ebook img

The Birth of a Consumer Society: The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England PDF

353 Pages·1982·6.606 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview The Birth of a Consumer Society: The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England

The Birth of a Consumer Society The Commercialization of Eighteenth-Century England Neil McKendrick, John Brewer and J. H. Plumb INDIANA UNIVERSITY PRESS Bloomington Copyright© 1982 by Neil McKendrick, John Brewer and J. H. Plumb All rights reserved No part of this book may be reproduced or utilized in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying and recording, or by any information storage and retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher. The Association of American University Presses’ Resolution on Permissions constitutes the only exception to this prohibition. Manufactured in (treat Britain Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data McKendrick, Neil. The birth of a consumer society. Includes bibliographical references. 1. Consumers—England—History—18th century. 2. Consumption (Economics)—England—History— 18th cen­ tury. 3. Leisure—England—History—18th century. 4. England—Economic conditions—18th century. I. Brewer, John, 1947- . II. Plumb, J. H. (John Harold), 1911- . III. Title. HC257.E5M37 306’.3’0942 82-47953 ISBN 0-253-31205-1 AACR2 Contents Notes on the Authors vi Preface Neil McKendrick vii Introduction. The Birth of a Consumer Society: the Commercialization 1 of Eighteenth-Century England Neil McKendrick PART I: COMMERCIALIZATION AND THE ECONOMY Neil McKendrick 1. The Consumer Revolution of Eighteenth-Century England 9 2. The Commercialization of Fashion 34 3. Josiah Wedgwood and the Commercialization of the Potteries 99 4. George Packwood and the Commercialization of Shaving: The Art of Eighteenth-Century Advertising or “The Way to Get Money and be Happy” 145 PART II: COMMERCIALIZATION AND POLITICS John Breioer 5. Commercialization and Politics 197 PART III: COMMERCIALIZATION AND SOCIETY J. H. Plumb 6. The Commercialization of Leisure 265 7. The New World of Children 286 8. The Acceptance of Modernity 316 Index 335 Notes on the Authors Neil McKendrick graduated with a ‘starred’ first in History at Cambridge in 1956. He was elected into a Research Fellowship at Christ’s College in 1958, and is now Fellow, College Lecturer, and Director of Studies in History at Gonville and Caius College. He has been a University Lecturer in Cambridge since 1961. He edited Historical Perspectives: Studies in English Thought and Society (1974), and has contributed to E. M. Carus- Wilson, Essays in Economic History (1962), D. S. Landes, The Rise of Capitalism (1966) and M. Teich and R. Young, Changing Perspectives in the History of Science (1973). He is general editor of the Europa Library of Business Biography and has published extended introductions on the theme of ‘The Luddite Interpretation of History’ in the first four volumes—R. J. Overy, William Morris, Viscount Nuffield (1976), Clive Trebilcock, The Vickers Brothers (1977), P. N. Davies, Sir Alfred Jones (1978), and Roy Church, Herbert Austin (1979). He is also general editor of the Europa History of Human Experience in which the first three volumes on Crime, Death and Marriage have so far appeared. He is, perhaps, best known for his work on Josiah Wedgwood and the Industrial Revolution. John Brewer graduated with a ‘starred’ first in History at Cambridge in 1968. He was elected into a Research Fellowship at Sidney Sussex College in 1969. He was visiting Professor at Washington University, St. Louis in 1972-3. He was an Assistant University Lecturer in History at Cambridge from 1973-6. He became Associate Professor at Yale in 1976, and is now Professor of History and Literature at Harvard. He published Party Ideology and Popular Politics at the Accession of George III (1976), and edited (with John Styles) An Ungovernable People (1980). He is, perhaps, best known for his work on John Wilkes and popular politics of the eighteenth century. J. H. Plumb graduated with the first First in History achieved from Leicester University in 1933. He was elected into a Research Fellowship at King’s College, Cambridge in 1939, and a Fellow of Christ’s College in 1946. He was successively Lecturer, Reader and Professor at Cambridge. He is now Master of Christ’s College and Emeritus Professor of Modern English History. He has been visiting Professor at Columbia, New York City and Texas Universities. He has published England in the Eighteenth Century (1950), Chatham (1953), The First Four Georges (1956), Sir Robert Walpole, vol. I (1956) and vol. II (1960), Men and Places (1962), The Growth of Political Stability in England, 1675-1725 (1967), Death of the Past (1969), In the Light of History (1972), Royal Heritage (1977), Georgian Delights (1980) and many other works. He is General Editor of the Fontana History of Europe and the Hutchinson History of Human Society. He is, perhaps, best known as a scholar for his work on Sir Robert Walpole and early eighteenth-century politics. Preface This book was conceived at a meeting of the Caius historical society—a body sometimes more noted for its critical rigour than for its creative vigour—when after a paper by Professor Brewer, it became clear that the three authors of this book had all, at different times, been working separately in Cambridge on different aspects of the commercialization of eighteenth-century England. Neil McKendrick’s work on Wedgwood had drawn attention in the early 1960s to the commercial revolution which Wedgwood and Bentley had achieved in their own industry;1 Professor Plumb in the early 1970s had drawn attention to the commercialization of leisure in his Slenton Lecture;2 and finally Professor Brewer’s work on Wilkes had revealed parallel devel­ opments in the political world.3 To draw together the work of three scholars—one working primarily in economic history, one (on this occasion) in social history, and one in political history—is more unusual than it should be. To do so in a monograph which hopes to stimulate more research in an exciting but little publicized field, and which is inevitably more speculative than definitive in some areas is possibly more adventurous than it should be. But all three contributors have done further recent work in this field4 and are convinced that they have jointly identified an important and neglected historical phenomenon. They feel that it deserves both greater recognition and more detailed attention. If by jointly publishing some of the results of their past and recent research they can establish the former and encourage the latter they will be more than satisfied. Even if they fail to achieve either of these modest ambitions, there are consolations to be found in this essay in co-operation. For it is comforting to note how much of the work of scholars operating within ostensibly separate (and all too often mutually hostile) historical disciplines can fruitfully overlap. And it is difficult to deny that when the authors’ three separate and 1 Neil McKendrick, ‘Josiah Wedgwood: An Eighteenth Century Entrepreneur in Salesmanship and Marketing Techniques’. Economic History Review, 2nd series, XII, no. 3 (April I960), pp. 408-33. (Reprinted in Essays in Economic History, ed. E. M. Carus-Wilson, vol. Ill (1962), pp. 353-70; ‘The Discovery of Pompeii and Herculaneum and the Neo-Classical Revival’, Horizon, vol. IV, no. 4, March 1962, pp. 42-75; 'Josiah Wedgwood and Thomas Bentley: An Inventor-Entrepreneur Partnership in the Industrial Revolution’, Transactions of the Royal Historical Society, 5th series, vol. 14 (1964), pp. 1-33. 1J H Plumb, The Commercialization oj leisure in Eighteenth Century England (The Stenton Lecture). The University of Reading, 1973. * John Brewer, Parly Ideology and Popular Politics at the Accession oj George III. (Cambridge, 1976). * Neil McKendrick, ‘Home Demand and Economic Growth: A New View of the Role of Women and Children in the Industrial Revolution’, Historical Perspectives: Studies in English Thought and Society, ed. Neil McKendrick (London, 1974), pp. 152-210; J. H. Plumb, 'The New World of Children in Eighteenth Century England’, Past and Present, no. 67, (1975), pp. 64-95, The Pursuit of Happiness (Yale, 1977). and Georgian Delights (London, 1980). vii BIRTH OF A CONSUMER SOCIETY tentative probes into the darkness of the past are brought together, the spotlight they produce illuminates the problem more brightly and throws the whole subject into sharper relief than their individual beams of light could ever have done alone. This is not to suggest that the authors have attempted to focus exclusively on a single aspect of their chosen century. The individual spotlights dance away to reveal, if only partially, other problems lying slightly off-centre on the academic stage, and to offer glimpses of yet others even deeper in the shadows of ignorance and unexplored archives. Individually at least (and outside the confínes of this book) efforts are being made to bring them into focus and into the spotlight too. Some of what is offered here is admittedly in the nature of preliminary studies. As is so often the case, the English critic can offer a more elegant guide to the art of the disarming preface than the historian can, and it is with gratitude that I borrow from Professor Steiner his definition of 'working papers* or 'position papers’, as exercises in which scholars 'put forward a point of view, analysis or proposition’ in a form which while it attempts to be inclusive and is certainly assertive, is nonetheless 'explicitly provisional*.1 Some parts of this book have some claim to be authoritative, others are published specifically to solicit 'correction, modification, and that collabora­ tive disagreement on which the hopes of rational discourse depend’.1 Neil McKendrick Gonville & Caius College, Cambridge. ‘George Steiner, On Difficulty (Oxford, 1978). Preface. INTRODUCTION The Birth of a Consumer Society The Commercialization of Eighteenth-century England by Neil McKendrick ‘The English of those several denominations [Peasants and Mechanics, Farmers, Freeholders, Tradesmen and Manufacturers in Middling Life, Wholesale Dealers, Merchants and all persons of Landed Estates] have better Conveniences in their Houses and affect to have more in Quantity of clean, neat Furniture, and a greater variety, such as Carpets, Screens, Window Curtains, Chamber Bells, polished Brass Locks, Fenders etc., (Things Hardly known abroad among persons of such Rank) than are to be found in any other Country of Europe ... were an inventory to be taken of Household Goods and Furniture of a Peasant, or Mechanic, in France, and of a Peasant, or Mechanic in England, the latter would be found on average to Exceed the former in Value by at least three to one.’ JOSIAH TUCKER Introduction There was a consumer revolution in eighteenth-century England. More men and women than ever before in human history enjoyed the experience of acquiring material possessions. Objects which for centuries had been the privileged possessions of the rich came, within the space of a few generations, to be within the reach of a larger part of society than ever before, and, for the first time, to be within the legitimate aspirations of almost all of it. Objects which were once acquired as the result of inheritance at best, came to be the legitimate pursuit of a whole new class of consumers. What men and women had once hoped to inherit from their parents, they now expected to buy for themselves. What were once bought at the dictate of need, were now bought at the dictate of fashion. What were once bought for life, might now be bought several times over. What were once available only on high days and holidays through the agency of markets, fairs and itinerant pedlars were increasingly made available every day but Sunday through the additional agency of an ever-advancing network of shops and shopkeepers. As a result ‘luxuries’ came to be seen as mere ‘decencies’, and ‘decencies’ came to be seen as ‘necessities’. Even ‘necessities’ underwent a dramatic metamorphosis in style, variety and availability. Where once material possessions were prized for their durability, they were now increasingly prized for their fashionability. Where once a fashion might last a lifetime, now it might barely last a year. Where once women had merely dreamed of following the prevailing London fashions, they could now follow them daily in the advertisements in the provincial press, and actually buy them from the ever-increasing number of commercial outlets dedicated to satisfying their wants and their needs. Where once consumers eager for new fashions were dependent on the chance of rumour and the impressions of gossip, they could now rely on the accurate details of the illustrated fashion print or ring the changes for themselves on the endless combinations made possible by the English fashion doll; instead of what a quick eye and a retentive memory could glean from the dress of the rich or a visit of the fashionable, there were now precise details minutely recorded in the pages of the fashion magazines for a new and larger market to pore over. Where once the ability to wear such fashions was limited to the very few, now rising real family incomes brought them increasingly within the reach of the many. 1 BIRTH OF A CONSUMER SOCIETY All these changes took place within the confines of the eighteenth century. The result of these changes for those engaged in making and selling objects for the person and for the home were revolutionary. And those making and selling such consumer goods had not only responded to those changes; they had, as a result of their earnest commercial endeavours, played a substantial and a positive role in bringing them about. They had helped to release and to satisfy a consumer boom of major proportions. This is not to suggest, of course, that the desire to consume was an eighteenth-century novelty. It was the ability to do so which was new. The ferocious pursuit of getting and spending has a long history. The feverish pursuit of fashion is just as ancient. Extravagant patterns of consumer behaviour can be easily traced back to antiquity; and one does not need to trouble post-seventeenth century Europe for the most grotesque examples of conspicuous consumption. But in the past the acquisitive part of society was a tiny one. Its indomitable pursuit of possessions satisfied more than personal greed and personal whim. It signalled more than simple, or even ornate, extravagances. It served important social and political functions too. Rich clothes, fine furs and precious gems, for instance, could mark the divinity of a king, and radiate the splendour and standing of his court. They could underline the exclusive status of the nobility, or the professional status of lawyers, doctors, and the educated élite. To preserve those distinctions sumptuary laws might be required to reinforce the effects of poverty, to buttress the conservative effects of custom, to insist on the unavailability of a desired cloth, to prevent commercial cunning from bringing it within the reach of those who aspired to wear it. The barriers to a consumer society were therefore numerous and effective. To overcome them required changes in attitude and thought, changes in prosperity and standards of living, changes in commercial technique and promotional skills, sometimes changes even in the law itself. Above all it required the commercialization of society—the process with which this book is mainly concerned. That process was so pervasive that to do justice to it requires that it be followed beyond the world of advertising and selling, beyond the world of fashion and credit. It needs to be pursued into the political world of eighteenth-century England, into the commercialization of leisure, and of childhood, and into the world of invention and creation, where unabashed by any sense of the plenitude of Nature men deliberately sought to create new and improved species and exciting novelties with which to delight the eye, to exhibit one's taste and to assert one’s wealth. The avowed intention was to proclaim one’s ability constantly to improve on the old and the inherited, and of course, to swell the demand for what was new and exciting and modern. The changes in attitude encompassed major political, intellectual and social adjustments as well as the more obvious economic realignments. To demonstrate the revolutionary nature of these changes, it will be necessary 2

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.