ebook img

Stochastic Implied Volatility: A Factor-Based Model PDF

234 Pages·2004·6.584 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Stochastic Implied Volatility: A Factor-Based Model

Lecture N otes in Economies and Mathematical Systems 545 Founding Editors: M. Beckmann H. P. Künzi Managing Editors: Prof. Dr. G. Fandel Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaften Fernuniversität Hagen Feithstr. 140lAVZ II, 58084 Hagen, Germany Prof. Dr. W. Trockel Institut für Mathematische Wirtschaftsforschung (IMW) Universität Bielefeld Universitätsstr. 25, 33615 Bielefeld, Germany Editorial Board: A. Basile, A. Drexl, H. Dawid, K. Inderfurth, W. Kürsten, U. Schittko Reinhold Hafner Stochastic Implied Volatility A Factor-Based Model ~Springer Author Dr. Reinhold Hafner risklab germany GmbH Nymphenburger Straße 112-116 80636 München Germany Library of Congress Control Number: 2004109369 ISSN 0075-8442 ISBN 978-3-540-22183-8 ISBN 978-3-642-17117-8 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-3-642-17117-8 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, re-use of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other way, and storage in data banks. Duplication of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions of the German Copyright Law of September 9, 1965, in its current version, and permission for use must always be obtained from Springer-Verlag. Violations are liable for prosecution under the German Copyright Law. springeronline.com © Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2004 Originally published by Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg New York in 2004 The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. Typesetting: Camera ready by author Cover design: Erich Kirchner, Heidelberg Printed on acid-free paper 42/3130Di 5 4 3 2 1 0 Für meine Eltern Preface This monograph is based on my Ph.D. thesis, which was accepted in Jan uary 2004 by the faculty of economics at the University of Augsburg. It is a great pleasure to thank my supervisor, Prof. Dr. Manfred Steiner, for his scientific guidance and support throughout my Ph.D. studies. I would also like to express my thanks to Prof. Dr. Günter Bamberg for his comments and suggestions. To my colleagues at the department of Finance and Banking at the U ni versity of Augsburg, I express my thanks for their kind support and their helpful comments over the past years. In particular, I would like to thank Dr. Bernhard Brunner for many interesting discussions and also for the careful revision of this manuscript. At risklab germany GmbH, Munich, I would first of alllike to thank Dr. Gerhard Scheuenstuhl and Prof. Dr. Rudi Zagst for creating an ideal environ ment for research. I would also like to express my thanks to my coIleagues. It has been most enjoyable to work with them. In particular, I would like to thank Dr. Bernd Schmid. Our joint projects on stochastic implied volatil ity models greatly influenced this work. I am also indebted to Anja Fischer for valuable contributions during her internship and Didier Vermeiren (from Octanti Associates) for carefuIly reading the manuscript. Further, I am extremely grateful to Prof. Dr. Martin WaIlmeier for his continuous support and advice, his thorough revision of the manuscript, as weIl as for many fruitful discussions. The results of our joint projects on the estimation and explanation of implied volatility structures entered this work. Most of aIl, I want to thank my girlfriend Heike for endless patience, encouragement, and support, and also my mother Lieselotte and my brot her Jürgen for being there aIl the times. Mering, May 2004 Reinhold Hafner Contents 1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 1.1 Motivation and Objectives . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1 1.2 Structure of the Work. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 2 Continuous-time Financial Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 2.1 The Financial Market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 10 2.1.1 Assets and Trading Strategies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 10 2.1.2 Absence of Arbitrage and Martingale Measures. . . . . . .. 13 2.2 Risk-Neutral Pricing of Contingent Claims. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 15 2.2.1 Contingent Claims. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 15 2.2.2 Risk-Neutral Valuation Formula. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 18 2.2.3 Attainability and Market Completeness .............. 20 3 Implied Volatility. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 23 3.1 The Black-Scholes Model ................................. 24 3.1.1 The Financial Market Model ........................ 24 3.1.2 Pricing and Hedging of Contingent Claims. . . . . . . . . . .. 25 3.1.3 The Black-Scholes Option Pricing Formula ........... 27 3.1.4 The Greeks ....................................... 29 3.2 The Concept ofImplied Volatility ......................... 32 3.2.1 Definition........................................ 32 3.2.2 Calculation....................................... 34 3.2.3 Interpretation..................................... 35 3.3 Features of Implied Volatility ............................. 38 3.3.1 Volatility Smiles. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 38 3.3.2 Volatility Term Structures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 39 3.3.3 Volatility Surfaces . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 41 3.4 Modelling Implied Volatility ............... . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 43 3.4.1 Overview......................................... 43 3.4.2 Implied Volatility as an Endogenous Variable ......... 45 3.4.3 Implied Volatility as an Exogenous Variable .......... 51 X Contents 3.4.4 Comparison of Approaches ......................... 56 4 The General Stochastic Implied Volatility Model. . . . . . . . . .. 59 4.1 The Financial Market Model .............................. 60 4.1.1 Model Specification . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 60 4.1.2 Movements of the Volatility Surface ................. 61 4.2 Risk-Neutral Implied Volatility Dynamics. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 63 4.2.1 Change of Measure and Drift Restriction ............. 63 4.2.2 Interpretation of Terms in the Risk-Neutral Drift. . . . .. 68 4.2.3 Existence and Uniqueness of the Risk-Neutral Measure. 68 4.3 Pricing and Hedging of Contingent Claims. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 70 5 Properties of DAX Implied Volatilities .................... 73 5.1 The DAX Option ........................................ 73 5.1.1 Contract Specifications. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 73 5.1.2 Previous Studies .................................. 75 5.2 Data ................................................... 76 5.2.1 Raw Data and Data Preparation .................... 76 5.2.2 Correcting for Taxes and Dividends. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 78 5.2.3 Liquidity Aspects ................................. 82 5.3 Structure of DAX Implied Volatilities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 83 5.3.1 Estimation of the DAX Volatility Surface. . . . . . . . . . . .. 83 5.3.2 Empirical Results ................................. 92 5.3.3 Identification and Selection of Volatility Risk Factors .. 99 5.4 Dynamics of DAX Implied Volatilities ...................... 102 5.4.1 Time-Series Properties of DAX Volatility Risk Factors . 102 5.4.2 Relating Volatility Risk Factors to Index Returns and other Market Variables ............................. 109 5.5 Summary of Empirical Observations ....................... 113 6 A Four-Factor Model for DAX Implied Volatilities ......... 115 6.1 The Model under the Objective Measure ................... 115 6.1.1 Model Specification ................................ 115 6.1.2 Model Estimation ................................. 118 6.1.3 Model Testing .................................... 124 6.2 The Model under the Risk-Neutral Measure ................. 131 6.2.1 Risk-Neutral Stock Price and Volatility Dynamics ..... 131 6.2.2 The Market Price of Risk Process ................... 133 6.2.3 Pricing and Hedging of Contingent Claims ............ 137 6.2.4 Model Calibration ................................. 140 6.3 Model Review and Conclusion ............................ 144 Contents XI 7 Model Applieations ........................................ 145 7.1 Pricing and Hedging of Exotic Derivatives .................. 145 7.1.1 Product Overview ................................. 145 7.1.2 Exotic Equity Index Derivatives ..................... 147 7.1.3 Volatility Derivatives .............................. 153 7.2 Value at Risk for Option Portfolios ........................ 158 7.2.1 The Value at Risk Concept ......................... 158 7.2.2 Computing VaR for Option Portfolios ................ 160 7.2.3 A Case Study ..................................... 162 7.2.4 Beyond VaR: Expected Shortfall .................... 167 7.3 Volatility Trading ....................................... 170 7.3.1 Definition and Motivation .......................... 170 7.3.2 Volatility Trade Design ............................. 171 7.3.3 Profit ability of DAX Volatility Trading Strategies ..... 178 8 Summary and Conclusion .................................. 187 A Some Mathematical Preliminaries ......................... 193 A.l Probability Theory ...................................... 193 A.2 Continuous-time Stochastic Processes ...................... 194 B Pricing of a Varianee Swap via Statie Replieation .......... 201 List of Abbreviations .......................................... 205 List of Symbols ................................................ 207 Referenees ..................................................... 215 Index .......................................................... 225 1 Introduction 1.1 Motivation and Objectives Financial derivatives or contingent claims are specialized contracts whose in tention is to transfer risk from those who are exposed to risk to those who are willing to bear risk for a price. Derivatives are heavily used by different groups of market participants, including financial institutions, fund managers (most notably hedge funds), and corporations. While speculators intend to benefit from the derivative's leverage to make large profits, hedgers want to ins ure their positions against adverse price movements in the derivative's underlying asset, and arbitrageurs are willing to exploit price inefficiencies between the derivative and the underlying asset. During the last two decades the market far financial derivatives has experienced rapid growth. From 2000 to 2002 alone, global exchange-traded derivatives volume nearly doubled, to reach almost 6 billion contracts traded in 2002. With a market share of approximately 50%, equity index derivatives are thereby the most actively traded contracts.1 Huge volumes of derivatives are also traded over the counter (OTC). In addition to standard products, the OTC market offers a wide variety of different con tracts, including so-called exotic derivatives. Exotic derivatives were developed as advancements to standard derivative products with specific characteristics tailared to particular investors' needs. The latest development in this area are volatility derivatives. These contracts, written on realized or implied volatil ity, provide direct exposure to volatility without inducing additional exposure to the underlying asset. The increasing use and complexity of derivatives raises the need for a framework that enables for the accurate and consistent pricing and hedging, risk management, and trading of a wide range of derivative products, including all kinds of exotic derivatives. The first important attempt in this direction was the Black-Scholes option pricing model, developed by BlackjScholes (1973), formalized and extended in the same year by Merton (1973). It builds a cor- lSee FrA (2003). R. Hafner, Stochastic Implied Volatility © Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 2004 2 1 Introduction nerstone in the theory of modern finance, and has led to many insights into the valuation of derivative securities. In 1997, the importance of the model was recognized when Myron Scholes and Robert Merton received the Nobel Price for Economics. The Black-Scholes model provides a unique "fair price" for a (European) option that is traded on a frictionless market and whose underlying asset exhibits lognormally distributed prices. Under the model's assumptions, an option's return stream can be perfectly replicated by con tinuously rebalancing a self-financing portfolio involving stocks2 and risk-free bonds. In the absence of arbitrage, the price of an option equals the initial value of the portfolio that exactly matches the option's payoff. The Black-Scholes model is often applied as a starting point for valuing options. However, the empirical investigation of the Black-Scholes model re vealed statistically significant and economically relevant deviations between market prices and model prices. A convenient way of illustrating these dis crepancies is to express the option price in terms of its implied volatility, i.e. as a number that, when plugged into the Black-Scholes formula for the volatility parameter, results in a model price equal to the market price. If the Black-Scholes model holds exactly, then all options on the same underlying asset should provide the same implied volatility. Yet, as is well known, on many markets, Black-Scholes implied volatilities tend to differ across exercise prices and times to maturity. The relationship between implied volatilities and exercise prices is commonly referred to as the "volatility smile" and the rela tionship between implied volatilities and times to maturity as the "volatility term structure". Volatility surfaces combine the volatility smile with the term structure of volatility. The existence of volatility surfaces implies that the im plied volatility of an option is not necessarily equal to the expected volatility of the underlying asset's rate of return. It rather also reflects determinants of the option's value that are neglected in the Black-Scholes formula. The obvious shortcomings of the Black-Scholes model have led to the de velopment of a considerable literature on alternative option pricing models, which attempt to identify and model the financial mechanisms that give rise to volatility surfaces, in particular to smiles. One strand of the literature concen trates on the nature of the underlying asset price process which was assumed to be a geometric Brownian motion with constant volatility in the Black Scholes framework. Here the main focus is on models which assume that the volatility of the underlying asset varies over time, either deterministically or stochastically. Derman/Kani (1994b), Derman/Kani (1994a), Dupire (1994), and Rubinstein (1994) were the first to model volatility as a deterministic func tion of time and stock price, known as local volatility. The unknown volatility function can be fitted to observed option prices to obtain an implied price process for the underlying asset. In an empirical study Dumas et al. (1998) 2We use the term "stock" as a general expression for the underlying asset of a derivative security, although it could as well be an equity index, an exchange rate, or the price of a commodity.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.