ebook img

The Effect of Endogenous Human Capital Accumulation on Optimal PDF

60 Pages·2013·0.33 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The Effect of Endogenous Human Capital Accumulation on Optimal

The Effect of Endogenous Human Capital Accumulation on Optimal Taxation WilliamBPeterman∗ May13,2013 Abstract This paper considers the impact of endogenous human capital accumulation on optimal tax policy in a life cycle model. Including endogenous human capital accumulation, either through learning-by- doing or learning-or-doing, is analytically shown to create a motive for the government to use age- dependent labor income taxes. If the government cannot condition taxes on age, then a capital tax is used in order to mimic such taxes. Quantitatively, in my benchmark model, introducing learning-by- doingcausestheoptimalcapitaltaxtoincreaseby7.3percentagepoints,whileintroducinglearning-or- doingincreasestheoptimalcapitaltaxbyonly0.7percentagepoint. Overall,theoptimalcapitaltaxis 6.6percentagepointshigherinthemodelwithlearning-by-doingcomparedtothemodelwithlearning- or-doing implying that how human capital accumulates is of significant importance when determining theoptimaltaxpolicy.Ifindthattheeffectsoflearning-by-doingonoptimaltaxationareenhancedwhen oneconsidersamodelwithwithincohortheterogeneity. JEL:E24,E62,H21. KeyWords: OptimalTaxation,CapitalTaxation,HumanCapital. ∗20thandCStreetNW,WashingtonDC20551. Tel: 2020-452-3703. E-mail: [email protected]. Viewsexpressed onthissitearemyownanddonotreflecttheviewoftheFederalReserveSystemoritsstaff. Forextensivediscussionsandhelp- fulcomments,Ithanktheanonymousreferee,VasiaPanousi,IrinaTelyukova,ValerieRamey,RogerGordon,andScottBorger, aswellasseminarparticipantsatUniversityofCaliforniaatSanDiego,MadridMacroeconomicWorkshop,theFederalReserve BoardofGovernors,theFederalReserveBankofPhiladelphia,theEasternEconomicsAssociationConference,theMissouriEco- nomicsConference,theMidwesternMacroeconomicsConference,andtheConferenceinComputinginEconomicsandFinance. Apreviousversionofthispaperwasdistributedunderthetitle“TheEffectofLearning-by-DoingonOptimalTaxation” 1 1 Introduction In their seminal works, Chamley (1986) and Judd (1985) determine that it is not optimal to tax capital in an infinitely-lived agent model. In contrast, previous studies using simplified life cycle models (Atkeson et al. (1999), Erosa and Gervais (2002), and Garriga (2001)) demonstrate that if the government cannot conditionlaborincometaxesonage,thenitwillgenerallybeoptimaltotaxcapitalatanon-zerorate.1 The government ideally wants to condition tax on age since variation in age-specific human capital causes the agenttovaryhisconsumptionandlaboroverthelifecycle.2 Whenthegovernmentcannotconditionlabor incometaxesonage,itisgenerallyoptimaltotaxcapitalinordertomimicanage-dependenttax. Recently, quantitativeexercisesbyConesaetal.(2009)andPeterman(2013)demonstratethatinacalibratedlifecycle model,theinabilitytoconditiontaxesonagecanbeastrongmotiveforapositivecapitaltax. Even though age-specific human capital is a driving mechanism for the positive optimal capital tax, previous life cycle studies typically incorporate human capital variation in models exogenously through age-specificproductivitylevels. Byincludinghumancapitalaccumulationexogenously, themodelsignore any effect that endogenous accumulation may have on the optimal tax policy. This paper analytically and quantitativelyassessestheimpactofincludingendogenousage-specifichumancapitalaccumulationonthe optimalcapitaltaxinalifecyclemodel. Specifically, this paper explores the effect on optimal tax policy of including either of two different forms of endogenous age-specific human capital accumulation: learning-by-doing (LBD) and learning-or- doing (LOD). In LBD, an agent acquires human capital by working. In LOD, which is also referred to as BenPorathtypeskillaccumulationoron-the-jobtraining,anagentacquireshumancapitalbyspendingtime training in periods in which he is also working.3 With LBD, an agent determines his level of age-specific human capital by choosing the hours he works, while with LOD, an agent determines his human capital by choosing the hours he trains. I analyze the effects of both forms, since there is empirical evidence that each form is responsible for age-specific human capital accumulation, and each is commonly employed in quantitativelifecyclemodels.4 1Atkesonetal.(1999)demonstratearelatedresult. Theyshowconditionsunderwhichtheoptimalcapitaltaxiszeroifage- dependenttaxesonlaborincomeareallowed.Gervais(2010)demonstratesthataprogressivelaborincometaxcanalsomimicking age-dependenttaxesonlaborincome. 2Idefineage-specifichumancapitalaschangesinanindividual’slaborproductivitythroughouthisworklife.Someothermodel features, includingliquidityconstraints, retirement, andstochasticearningsmayalsocausevariationsinconsumptionandlabor overthelifecycleandgeneratearationalefortaxesoncapitalincome. 3Thispaperdoesnotevaluatetheeffectofformaleducationonoptimaltaxpolicysincethepaperfocusesontrainingoncean individualsbeginsworking.Therefore,thequantitativemodeliscalibratetoexcludetimespentinschool.However,themechanisms bywhichLODchangestheoptimaltaxpolicywouldbesimilarifindividualsworkwhileattendingschool. 4ExamplesoflifecyclestudiesthatincludevariationsofLBDorLODincludeHansenand˙Imrohorogˇlu(2009),ImaiandKeane (2004),Changetal.(2002),Jonesetal.(1997),JonesandManuelli(1999),Guvenenetal.(2009),Kuruscu(2006),Kapicka(2006), 2 I analytically demonstrate that including either LBD or LOD causes the optimal tax policy to include age-dependent taxes. I demonstrate this result in a model with a utility function that is both separable and homothetic with respect to consumption and hours worked. In contrast, Garriga (2001) demonstrates in a similar model with exogenous age-specific human capital accumulation the optimal tax policy does not include age-dependent taxes on labor income.5 Determining whether age-dependent taxes are optimal is importantbecauseiftheyarenotinthefeasiblepolicyset,thenanon-zerocapitaltaxcanbeusedtomimic the wedge created by conditioning labor income taxes on age. Specifically, a positive (negative) tax on capital can be used to impose the same wedge on the marginal rate of substitution as a relatively larger (smaller)taxonyounglaborincome. Furthermore, the form by which one includes endogenous human capital accumulation qualitatively changes the properties of the optimal capital income tax. In a model with exogenous skill accumulation, anagent’sonlyincentivetoworkishiswage. InamodelwithLBD,thebenefitsfromworkingarecurrent wages as well as an increase in future age-specific human capital. I refer to these benefits as the “wage benefit”andthe“humancapitalbenefit,”respectively. Theimportanceofthehumancapitalbenefitdecreases as an agent approaches retirement. Thus, adding LBD causes the agent to supply labor relatively less elasticallyearlyinhislifecomparedwithlaterinhislife. Relyingmoreheavilyonacapitaltaxreducesthe distortionsthatthistaxpolicyimposesontheeconomy,sinceitimplicitlytaxesthislesselasticallysupplied laborincomefromyoungeragentsatahigherratethanolderagents. Irefertothischannelastheelasticity channelsinceanalterationtothelaborsupplyelasticityprofileisresponsibleforthechangeintheoptimal capitaltax. Adding LOD to the model also causes the government to use a non-zero capital tax. There are two channelsthroughwhichLODaffectstheoptimaltaxpolicy: theelasticitychannelandthesavingschannel. First,addingLODchangesanagent’selasticityprofile. Trainingisanimperfectsubstituteforlaborasboth involve forfeiting leisure in exchange for higher lifetime income. The substitutability of training decreases as an agent ages since he has less time to take advantage of the accumulated skills. Therefore, introducing LOD causes a young agent to supply labor relatively more elastically. Because of this elasticity channel, theoptimalcapitaltaxislowerinordertodecreasestheimplicitrelativetaxesonlaborincomeofyounger agents. Thesecondchannel,thesavingschannel,arisesbecausetrainingisanalternativemethodofsaving, andKapicka(2009). Topel(1990),Cossaetal.(1999),Altug˘ andMiller(1998)provideempiricalevidenceofLBD.Theauthors showthatpasthoursworkedandlengthofcurrentjobtenureimpactcurrentwages.WithregardstoLOD,numerousstudiesprovide evidencethatindividualspartakeintrainingandthatthetrainingisresponsibleforwagegrowth.ForexamplesseeMulligan(1995), FrazisandLoewenstein(2006),Kuruscu(2006),andMincer(1989). 5Ahostofworkdemonstratesasimilarsetofresultsinatwogenerationmodelwithasinglecohort. Twoexamplesofthese worksincludeAtkinsonandStiglitz(1976),andDeaton(1979). 3 as opposed to accumulating physical capital. When the government taxes labor they implicitly decrease the desirability to save via training as opposed to ordinary capital. In order to mitigate this distortion, the government increases the capital tax. Since these two channels have counteracting effects, one cannot analyticallydeterminethecumulativedirectionoftheirimpactontheoptimaltaxpolicy.6 I quantitatively assess the effect of adding each form of endogenous age-specific human capital ac- cumulation on optimal tax policy in a calibrated life cycle model using the specific utility function from Garriga (2001). In a calibrated overlapping generations model (OLG) model which includes exogenously determined retirement, a reduced form social security program, lifetime length uncertainty, and exogenous age-specific human capital (exogenous model), I find that the optimal tax rates are 18.2 percent on capital and 23.7 percent on labor. Unlike the analytically tractable model, the optimal capital tax is non-zero with exogenous human capital accumulation because I include additional features in this more realistic model.7 I find that adding either form of endogenous human capital increases the optimal capital tax. In the model withLBDtheoptimaltaxratesare25.5percentoncapitaland22.1percentonlabor. Theoptimaltaxrates in the model with the LOD framework are 18.9 percent on capital and 23.6 percent on labor. Adding en- dogenous age-specific human capital accumulation raises the optimal capital tax by 7.3 percentage points (approximatelyfortypercent)intheLBDframeworkand0.7percentagepoint(approximatelyfourpercent) in the LOD framework. Overall, the optimal capital tax is 6.6 percentage points (35 percent) higher in the model with LBD compared to the model with LOD indicating that the form by which human capital accumulatesisquantitativelyimportantfordeterminingtheoptimaltaxpolicy. Itestthesensitivityoftheseresultswithrespecttotheutilityfunction. Usinganalternativeutilityfunc- tion that is neither separable nor homothetic with respect to consumption and hours worked, I find that the optimal capital tax is much larger in the exogenous model. The optimal capital tax is larger because, with this utility function, the Frisch labor supply elasticity profile is upward sloping regardless of the form of human capital accumulation. Nevertheless, I find that including either form of endogenous human capital accumulationwiththisutilityfunctioncausesanevenlargerincreaseintheoptimalcapitaltax. Theoptimal capitaltaxincreasesbyapproximately14.5percentagepoints(fortysixpercent)and4.7percentagepoints (fifteenpercent)whenLBDandLODareincluded,respectively. Theoptimalcapitaltaxisstill9.8percent- agepoints(twentysevenpercent)higherintheLBDmodelcomparedtotheLODmodel. Therefore,evenin thissetupwhichhasalargemotiveforacapitaltaxintheexogenousmodel,includingendogenoushuman capitalaccumulationscausestheoptimalcapitaltaxtoincrease. 6Itisassumedthatthegovernmentcannotdirectlytaxhumancapitalsinceitisunobservable. 7SeePeterman(2013)foranindepthdiscussionofmotivesforapositivecapitaltaxincalibratedOLGmodel. 4 InthebenchmarkmodelincludingLBDhasalargeeffectontheoptimaltaxpolicy. However,thisspec- ification may not capture all of the effects of LBD on optimal tax policy because it abstracts from within cohort heterogeneity. Therefore, in this framework, the optimal tax policy only considers efficiency as op- posed to determining the optimal tradeoff between efficiency and equity. To assess whether LBD has an effect on this tradeoff, I examine a model that includes inequality through idiosyncratic labor productivity shocks. IfindthatinthismodelincludingLBDcauseslargerdifferencesintheoptimaltaxpolicies. Specif- ically, I find that the efficiency costs of a redistributive tax policy are larger in the LBD model leading to a lessprogressiveoptimallabortax. Furthermore,IfindthattheincreaseintheoptimalcapitaltaxwhenLBD isincludedislargerinthisspecification;theoptimalcapitaltaxincreasesfrom12.5intheexogenousmodel to36percentintheLBDmodel. This paper is generally related to a class of research which demonstrates that in a model where the government has an incomplete set of tax instruments a non-zero capital tax may be optimal in order to mimicthemissingtaxes(seeCorreia(1996),ArmenterandAlbanesi(2009),andJonesetal.(1997)). This papercombinestworelatedstrandsoftheliteraturewithinthisclassofresearch. Thefirststrandexamines theoptimalcapitaltaxinacalibratedlifecyclemodelwithexogenoushumancapitalwherethegovernment cannot condition labor income taxes on age. Conesa et al. (2009), henceforth CKK, solve a calibrated life cycle model to determine the optimal capital tax. They determine that the optimal tax policy is a flat 34 percentcapitaltaxandaflat14percentlaborincometax.8 Theystatethataprimarymotiveforimposinga high capital tax is to mimic a relatively larger labor income tax on younger agents when they supply labor relatively less elastically. An agent supplies labor more elastically as he ages because his labor supply is decreasing,andtheauthorsuseautilityspecificationinwhichtheagent’sFrischlaborsupplyelasticityisa negativefunctionofhoursworked. Peterman(2013)confirmsthatthisisaneconomicallysignificantmotive for the positive capital tax in a model similar to CKK’s model, but concludes that the restriction on the government from being able to tax accidental bequests at a different rate from ordinary capital income is alsoalargecontributiontothepositiveoptimalcapitaltax.9 However,CespedesandKuklik(2012)findthat when a non-linear mapping between hours and wages is incorporated into a model similar to CKK hours becomemorepersistentandtheoptimalcapitaltaxfallsignificantly. Thispaperextendsthesepreviouslife cycle studies of optimal tax policy by determining how the optimal tax policy changes when endogenous 8ThisismodelM4inConesaetal.(2009). IrefertoCKK’smodelthatabstractsfromidiosyncraticearningsriskandwithin- cohortheterogeneitybecausetheyfindthatthesefeaturesdonotaffecttheleveloftheoptimalcapitaltax.Therefore,Ialsoabstract fromthesefeaturesinmybenchmarkanalysis. 9Furtherwork,suchas,Karabarbounis(2012)andPeterman(2012),demonstratethatincorporatingendogenousfluctuationsin laborsupplyontheextensivemargincanenhancethismotiveforthegovernmenttouseacapitaltaxtomimicage-dependenttaxes onlaborincome. 5 age-specifichumancapitalaccumulationisincludedinthisstandardlifecyclemodel. This paper is related to a second strand of the literature that analyzes the tradeoff between labor and capital taxes in a model that includes endogenous age-specific human capital accumulation but not in a life cycle model.10 For example, both Jones et al. (1997) and Judd (1999) examine optimal capital tax in an infinitely lived agent model in which agents are required to use market goods to acquire human capital similartoordinarycapital. Theyfindthatifthegovernmentcandistinguishbetweenpureconsumptionand human capital investment, then it is not optimal to distort either human or physical capital accumulation in the long run. Reis (2007) shows in a similar model that if the government cannot distinguish between consumption and human capital investment, then the optimal capital tax is still zero as long as the level of capitaldoesnotinfluencetherelativeproductivityofhumancapital. Chenetal.(2010)findinaninfinitely lived agent model with labor search, that including endogenous human capital accumulation through both LBD and LOD causes the optimal capital tax to increase because a higher capital tax unravels the labor market frictions.11 This second strand of literature does not account for the effects of endogenous human capital accumulation through life cycle channels. Since CKK and Peterman (2013) demonstrate that these lifecyclechannelsarequantitativelyimportantformotivatingapositivecapitaltaxthispaperincludesthem. Overall, this paper combines both strands of the literature and determines the optimal tax policy in a life cyclemodelwithendogenouslydeterminedhumancapital. This paper is organized as follows: Section 2 examines an analytically tractable version of the model todemonstratethatincludingendogenoushumancapitalaccumulationcreatesamotiveforthegovernment toconditionlaborincometaxesonage. Section3describesthefullmodelandthecompetitiveequilibrium usedinthequantitativeexercises. Thecalibrationandfunctionalformsarediscussedinsection4. Section5 describesthecomputationalexperiment,andsection6presentstheresults. Section7teststhesensitivityof theresultswithrespecttocalibrationparametersandutilityspecifications,whilesection8concludes. 10OnepaperthatcombinesbothstrandsisJacobsandBovenberg(2009),whichanalyzesthetradeoffbetweenalaborandcapital taxinalifecyclemodelwithpre-workeducation. Theauthorsfindthatinatwo-periodmodelwhereagentsacquireeducationin thefirstperiodandworkinthesecondperiodtheoptimalcapitaltaxisgenerallypositiveifeducationalinvestmentisnotverifiable. Thetaxoncapitalreducesthetaxonlaborincome,whichinturnreducesthedistortionsonthebenefittoeducation. Jacobsand Bovenberg(2009)isrelatedtothecurrentwork; howevertheyfocusonhumancapitalaccumulationpriortoworkingwhilethis studyexaminestheresultsofendogenoushumancapitalaccumulationonceanagentbeginstowork.Inanotherrelatedpaper,Best andKleven(2012)examinehowintroducingLBDchangestheoptimalgeneralincometaxinamodelwithoutsavings. Bestand Kleven(2012)showsthatintroducingLBDcausesthegovernmenttochangetheprogressivityofthetaxratessuchthattherelative taxonyoungincomeincreases. Thisresultissimilartotheresultinthispaper. However,inthispaperwhenthegovernmentcan useeitheraprogressivetaxonlabororanon-zerotaxoncapitaltomimicage-dependenttaxestheychoosethetaxoncapital. 11ThelabormarketfrictionsinChenetal.(2010)causealowerlevelofemploymentintheireconomy. Acapitaltaxcausesthe wagediscounttoincrease,thuscausingfirmstopostmorevacancieswhichinturncausesanincreaseinworkerparticipation. 6 2 Analytical Model Inthissection,Idemonstratethataddingendogenoushumancapitalaccumulationoverturnstheresultfrom Garriga(2001)thatforaspecificutilityfunctionthatisseparableandhomotheticinbothconsumptionand laborthegovernmenthasnoincentivetoconditionlaborincometaxesonage. Itisusefultodetermineifthe government wants to use age-dependent taxes because both Garriga (2001) and Erosa and Gervais (2002) showthatifthegovernmentwantstoconditiontaxesonageandcannotdosothentheoptimalcapitaltaxwill generallybenon-zeroinordertomimicthisage-dependenttax. Ibeginthissectionbysettinguptheagent’s problem and demonstrating why a capital tax is an imperfect substitute for age-dependent taxes on labor income. Next, using the primal approach, I solve for the optimal tax policy in the exogenous model, with a benchmark utility function that is homothetic with respect to consumption and hours worked,U(c,h)= c1−σ1 −χ(h)1+σ12 . I confirm the Garriga (2001) result that the government has no incentive to condition 1−σ1 1+σ12 labor income taxes on age and therefore the optimal capital tax is zero. I show that adding endogenous human capital accumulation to this model causes the optimal tax policy to include age-dependent taxes. Thereforetheseresults,coupledwiththepreviousfindingsinGarriga(2001)andErosaandGervais(2002), demonstratethatifage-dependenttaxesareunavailableintheendogenousmodel,thenanon-zerocapitaltax isoptimal. Ialsodemonstratethechannelsbywhichtheformsofendogenoushumancapitalaccumulation affecttheoptimaltaxpolicy. I derive these analytical results in a tractable two-period version of the computational model. For tractability purposes, the features I abstract from include: retirement, population growth, progressive tax policy,andconditionalsurvivability. Additionally,Iassumethatthemarginalproductsofcapitalandlabor areconstant. Thisassumptionpermitsmetofocusonthelifecycleelementsofthemodel,inthatchangesto thetaxsystemdonotaffectthepre-taxwageorrateofreturn. Sincethefactorpricesdonotvary,Isuppress theirtimesubscriptsinthissection. Alloftheseassumptionsarerelaxedinthecomputationalmodel. 2.1 ExogenousAge-SpecificHumanCapital 2.1.1 GeneralSet-up In the analytically tractable model, agents live with certainty for two periods, and their preferences over consumptionandlaborarerepresentedby U(c ,h )+βU(c ,h ) (1) 1,t 1,t 2,t+1 2,t+1 7 where β is the discount rate, c is the consumption of an age j agent at time t, and h is the percent of j,t j,t the time endowment the agent works.12 Age-specific human capital is normalized to unity when the agent is young. At age two, age-specific human capital is ε . The agent maximizes equation 1 with respect to 2 consumptionandhourssubjecttothefollowingconstraints c +a =(1−τ )h w (2) 1,t 1,t h,1 1,t and c =(1+r(1−τ ))a +(1−τ )ε h w, (3) 2,t+1 k 1,t h,2 2 2,t+1 where a is the amount young agents save, τ is the tax rate on labor income for an agent of age j, τ is 1,t h,j k thetaxrateoncapitalincome,wistheefficiencywageforlaborservices,andristherentalrateoncapital. I assumethatthetaxrateonlaborincomecanbeconditionedonage;however,thetaxrateoncapitalincome cannot.13 Icombineequations2and3toformajointintertemporalbudgetconstraint: c w(1−τ )ε h 2,t+1 h,2 2 2,t+1 c + =w(1−τ )h + . (4) 1,t h,1 1,t 1+r(1−τ ) 1+r(1−τ ) k k Theagent’sproblemistomaximizeequation1subjectto4. Theagent’sfirstorderconditionsare U (t) h1 =−w(1−τ ), (5) h,1 U (t) c1 U (t+1) h2 =−wε (1−τ ), (6) 2 h,2 U (t+1) c2 and U (t) c1 =β(1+r(1−τ )), (7) k U (t+1) c2 whereU (t)≡ ∂U(c1,t,h1,t). Given a social welfare function, prices, and taxes, these first order conditions, c1 ∂c1,t combinedwiththeintertemporalbudgetconstraint,determinetheoptimalallocationof(c ,h ,c ,h ). 1,t 1,t 2,t+1 2,t+1 12Timeworkingismeasuredasapercentageofendowmentandnotinhours.However,forexpositionalconvenience,Ialsorefer tohj,t ashours. 13Agentsonlylivefortwoperiodsintheanalyticallytractablemodelsotheychoosenottosavewhentheyareold.Therefore,in thismodeltherestrictiononthecapitaltaxpolicyisnotbinding. 8 2.1.2 TaxonCapitalMimicsAge-DependentTaxonLabor To demonstrate why a capital tax has a similar effect to an age-dependent labor income tax, I derive the intertemporalEulerequationbycombiningequations5,6,and7: U (t) 1−τ h1 h,1 ε =β(1+r(1−τ )) . (8) 2 k U (t+1) 1−τ h2 h,2 Equation8demonstratesthatifthegovernmentwantstocreateawedgeonthemarginalrateofsubstitution byvaryingthelaborincometaxratebyage,thenτ isanalternativeoption. Apositive(negative)capitaltax k inducesawedgeonthemarginalrateofsubstitutionthatissimilartoarelativelylargertaxonyoung(old) laborincome. 2.1.3 PrimalApproach I use the primal approach to determine the optimal tax policy.14 I use a social welfare function that maxi- mizes the expected utility of a newborn and discounts future generations with social discount factor θ (see section5formoredetails), ∞ [U(c ,h )/θ]+∑θt[U(c ,h )+βU(c ,h )]. (9) 2,0 2,0 1,t 1,t 2,t+1 2,t+1 t=0 The government maximizes this objective function with respect to two constraints: the implementability constraintandtheresourceconstraint.15 Theimplementabilityconstraintistheagent’sintertemporalbudget constraint,withpricesandtaxesreplacedbyhisfirstorderconditions(equations5,6,and7) c U (t)+βc U (t+1)+h U (t)+βh U (t+1)=0. (10) 1,t c1 2,t+1 c2 1,t h1 2,t+1 h2 Includingthisconstraintensuresthatanyallocationthegovernmentchoosescanbesupportedbyacompet- itiveequilibrium. Theresourceconstraintis c +c +K −K +G =rK +w(h +h ε ). (11) 1,t 2,t t+1 t t t 1,t 2,t 2 14SeeLucasandStokey(1983)orErosaandGervais(2002)forafulldescriptionoftheprimalapproach. 15Thegovernmentbudgetconstraintisathirdconstraint. DuetoWalras’Law,Ionlyneedtoincludetwoofthreeconstraintsin theLagrangianandleaveoutthegovernmentbudgetconstraint. 9 Includingthebenchmarkutilityspecification,theLagrangianthegovernmentmaximizesis 1+ 1 1+ 1 c1−σ1 h σ2 c1−σ1 h σ2 L = 1,t −χ 1,t +β 2,t+1 −χ 2,t+1 (12) 1−σ1 1+ 1 1−σ1 1+ 1 σ2 σ2 −ρ (c +c +K −K +G −rK −w(h +h ε )) t 1,t 2,t t+1 t t t 1,t 2,t 2 −ρ θ(c +c +K −K +G −rK −w(h +h ε )) t+1 1,t+1 2,t+1 t+2 t+1 t+1 t+1 1,t+1 2,t+1 2 1+ 1 1+ 1 +λ (c1−σ1+βc1−σ1−χh σ2 −βχh σ2) t 1,t 2,t+1 1,t 2,t+1 whereρistheLagrangemultiplierontheresourceconstraintandλistheLagrangemultiplierontheimple- mentabilityconstraint. 2.1.4 OptimalTaxPolicy Isolvefortheoptimaltaxpolicyintheanalyticallytractableexogenousmodel. Theformulationofthegov- ernment’sproblemandtheirfirstorderconditionsforthismodelcanbefoundinappendixA.1. Combining thegovernment’sfirstorderconditionsgeneratesthefollowingexpressionforoptimallaborincometaxes: 1−τh,2 = 1+λt(1+σ12) =1. (13) 1−τh,1 1+λt(1+σ12) Equation13demonstratesthatthegovernmenthasnoincentivetoconditionlaborincometaxesonagewhen age-specifichumancapitalisexogenous.16 UtilizingthefirstorderconditionfromtheLagrangianwithrespecttocapitalandconsumptionleadsto thefollowingequation: (cid:32) (cid:33)−σ1 c 1,t =β(1+r). (14) c 2,t+1 Applyingthebenchmarkutilityfunctiontoequation7providesthefollowingrelationship: (cid:32) (cid:33)−σ1 c 1,t =β(1+r(1−τ )). (15) k c 2,t+1 Equations14and15demonstratethatinorderforthehouseholdtochoosetheoptimalallocationindicated bytheprimalapproach,thecapitaltaxmustequalzero.17 16Thisresultisspecifictothisutilityfunction.SeeGarriga(2001)forfurtherdetails. 17Regardlessofwhetherthegovernmentcanconditionlaborincometaxesonage,inthismodeltheydonotwanttotaxcapital becausethereisnodesiretomimicanage-dependenttaxonlaborincome. Whenthegovernmentcannotconditionlaborincome 10

Description:
May 13, 2013 This paper considers the impact of endogenous human capital accumulation on optimal tax policy in a life cycle model. Including endogenous
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.