ebook img

The Emergence of the Social Sciences, 1642-1792 PDF

240 Pages·1993·12.84 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The Emergence of the Social Sciences, 1642-1792

Twayne’s Studies in Intellectual and Cultural LListory Michael Roth, General Editor Scripps College and the Claremont Graduate School Liberalism Old and New byj. G. Merquior Renaissance Humanism by Donald R. Kelley Dissent and Order in the Middle Ages by Jeffrey Burton Russell Anarchism by Richard D. Sonn The Emergence OE THE Social Sciences 1642-1792 Richard Olson Twayne Publishers • New York Maxwell Macmillan Canada • Toronto Maxwell Macmillan International • New York Oxford Singapore Sydney The Emergence of the Social Sciences, 1642-1792 Twayne's Studies in Intellectual and Cultural History, No. 5 Copyright © 1993 by Richard Olson All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, including photocopying, recording, or by any information storage and retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher. Twayne Publishers Maxwell Macmillan Canada, Inc. Macmillan Publishing Company 1200 Eglinton Avenue East 866 Third Avenue Suite 200 New York, New York 10022 Don Mills, Ontario M3C 3N1 Macmillan Publishing Company is part of the Maxwell Communication Group of Companies. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Olson, Richard, 1940- The emergence of the social sciences, 1642-1792 / Richard Olson, p. cm. — (Twayne's studies in intellectual and cultural history ; no. 5) Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 0-8057-8607-4 — ISBN 0-8057-8632-5 (pbk.) 1. Social sciences—History. I. Title. II. Series. H51.057 1993 300'.9—dc20 92-36978 CIP 10 987654321 (he) 10 987654321 (pb) The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of American National Standard for Information Sciences—Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials. ANSI Z3948-1984.©™ Printed and bound in the United States of America. Contents Foreword vii 1. Introduction 1 2. Contexts for the Emergence of the Social Sciences: Traditions of Social Discourse and the New Philosophies of the Scientific Revolution 6 3. Renaissance Naturalism and Political Economy in the German Cameralist Tradition 27 4. Rationalist Mechanical Philosophy and the Psychological Tradition of Social Science 35 5. Experimental Mechanical Philosophy, Political Arithmetic, and Political Economy in Seventeenth-Century Britain 57 6. Natural History, Historical Jurisprudence, and the Emergence of Traditions of Philosophical History to the Time of Montesquieu 71 7. Newton, Locke, and Changing Ideas About the Character of Science 83 8. Associationist and Sensationalist Psychologies, Political Radicalism, and Utilitarianism, 1700-1790 96 9. Political Economy and the Consolidation of Economic Liberalism, 1695-1775 118 V Contents 10. Philosophical History (Sociology) and the Emergence of Conservative Ideology^ 1725-67 138 11. Fused Sciences and Mixed Ideological Messages: The Glasgow School of Hutcheson, Smith, and Millar 162 12. Conclusion 190 Chronology 197 Notes and References 201 Bibliographic Essay 213 Index 219 VI Foreword Twayne's Studies in Intellectual and Cultural History consists of brief original studies of major movements in European intellectual and cultural history, emphasizing historical approaches to continuity and change in religion, philosophy, political theory, aesthetics, literature, and science. The series reflects the recent resurgence of innovative contextual as well as theoretical work in these areas, and the more general interest in the historical study of ideas and cultures. It will advance some of the most exciting work in the human sciences as it stimulates further interest in cultural and intellectual history. The books are intended for the educated reader and the serious student; each combines the virtues of accessibility with original interpretations of important topics. Richard Olson's study provides a rich account of the variety of meanings of the sciences of society in their earliest years and of the early development of the disciplines that now go under the name of the social sciences. The focus here is on economics, psychology, political science, and the philosophy of history. The book examines the various strains of social science as they emerged from the constellation of social and intellectual themes important to early modern Europe. Olson's thesis is that psychology, politics, and economics began with strong programmatic emphases, and that they developed as social sciences in ways quite antithetical to their early agendas. The social sciences eventually helped to remake the social conditions out of which they emerged. The book shows both the traditions out of which the social sciences developed and the Vll Foreword problems that they helped to define. In this way, Olson shows how the early social sciences created a bridge between the pre-modern and the modern world. The Emergence of the Social Sciences surveys the very different intellectual and national traditions of England, Germany, and France. It shows how the social sciences, emerging out of very different conditions, come to have strong affinities with one another. This intellectual history is richly contextual, yet it is based on a close reading of the relevant authors. Richard Olson's book points both to the traditions in religion and science within which the social sciences achieved importance, and to their very modern goals which recon¬ figured these traditions. Michael S. Roth Scripps College and the Claremont Graduate School vm 1 J' Introduction i his book has three major objectives. First, it seeks to characterize and briefly analyze each of four major new and self-consciously scientific traditions of discourse about humans and their institutions which emerged in the seventeenth century and came to flourish in the eighteenth. It will pay special attention to methodological issues—explicit and implicit notions of how to formulate questions, structure discourse, and evaluate arguments and evidence. In this connection, it will address a variety of questions. What did the initiators of these new approaches to social knowledge expect to gain from applying scientific methods to their subjects? What did each understand the central features of a scientific approach to be? How did the differences in their answers to methodological questions lead to distinctive and sometimes contradictory conclusions about the extent and limits of human capacities to influence and consciously shape institutions and events? Second, it seeks to explore the ways in which preexistent social, political, and intellectual conditions, interests, and beliefs shaped the emergent traditions of social science. With rare exceptions, the new social sciences inherited their principal problems and many of their initial value orientations from the traditions of discourse they sought to supplant or reform; moreover, they were all initiated to serve particular political, social, economic, or religious interests. In spite of the fact that most of the new social scientists wanted to claim that their methods freed them from biases associated with special parti- 1 Introduction san interests, it is unquestionably true that ideological assumptions were either unwittingly or intentionally incorporated into every seventeenth- and eighteenth-century attempt to formulate a scien¬ tific approach to social subject matter. Some social-scientific tradi¬ tions were initiated in an attempt to stabilize or perfect existing political and social institutions; others sought to accelerate and guide political change; still others claimed to be indifferent to social and governmental forms and capable of improving the quality of human life within any social and political structure. Their initial aims had a bearing on the character of each tradition, and they must be considered if we are to understand the early social sciences. Together, the first and second goals of this work address what recent scholars sometimes call the '"social construction" of the early social sciences. They presume that these sciences, like all other human creations, are shaped by the conditions in which they emerge. New sciences, in particular, are responses to contemporary understandings of the character of science drawn from knowledge of other scientific activities, to specific social and economic circum¬ stances and commitments, and to the special interests they are intended to serve. The third goal of the work is quite different from the first two and is both more ambitious and more problematic. It is to explore the ways in which the emergent traditions of social science operated to reconstruct the intellectual and social contexts out of which they emerged. Like every other form of human creative activity, the sciences operate both as mirrors that reflect features of the culture which produces them and as lamps which illuminate features of that culture's future. Ironically, in no case that I know of did any of the social sciences that emerged in the seventeenth century effectively serve the major interests that its earliest advocates sought to further. A psychological tradition was initiated by Thomas Hobbes to defend political abso¬ lutism and monarchy; yet, as we shall see, it was transformed during the late seventeenth and the eighteenth centuries into the chief buttress of radical social and political positions, including secular socialism and individualistic feminism. Similarly, a sociological tra¬ dition initiated by James Harrington was aimed at undermining the monarchy and promoting republicanism in seventeenth-century England; yet, by the end of the eighteenth century it had become a central prop for reactionary political platforms that sought a return to an imagined absolutist past, a system of feudal vassalage, or even. 2 Introduction in some cases, a preagrarian primitivism. A tradition of political economy initiated by William Petty in order to increase the capabili¬ ties of a central government to manage resources for the general well-being of its citizens and to '"level" their economic standing soon became the foundation of liberal economic doctrines that served principally to limit the role of the state to the protection of private property and rejected notions of distributive justice. Finally, a tradition of cameralism, intended by Ludwig von Sekendorf and Johann Becher to improve the intensely personal and paternalist rule of German princes and to increase the efficiency and productivity of their es'tates, contributed to generating some of the most impersonal, bureaucratic, and inefficient governmental practices of the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries.^ It thus seems that early social-scientific traditions took on lives of their own which turned their impact almost directly against the intentions of their initiators. This perversion of original intent seems peculiarly apt, for if there was a single general principle embraced by all of the social-scientific traditions by the middle of the eighteenth century it was one which is often called "the law of unintended consequences." The most widely cited and ironic expression of this general notion appeared in Bernard Mandeville's The Grumbling Hive, or Knaves Turned Honest (1705) which was eventually expanded into The Fable of the Bees. Mandeville emphasized the seemingly perverse fact that though the wealthy intended only to aggrandize themselves through conspicuous consumption, their vain habits served to stimulate commercial activity and provide jobs for the poor and industrious: whilst luxury Employed a Million of the Poor, And odious Pride a Million more; Envy itself, and Vanity, Were Ministers of industry; Their darling folly—fickleness In diet, furniture, and dress— That strange, ridiculous vice, was made The very wheel that turned the trade. At the hands of such social theorists as Charles-Louis de Secondat, baron de Montesquieu, Giambattista Vico, Adam Smith, Adam Ferguson, and Edmund Burke, this notion was generalized to an 3

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.