 1 Introduction In many markets, the link between advertising expenditure and profitability is difficult to establish. Advertising strategies develop in a dynamic and competitive setting in which advertising effects carry over to the future, and advertising campaigns often diverge from a consumer’s actual moment of purchase. Accounting for advertising efforts is further com- plicated by the co-occurrence of a brand’s own marketing activities and its competitors’ marketing activities, especially in the form of price and non-price promotions. Addition- ally, advertising effectiveness largely depends on mental processes (e.g., the cognitive and emotional effects of advertising), which are heterogeneous across consumers. These mental processes are also unstable over time because of consumers’ product experiences, wear-in and wear-out effects and the threat of competitors’ advertising. Inthispaper,weintroduceamethodologytoaddresstheseissuesandtomeasurethetotal effect of advertising on firm profitability by simultaneously accounting for the moderating effects of advertising effectiveness. These moderating effects are linked to the cognitive and emotional consequences of advertising. Our results show how changes in consumers’ appreciation of an advertisement affect a firm’s pricing and advertising strategies and its profitability. Additionally, in a state of equilibrium, the changes in appreciation also affect competitors’ pricing and advertising strategies. We base our research approach on a structural model in which advertising affects a con- sumer’s utility via goodwill, and utility, in turn, determines the consumer’s product choice. OurworkisinspiredbythestructuralworkofDub´e, Hitsch&Manchanda(2005), Doganoglu & Klapper (2006) and Draganska, Klapper & Villas-Boas (2010), who have shown that good- willisanappropriatemeasureofthelinkbetweenconsumerutilityandadvertising. Goodwill depreciates during each period, and advertising provides a means to replenish the depreci- ated goodwill. In contrast to, for example, Dub´e et al. (2005) the depreciation of goodwill and the impact of goodwill on utility depend not only on the advertising intensity per se but also on the cognitive and emotional processes induced by a brand’s advertising and 3 a consumer’s experience with the brand. Information about this intermediate advertising effects come from the advertising tracking data that are combined with advertising spend- ing and store level scanner data. Our empirical findings show that experience, cognition and affect significantly influence goodwill production and advertising effectiveness. In other words, these factors determine how a company’s advertising strategy translates into a stock of goodwill and how this goodwill stock influences sales and profits. We then assume that firms set their advertising budgets strategically according to an Markov perfect equilibrium (MPE) and study the influence of exogenous shocks to intermediate advertising effects on the firms’ price and advertising strategies and their profitability. Several counterfactual studies will show the profit implications of exogenous changes in consumers’ product experiences, advertising knowledge and appreciation of advertising. A large body of research has focused on the impacts of cognition, emotions and consumer experiences related to a brand or product on consumer behavior and preferences. However, to the best of our knowledge, the profit implications of these factors have not been studied in detail. For example, in a hierarchy of effects model (Lavidge & Steiner 1961), advertising must inform and persuade consumers before they buy a firm’s products, but scholars have not yet determined the order in which these effects take place (Barry & Howard 1990). Per- suasive models (e.g., Petty & Cacioppo 1981a, Petty & Cacioppo 1981b) state that cognition precedes affect, which, in turn, precedes behavior. In this context, behavior refers to the conative part of advertising effectiveness, as does product experience. For example, Ehren- berg (1974) established a trial-reinforcement model in which cognition precedes experience and experience precedes affect. Other models with alternative orders (e.g., conation-affect- cognition or conation-cognition-affect) have been introduced in the literature (e.g., Barry & Howard 1990, Vaughn 1980, Vaughn 1986). Based on an extensive literature review, Vakratsas & Ambler (1999) conclude that there is no support for a hierarchy of effects; but, cognitive, emotional and conative effects simultaneously impact and moderate the influence 4 of advertising on consumer preferences.1 Given the lack of evidence for a hierarchy of effects model (i.e., whether cognition pre- cedes affect or the role of experience in the interplay between cognitions and emotions), our approach uses these three intermediate advertising effects (i.e., experience, cognition and affect) as the drivers of advertising effectiveness in a hierarchy-free manner. Our work is also related to that of Srinivasan, Vanhuele & Pauwels (2010). The authors had access to a nationally representative panel of households that provided information on aided brand awareness, aided advertising awareness, advertising appreciation, consideration sets and purchase intentions. The data consisted of monthly averages at the brand level and wereclassifiedintofourproductcategories. Thesedatawerecomplementedbypurchasedata and price data extracted from a national panel of households and from information about firms’productdistributionsandadvertisingefforts. Srinivasanetal.(2010)usedthemonthly time series to build a 15-equation VARX model at the brand level. The list of dependent variables included three mindset metrics (i.e., advertising awareness, brand consideration and brand appreciation). Each dependent variable was related to each lagged dependent variable and to other exogenous factors to account for seasonal factors. By applying gener- alized impulse response functions, the researchers could compute the sales impact of their mindset metrics and relate these metrics to the marketing mix. The researchers found that mindset metrics impact sales and that these metrics can monitor future declines in sales. Our approach differs, although we use similar demand shifters. We begin by defining an economic foundation of demand in which advertising affects consumer decisions through a goodwill variable. The effect of goodwill on utility and the process by which goodwill is established depend on intermediate variables, which Srinivasan et al. (2010) called mindset metrics. Hence, in our model, the intermediate advertising effects influence the impact of 1Theconativedimensionaccountsforintendedoractualbehaviorwithrespecttopreviousexperienceand canbemeasuredbytheconsumer’spurchaseintentions,recommendationsorproductexperiences(Vakratsas & Ambler 1999, Shim, Eastlick, Lotz & Warrington 2001). Cognition consists of a person’s cognitive efforts ormentalactivitiesandistypicallyoperationalizedbyrecall, recognitionorcomprehensionscores(Bettman & Park 1980, Barry & Howard 1990, Aaker 1991). Affect is typically measured by a person’s appreciation of and attitude toward an advertisement or image (Keller 1993). 5 advertising on utility. We model demand by employing a flexible, random coefficient logit model for aggregated data, which accounts for the heterogeneity of brand perceptions, price responses and advertising responses. This model accounts for the possibility that compet- ing brands will exhibit flexible substitution patterns, and it supports the observation that consumers may encounter, experience and process advertisements differently. Ourmodelingapproachcombinesmacroandmicrodata. Macrodataprovideinformation about a company’s sales, prices, advertising and promotional effort. We extract the micro data from advertising tracking data, which contain monthly repeated samples of consumers. These consumers are interviewed regarding their product experiences, advertising recall and advertising appreciation, among other measures. We use both data sources to investigate the advertising sales relationship and to identify the effects of exogenous changes in expe- rience, advertising appreciation, or advertising recall on a firm’s dynamic and competitive advertising strategies and its profitability. The remainder of the paper is structured as follows. After describing the data in detail, we outline the structural model used to study the impact of intermediate advertising effects on demand. Then, we analyze the estimation results and the impact of exogenous changes in intermediate advertising effects on a company’s price setting, advertising budget and profits. 2 Data description: ground coffee We study the influence of intermediate advertising effects (i.e., cognition, affect and ex- perience) on firms’ advertising effectiveness and dynamic advertising strategies by examining the ground coffee industry. We use data on the German market from 2000 to 2001. Pro- ducers of ground coffee typically emphasize the importance of advertising as a means to build brands and shift consumer preferences. Therefore, these producers invest a signifi- cant percentage of their revenues in television (TV) advertising. For example, in the year 6 2000, the German coffee industry made 4.09 billion euros in revenue at the retail level. The manufacturers invested approximately 134 million euros in TV advertisements. In terms of revenue, coffee is the most frequently consumed beverage in Germany, followed by mineral water and beer. Ground coffee is one of the most frequently advertised products on German TV (KloseDetering Werbeagentur 2001). In both 2000 and 2001, the average per capita consumption of raw coffee was 6.7 kilograms, which corresponds to a total consumption of 548,520 and 549,530 tons of raw coffee in 2000 and 2001, respectively (European Coffee Federation 2002). In the next section, we briefly describe our three sources of data: (1) a nationally represen- tative sample of store-level scanner data, (2) national advertising budgets, and (3) tracking data that provide information on the intermediate effects of advertising. 2.1 Macro data: sales data and advertising budgets The market research company MADAKOM (Cologne, Germany) collected data from a nationally representative sample of retail stores for the years 2000 and 2001. The stores belong to six major retail chains (i.e., Edeka, Markant, Metro, Rewe, Spar and Tengelmann) from which consumers purchased products in the demand model. We do not include discount stores belonging to Aldi and Lidl in our data and analysis because these stores primarily sell private labels and do not advertise on TV. We treat the coffee from these stores as an outside option and concentrate on the retailers that predominantly sell national brands. To compare theretailers’advertisingexpenditurestotheirrevenuesandprofitability, wederivetheirgross national sales. Based on publicly available information about each retailer’s total revenues, we can derive the retailers’ gross revenues. Our analysis focuses on the five largest coffee brands (i.e., Jacobs, Melitta, Dallmayr, Tchibo and Eduscho), which are predominantly sold in 500-gram packages (i.e., 98% of all units are sold in this size). We analyze thirteen sub- brands of the five national brands. The store-level scanner data include information about the stores’ prices and promotional activities. Because the stores’ featured advertising and 7 in-store promotions frequently appear together, we combine these two factors into a single variable called Promotion. Figure 1: Monthly TV budgets in thousands of euros for the sub-brands. A market research company collected and provided the monthly gross TV advertising budgets for the thirteen sub-brands. The advertising budgets represent only the amount of money spent on broadcasting and do not include the costs of creating the campaigns. Note that throughout the time of the study, advertising campaigns do not change. Budgets do not represent the actual amount paid by the manufacturers for TV advertising because the market research company calculated the budgets based on the catalog prices of advertising on the TV channels and the times when the TV commercials were broadcast. The media agenciesthat managethemanufacturers’TV advertisements typically receive largediscounts from the TV stations. These discounts are passed on to the advertisers. The national brand manufacturers primarily use TV advertising, which accounts for more than 90% of their 8 Brand Quantity Market Promotion Price TV share budgets Jacobs (Sb 1) 633.1 1.25 18.68 7.49 1050 Jacobs (Sb 2) 137.4 0.28 17.20 7.55 439 Jacobs (Sb 3) 32.2 0.06 10.52 8.13 484 Melitta (Sb 1) 367.7 0.75 19.06 6.69 1217 Melitta (Sb 2) 112.6 0.24 17.76 6.75 536 Dallmayr (Sb 1) 419.7 0.84 14.71 8.02 1606 Tchibo (Sb 1) 29.5 0.07 2.13 10.76 251 Tchibo (Sb 2) 341.4 0.70 12.47 8.61 251 Tchibo (Sb 3) 54.2 0.12 3.69 9.43 251 Tchibo (Sb 4) 56.9 0.12 3.74 9.42 251 Tchibo (Sb 5) 110.6 0.24 8.28 7.66 251 Tchibo (Sb 6) 69.1 0.15 9.22 8.03 251 Eduscho (Sb 1) 429.8 0.87 16.33 7.19 1300 Table 1: Mean values of sold quantity (in tons per week), market share (in percent per week), promotion (in percent per week), price (in euros per kilogram per week) and TV budget (in tsd euros per month) for each sub-brand. total expenditures for advertising. The fact that monthly expenditures for TV advertising are reported several months before the store-level scanner data are reported facilitates the initialization of the goodwill production function. Figure 1 shows the TV budgets for each sub-brand for the months during which the store-level scanner data are reported. Tchibo engages in umbrella advertising, and its advertising budget is assigned to each sub-brand in proportion to the number of sub-brands. Table 1 provides a descriptive overview of each sub-brand’s market share, prices, promo- tional efforts and advertising expenditures. The sub-brands tend to differ in their market shares. The sub-brands with high market shares generally show lower prices, greater pro- motional support and larger advertising budgets than do the sub-brands with low market shares. 2.2 Micro data: advertising tracking data The advertising tracking data were collected by a large market research company, which conducted monthly, face-to-face interviews with approximately 320 respondents based on a repeated cross-sectional design. These questionnaires are similar across industries and 9 marketing research institutes. The sample is representative of the target group of coffee consumers. Because the tracking data is measured at the brand level, we cannot differentiate among the various sub-brands. Thus, we assign identical values to the sub-brands within each brand. In addition, we match the monthly tracking data to the weekly sales data using exponential smoothing. Figure2: Purchasedrecently(PurchRecent), aidedadvertisingrecall(AdRecall)andattitude toward advertising (Aad) during months. The tracking data provide information about consumers’ experiences, cognition and af- fect. We measure experience by analyzing the brands that the respondents have recently purchased (denoted as PurchRecent). We operationalize the respondents’ cognition by mea- suring their capacities for aided advertising recall (denoted as AdRecall). In addition to advertising recall, the tracking data also contain information describing whether each re- 10

Description:
effects on firms' price and advertising strategies and their profitability in equilibrium. 2 . tsd euros per month) for each sub-brand. total expenditures
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.