ebook img

sovereign debt relief and its aftermath PDF

37 Pages·2016·1.2 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview sovereign debt relief and its aftermath

SOVEREIGN DEBT RELIEF AND ITS AFTERMATH CarmenM.Reinhart ChristophTrebesch HarvardUniversity,KennedySchool UniversityofMunich Abstract Thispaperstudiessovereigndebtreliefinalong-termperspective.Wequantifythereliefachieved throughdefaultandrestructuringintwodistinctsamples:1920–1939,focusingonthedefaultson official(governmenttogovernment)debtinadvancedeconomiesafterWorldWarI;and1978–2010, focusingonemergingmarketdebtcriseswithprivateexternalcreditors.Debtreliefwassubstantial inbotheras,averaging21%ofGDPinthe1930sand16%ofGDPinrecentdecades.Wethenanalyze theaftermathofdebtreliefandconductadifference-in-differencesanalysisaroundthesynchronous wardebtdefaultsof1934andtheBakerandBradyinitiativesofthe1980s/1990s.Theeconomic landscape of debtor countries improves significantly after debt relief operations, but only if these involve debt write-offs. Softer forms of debt relief, such as maturity extensions and interest rate reductions,arenotgenerallyfollowedbyhighereconomicgrowthorimprovedcreditratings.(JEL: E6,F3,N0,H6) 1. Introduction Should countries with a heavy debt burden and little prospect of repayment receive debtforgiveness?Thisisanoldquestionwithmodernresonance.1 Despitethepolicy relevance and controversy surrounding this issue, surprisingly little is known about the characteristics and the economic impact of sovereign debt relief. The literature TheeditorinchargeofthispaperwasFarbrizioZilibotti. Acknowledgments: We would like to thank Michael Bordo, Josefin Meyer, Maurice Obstfeld, Vincent Reinhart, and Ken Rogoff, the editor, two anonymous referees, and seminar participants at Columbia University, Harvard University, the International Monetary Fund, and the University of Melbourne for helpfulcommentsandsuggestions.MaximilianMandlandTakeshiTashiroprovidedexcellentresearch assistance. E-mail: [email protected](Reinhart); [email protected](Trebesch) 1. SeeAhamed(2010)foradiscussionoftherecurringinternationaldebatesondebtreliefduringthe 1920sand1930sandSachs(1990)andCline(1995)onthedebtoverhangdebateofthe1980sand1990s. Inthecurrentcontext,theIMFemphaticallycalledforfurtherdebtreliefforGreece(FinancialTimes,5 May2015),whileLarrySummersarguedforadeepdebtreductionforwar-tornUkraine(Summers2015). JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociation February2016 14(1):215–251 (cid:2)c 2016bytheEuropeanEconomicAssociation DOI:10.1111/jeea.12166 216 JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociation hasmostlyfocusedontheoccurrenceofdebtcrises,butnotontheirresolution.2 We contributetowardsfillingthisgapbystudyingtwo20thcenturyinstancesofdebtrelief that encompassed a substantial number of countries. These include the protracted debt overhangs in many advanced economies in the 1920s and 1930s and those of developingcountriesinthe1980sandearly1990s. Thepaperisorganizedaroundtwomaincontributions.Inthefirstpart,wedocument the process and magnitude of debt relief achieved through default and restructuring of external sovereign debt in 48 crisis spells. We focus, in particular, on the debt overhang that resulted from World War I, which was dominated by official external sovereign debt (i.e., debts owed to government creditors). This episode has been largelymissedinpreviousempiricalresearch,whichhasalmostexclusivelyfocusedon sovereigndefaultsonprivatecreditors.Itscomparativeobscurityisbafflinggiventhat intergovernmentalwardebtswereregardedasoneofthecentraleconomicchallenges atthetime(see,forexample,MoultonandPasvolsky1932).3Theofficialdebtoverhang ofthe1930sisalsoreminiscentofthesituationinperipheryEuropetoday,wheremuch ofthedebtsarenowalsointhehandsofofficialcreditors.4Moreover,itisnotablethat theepisodeendedwithafullcancellationofthewardebt. To analyze the 1930s defaults on official debts, we collect the details on official lending and debt relief events in a large network of war-related loans owed by 18 advanceddebtorcountriestothetwomaincreditorcountriesduringWorldWarIand the 1920s: the United States and the United Kingdom. We next compare this intra- war episode to the better-documented emerging market (EM) debt crises of recent decades.Theseweredominatedbydefaultsonprivatecreditors,notablyforeignbanks and bondholders. For the modern sample, we rely on earlier estimates of haircuts in middle-income emerging markets between 1978 and 2010. However, we are the first to compute various measures of debt relief for a representative group of crises and countries.5 Wealsodocumenttheprocessofcrisisresolutionindetail. 2. Recent work focusing on debt crisis resolution and renegotiation includes Benjamin and Wright (2009),PitchfordandWright(2012),AguiarandAmador(2013),Hatchondoetal.(2014),Kaminskyand Vega-Garcia(2014),andAsonumaandTrebesch(2016).Inaddition,asmallbodyofempiricalworkhas shedlightonspecificdebtreliefepisodes,suchasthe16Bradydebtreductiondealsofthe1990s(Cline 1989;Rieffel2003;ArslanalpandHenry2005),orthedebtforgivenessforhighlyindebtedpoorcountries (HIPCs)(DepretisChauvinandKraay2005,2007;Diasetal.2013).However,acomprehensivepicture ondebtrelieffromtheperspectiveofmiddle-andhigh-incomedebtorcountriesismissing.SeeTomzand Wright(2013)forasurvey. 3. EichengreenandPortes(1986,1990)andEichengreen(1992)studytheinterwardefaultsonexternal debtowedtoprivateforeignbondholders. 4. ArslanalpandTsuda(2014)documentthesharpmigrationofperipherysovereigndebtfromprivate topublichands.Theimportanceofofficialcreditorsisevenhigherifonetakesintoaccounttheholdings ofcentralbanks. 5. SturzeneggerandZettelmeyer(2006,2008),BenjaminandWright(2009),andCrucesandTrebesch (2013) estimate the scope of credit losses (“haircuts”) in past sovereign defaults from an investor’s perspective. Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer (2007) and Zettelmeyer et al. (2013) compute debt relief toGDPforsevenrecentcrisisspells. ReinhartandTrebesch SovereignDebtRelief 217 Our second contribution is to examine the economic performance of debtor countriesduringandaftersovereigndebtreliefoperations.Theoryisambiguousasto whetherdebtreliefisbeneficialornot.Krugman(1988),Sachs(1989),andObstfeld and Rogoff (1996) emphasize the potential welfare benefits of forgiving debt in a situationofdebtoverhang.Inthesemodels,bothcreditorsanddebtorscangainfroma partialdebtwrite-down,sinceanexcessivedebtstockandtheprospectoflargefuture debtrepaymentsactasataxondomesticinvestmentanddepressthepresentvalueof claimsheldbyinvestors.6Onthisbasis,areductioninthedebtlevelshouldbefollowed byaperiodofhighergrowth.7However,asubstantialrelatedliteraturesuggeststhata defaultorrestructuringcancausereputationaldamageandtriggersanctionsandoutput losses(e.g.,EatonandGersovitz1981;BulowandRogoff1989;ColeandKehoe1998; Aguiar and Gopinath 2006; Arellano 2008). In addition, debt relief may reduce the incentives to implement economic reforms (Easterly 2002), and debt renegotiations can give rise to collective action problems and inefficient delays that reduce output (Benjamin and Wright 2009; Pitchford and Wright 2012). Determining the overall (net)impactofdebtreliefis,intheend,anempiricalquestion.8 We study the aftermath of debt relief by tracing the evolution of real per capita GDP,sovereigncreditratings,debtservicingcosts,andthelevelofgovernmentdebt (externalandtotal)inaten-yearwindowaroundthereliefevent.9Wedescribestylized factsfortheepisodesandrundifference-in-differences(DiD)regressionsbycomparing theperformanceofcountriesthatreceiveddebtrelieftoacontrolgroupthatdidnot. There are (at least) two challenges in assessing the impacts of debt relief—both of which we address. First, the timing of debt relief may be endogenous, since countries often renegotiate their debt only after they start to recover (Kovrijnykh andSzentes2007;BenjaminandWright2009).Toaccountforthisconcern,webuild on the identification strategy of Arslanalp and Henry (2005) and focus on episodes of debt reduction that were centrally orchestrated and, thus, synchronously applied across debtor countries, irrespective of their individual economic circumstances. In theinterwaryears,twosuchepisodesemerge:theHooverMoratoriumof1931andthe generalizedwardebtdefaultsofthesummerof1934,whichoccurredsimultaneously inmorethan15debtorcountries.Inthemodernperiod,westressthetwodebtrelief initiativesthatwerespearheadedbytheUnitedStates:(i)theBakerplanof1986,which granteddebtreliefbyreducinginterestratesandbylengtheningthematurityofselected developingcountrydebtsand(ii)theBradyinitiativeof1990,whichsetthestagefor 6. InAguiaretal.(2009),debtreliefcanbebeneficialforgovernmentswithlargedebtstocks,althoughit isneveraParetoimprovementandnotnecessarilybeneficialforinvestors.InFernandezandMartin(2014), creditorsbenefitfromadebtrestructuringifitisdesignedcorrectly.InSunder-Plassmann(2015),high debtreliefisnotwelfareimproving,sinceitisassociatedwithhigherborrowingcostsandmorefrequent defaultsinequilibrium. 7. Thispredictionisbroadlyinlinewiththeliteraturelinkingdebtandgrowth,whichhasestablisheda negativecorrelationbetweenthelevelofpublicdebtandeconomicperformance.Thisliteratureissurveyed inPanizzaandPresbitero(2013). 8. Thereisanascentliteraturestudyingtheeffectsofdebtreliefforhouseholds(DobbieandSong2015). 9. SeeTomzandWright(2007)forarelatedhistoricalstudyonsovereigndefaultandoutput. 218 JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociation face value debt reduction. These four events are useful for identification purposes, sincedebtorcountriesdidnotchoosethetimingofreliefinanidiosyncraticmanner. Theapproachalleviates,butdoesnotnecessarilyeliminate,potentialendogeneity. Asecondchallengeinanalyzingthe“beforeandafter”ofdebtreliefisthepossible roleofomittedvariablesandconfoundingfactors.Toaddressthis,weincludecountry and time fixed effects, in line with the empirical strategy in Mian et al. (2014), which takes care of any time-invariant variation and common trends. This approach also accounts for global factors that might have influenced the dating choice of the (synchronous)debtreliefevents.Finally,weaccountfortime-varyingconfoundersby running a battery of robustness checks, in particular by adding controls for inflation, banking crises, currency crises, wars and conflicts, and major political shocks. The results are robust, but they should nevertheless be interpreted with caution as our controlsarenotexhaustive. Withthesecaveatsinmind,theevidenceisclearlyconsistentwiththenotionthat debtreliefhasbeneficialeconomiceffectsfordebtorcountries.Wecansummarizethe findingsasfollows. Sovereigndebtreliefaveraged21%ofGDPand43%ofexternalgovernmentdebt for advanced economies crises in the 1930s, and 16% of GDP and 36% of external debt in middle/high-income emerging markets from 1978 to 2010. These estimates represent a lower bound of the true magnitude of relief. The results for emerging marketsarequitesimilartothoseofadvancedeconomies,andreliefestimatesarenot clusteredinaparticularrange.Moregenerally,likeGourinchasandObstfeld(2012), wefindstrikingparallelsinthecrisispatternsofthetwocountrygroups. Regardingtheaftermathofdebtrelief,wefindthatpercapitaGDPincreases11% and20%duringthefiveyearsfollowingdecisivedebtrelief,foremergingmarketsand advancedeconomies,respectively.Decisiveherereferstothelastdebtreductionina sequence,meaningthedebtoperationthatallowedcountriestoexitthedefault.10 We also find a strong increase in average ratings for emerging markets. The Institutional Investorrating(IIR)indeximprovesby21%aftertwoyearsfollowingadecisivedebt relief operation, and 40% after five years. In contrast, for the interwar years, there is no notable improvement in ratings. Regarding debt levels, we observe a strong declinefollowingthecrisisexitinbothepisodes.Withinfiveyears,totalgovernment debt/GDP falls by 27 percentage points across emerging market episodes and by 22 percentagepointsintheinterwarsample.Also,thedebtserviceburden(amortizations plusinterestpayments)decreasesintheaftermathofdebtrelief,buttheaveragedecline islesspronouncedthaninthedebtstocks. Thesedescriptivefindingscallintoquestiontheoreticalmodelsthatassumecredit events cast a long shadow. The DiD regressions amplify this message. The patterns revealed by the data suggest that economic activity picks up following a debt relief 10. Inasignificantnumberofinstancesthereisonlyasinglerestructuring.However,therearenumerous default spells where the number of restructurings ranges from two to eight. In the interwar years, the “decisive”eventisthe1934summerdefault,whichwasfollowedbyacancellationofthewardebtsacross Europe. ReinhartandTrebesch SovereignDebtRelief 219 operation,withoneimportantcaveat:weonlyfindsignificantimprovementsingrowth and ratings if the deal involves face value debt reductions. Rescheduling operations with maturity extensions and interest reductions were not followed by a significant improvementineconomicgrowth,oncewecontrolfortimeandcountryfixedeffects andconductacounterfactualanalysis.Theregressionresultsalsopointtoasignificant declineindebtstockstoGDPafterdecisivedebtrelief,buttheresultsarelessrobust than with regard to growth and ratings. More surprisingly, we find no significant correlation of debt relief and subsequent debt servicing burdens. The decline we observeintherawdataseemstobeduetoacommontrendinborrowingcosts. Thepaperproceedsasfollows.InSection2,wesummarizethecrisisanddebtrelief experiencesofadvancedeconomiesandemergingmarketsthatarethemainfocusof thepaper.InSection3,westudytheaftermathofdebtrelief,byshowingstylizedfacts across all event spells, while in Section 4 we present the methodology and results of ourDiDanalysis.InSection5,weconcludeanddiscussavenuesforfutureresearch. 2. Two Eras of Default and Relief: World War I Debts and Emerging Market Crises In this section, we introduce the restructuring and default episodes that are the centerpiece of our study and compute the magnitudes of debt relief for each case. In both eras, we focus on external debt, meaning debt that is predominantly (but not exclusively) issued under foreign law, denominated in a foreign currency, and held by non-residents. Our aim is to quantify the magnitude of external debt relief oftheentiredebtcrisisspellineachcountry,ratherthanjustindividualrestructuring agreements. 2.1. TheWorldWarIDebtOverhanganditsResolution Forthe1920sand1930s,weconfineourattentiontoofficialWorldWarIdebt,where boththeborrowerandthelendersweresovereigngovernments.Wardebtissomewhat of a misnomer, since for most borrowers with the exception of the United Kingdom, muchoftheofficialdebtwascontractedafterthewarhadendedandhadthecharacter of reconstruction and stabilization loans.11 We focus, in particular, on official debts owedtothetwomaincreditorsoftheinterwarperiod:theUnitedStates,whichwasthe largest creditor and did not have outstanding debts to any other sovereign connected with the war or its aftermath, and the United Kingdom, which also had lent large amounts to other European countries and owed significant amounts to the United States(seeMoultonandPasvolsky1932,foranoverview). Whileourmainfocusisonthewardebtreliefeventsoftheearlyandmid-1930s, and, in particular, the 1934 summer defaults and the subsequent debt cancellations, 11. SeeBailey(1950),Lloyd(1934),andUnitedStatesTreasury(1920,1933). 220 JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociation we document how the payment irregularities on the war debt began much earlier. TableA.1inOnlineAppendixApresentsadetailedcountry-by-countrychronologyof officialcrediteventsandrelatedmilestones.Itisevidentfromthesecountrytimelines that the debt overhang episode was very protracted, spanning more than a decade.12 Thefirstdefaultsonthewardebtoccurredintheearly1920sandthesewerequickly followedbyaseriesofreschedulingagreementswiththeUnitedStatesandtheUnited Kingdom. In chronological order, the United States rescheduled its war debt with Finland (May1923),GreatBritain(June1923),Hungary(April1924),Lithuania(September 1924), Poland (November 1924), Belgium (August 1925), Latvia (September 1925), Czechoslovakia (October 1925), Estonia (October 1925), Italy (November 1925), Romania (December 1925), France (April 1926), Yugolsavia (May 1926), Greece (May 1929), and Austria (May 1930). Similarly, the United Kingdom arranged debt rescheduling settlements with Belgium (December 1925), Romania (1925), Italy (January1926),France(July1926),Portugal(December1926),Greece(April1927), andYugolsavia(August1927). The terms of these agreements were favorable for debtor countries, since the projected repayment periods were long, often exceeding 50 years, so that principal would only extinguish in the mid-1980s. The (nominal) interest rates charged were typicallyatorbelow3.5%ofprincipaloutstanding.Thedetailedtermsandrepayment streamsofeachagreementweremainlygatheredfromtheoriginaldocumentsreprinted in the authoritative study by Moulton and Pasvolsky (1932) and corroborated by documentsfromtheUSTreasury(seeTableA.2intheOnlineAppendixfordetails). In effect, the concessionary terms on the official war debt agreed in the crisis years of the 1920s closely resemble the rescheduling terms of the Greek official debt in 2010. The restructured Greek debt to the European official institutions also features repaymentperiodsabove30yearsandinterestratesaslowas2.5%(seeZettelmeyer etal.2013). After the rescheduling agreements of the mid- and end-1920s, most countries continued to honor their scheduled interest and principal payments, at least partially. ThisstateofaffairscametoanendwiththemoratoriumannouncedbyUSPresident Hooveron20June1931,andapprovedby15creditoranddebtornationson6July1931. Initially,Hoover’splanwastograntasuspensionofinterestandprincipalpaymentson allinter-alliedwardebtsaswellasGermany’sreparationspaymentsforoneyear,i.e. untillate1932.13However,attheendofthistemporarymoratoriumin1932,scheduled paymentsdidnotresumeinuniformandregularfashion.WhiletheUnitedKingdom, 12. Thesameistrueforthedebtoverhangonnon–WorldWarIpublicandprivatedebts,whichstretched intothepost–WorldWarIIera.Forexample,AustriaandGermanywereindefaultthrough1952;Italy wasindefault1940–1945;GreeceandHungaryhadevenlongerstintsindefaultstatusthrough1964and 1967,respectively.SeeReinhartandRogoff(2009). 13. Forbrevity,wedonotdelveintothecomplexissueoftheGermanreparationdebts,whichhavebeen studiedatlengthelsewhere.ThesedebtsoriginatedintheTreatyofVersaillesin1919,wererestructured undertheDawesPlanin1924,restructuredagainundertheYoungPlanin1929,andultimatelydefaulted onduring1932–1934(fordetailssee,e.g.,Ritschl2012). ReinhartandTrebesch SovereignDebtRelief 221 Italy, Czechoslovakia, Finland, Greece, Latvia, Lithuania, Romania, and Yugoslavia made the scheduled 15 December payment on war debt, France, Belgium, Poland, Estonia and Hungary did not.14 In addition, the European countries suspended their wardebtpaymentstotheUnitedKingdomaftertheLausannewardebtconferenceof July1932,asdidAustraliaandNewZealand. TherepaymentirregularitiescametoaheadinJune1934,withtheannouncementof fullsuspensionofpayments.AlldebtorcountriesexceptFinland,whichfullyrepaid, suspended all payments on the war debt owed to the United States and the United Kingdom, and at various points in time removed this debt from their books.15 The 1934defaultscanthusbeinterpretedasadecisive“crisisexit”eventofthisperiod,in the sense that it was understood that those debts would not be repaid anytime in the foreseeablefuture.Inretrospect,thesummerdefaultsof1934thusbroughttoaclose thewardebtoverhangepisodeofthe1920sand1930s,againstthestrongopposition oftheUnitedStates.16 What was the scope of debt relief achieved through the 1934 defaults and debt cancellations?Table1lists18countriesthat,asof1934,oweddebttotheUSandthe UK governments from World War I and its aftermath (Australia, New Zealand, and Portugal only owed debt to the United Kingdom). Finland, the only country to fully honoritswardebtobligationstotheUnitedStates,willdropoutfromthedebtrelief list.Toencompasstherangeof“creditevents”intheadvancedeconomiesatthattime, we add to this list the default spell of Germany (which applied to all external debts, affecting both private and public creditors) and the United States’ 1934 haircut that resultedfromtheabrogationofthegoldclause,whichmostlyaffecteddomesticprivate creditors(TableA.3inOnlineAppendixAprovidesthedetailsofthisepisode).This bringsthetotalnumberof1930sepisodesto19.17 The first column of Table 1 gives the amount of debt outstanding plus interest arrearsatthetimeofthegeneralizeddefaultinJune1934.Theseamountsowedtothe United States and the United Kingdom vary somewhat across sources. For instance, the unpaid obligations that are recorded in the United Nations 1948 publication, Public Debt, 1914–1946, and in Baily (1950, p. 701) are not strictly the same as those shown in Table 1, which are taken from the annual financial reports by the US TreasuryDepartmentandfromtheMoody’sManualsonForeignSecurities(although 14. LeagueofNations,WorldEconomicSurvey1932/1933(p.332). 15. Somecountriesformallycanceledtheirdebtonlyyearsafter1934.Forexample,Franceremoved theUKandUSwardebtfromitsbooksin1938.Others,suchasBelgiumandtheUnitedKingdom,kept thewardebtintheirofficialdebtfiguresuntiltheendofWorldWarII.Nevertheless,in1934,itbecame generallyrecognizedthatthewardebtswouldnotbeservicedforyearstocome. 16. InreactiontotheEuropeanpaymentsuspensions,theUSCongressenactedtheJohnsonDebtDefault Actof1934,whichbannedUScitizensfromgrantingloanstocountriesthathaddefaultedontheirwar debttotheUnitedStates.Moreover,theUSTreasurystillliststheunpaid1934wardebtobligationsinits financialaccountstoday. 17. Inthevariousempiricalexercisesthatfollow,thesecountriesareincorporatedtotheextentthatthe datapermit.Thecoreepisodeswiththemostcompleteprofileare:Austria,Belgium,France,Germany, Greece,Italy,andtheUnitedKingdom. 222 JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociation bt e d c asbli ngdom. Debtreliefexternalpu(6) 91.9––11.3–48.136.1–44.05.395.8–97.8–0.614.810.066.6 Ki of d % e StatesandtheUnit GDP(in%) Presentvalue(lowerbound)(5) 19.525.111.52.7––––21.41.6–0.2–––––– otheUnited Debtreliefto acevalueperbound)(4) 24.552.236.44.1––––43.41.7–0.2–––6.210.510.3 d/GDP(US)17.6d/GDP(UK)28.6 t Fp e e d u w w e ( O O w o eandpostwardebt otaltoUSandUK DebtoutstandingnUS$(w/arrears)(3) 4,714,345,2357,342,122,9723,133,049,808478,061,010243,356,167165,409,455208,197,822204,719,173132,174,14823,822,49219,511,4298,711,99613,658,4036,650,0802,086,096337,777,250110,966,57999,459,373 m T i warti gs) unpaidallied OwedtoUK ebtoutstandinUS$(w/arrear(2) –3,361,387,8611,123,494,77264,631,01017,107,8600146,572,822140,836,16799,384,80501,432,04506,222,619–0337,777,250110,966,57999,459,373 USGDP6,800,000,000UKGDP9,264,825,087 ults: Din 6 1 defa gs) US: UK: The1934summer OwedtoUS DebtoutstandininUS$(w/arrear(1) 4,714,345,2353,980,735,1122,009,555,036413,430,000226,248,308165,409,45561,625,00063,883,00732,789,34423,822,49218,079,3838,711,9967,435,7846,650,0802,086,096000 Totalowedtothe11,734,806,327Totalowedtothe5,509,273,162 dixTableA.2. 1.LE aid) ms: Appen TAB UnitedKingdomFranceItalyBelgiumPolandCzechoslovakiaYugoslaviaRomaniaGreeceAustriaEstoniaFinland(fullyrepLatviaLithuaniaHungaryAustraliaNewZealandPortugal Memorandumite Source:SeeOnline ReinhartandTrebesch SovereignDebtRelief 223 allnumbersarequiteclose).Discrepanciesmayalsoarisefromtheexchangerateused toconvertthedebtintolocalcurrency,toconstructameasureofdebtreliefrelativeto GDP. Our point estimates of debt relief (column (4)) are based on the nominal GDP and exchange rates shown in Online Appendix Table A.2, using 1934 values, since thatyearuniformlydatesthe“dejure”debtreliefeventtowardstheUnitedStatesand theUnitedKingdom.The1934dateisalsoappropriateforthedomesticdebtdefault of the United States case, since the abrogation of the gold clause came into force instantly. Thesenumbersareaconservativeestimateofthetruescopeofthewardebtrelief ofthe1930sfortwomainreasons.First,whenindoubtaboutthebestsourceondebt amounts, exchange rates, or GDP, we have always opted for the values that would yieldthemoreconservativeestimatesofdebtrelief.Second,andmoreimportantly,the defaultsanddebtwrite-downsof1934werenotlimitedtodebtowedtheUnitedStates andtheUnitedKingdom(whicharetheonlyoneswequantifyhere).Largeamounts ofgovernmentaldebtwerealsoowedtoFrance,Italy,andBelgiumandtheseamounts arenotpartofourcalculations.18 Methodologically, our preferred debt relief estimate for 1934 is simply the outstandingfacevalueofwardebtsasashareofGDP,becausetheentiredebtstockwas writtenoffandnonewdebtwasissued.Thisstandsincontrasttoalmostallemerging marketdebtrestructurings,whichinvolvedanexchangeofoldloansorbondsagainst newones.Asanalternative,however,wealsocomputeddebtreliefestimatesinpresent value, based on the terms of the debt rescheduling agreements vis-a`-vis the United Kingdom and the United States of the 1920s.19 To discount future payments in this exercise, we use a 5% annual rate, which follows the approach chosen in Moulton andPasvolsky(1932).Figure1showstheresultsandcomparesthemtoourbaseline numbers, focusing on the seven largest debtor countries: Austria, Belgium, France, Greece, Italy, Portugal, and the United Kingdom. Unsurprisingly, due to the long remaining maturity of the rescheduled war debts, the present value relief estimates areoftenconsiderablybelowthefacevalueestimates,especiallyforFranceandItaly. Nevertheless, the magnitudes of debt relief are large with either method, exceeding 10% of GDP even in present value terms in most cases. Moreover, it should be kept in mind that these war loans would have long fallen due before 1934 had this debt notbeenrescheduledunderverygeneroustermsinthe1920s.Thepresentvaluerelief estimatesfor1934arethereforeartificiallysmall,whilethefacevaluedebtreduction amounts are a more appropriate assessment of the true scope of relief during this period. 18. Belgium,France,andItalywereeachowedtotalwardebtsofmorethan$1bn1933USdollars(see MoultonandPasvolsky1932). 19. WecouldnotgatherdetailsontheagreementsofAustraliaandNewZealand,andPortugalontheir debtowedtotheUnitedKingdom.Wearethereforenotabletocomputepresentvaluedebtreliefestimates forthesecases. 224 JournaloftheEuropeanEconomicAssociation FIGURE 1. Debt relief of major European countries as a share of debtor country GDP in 1934. FiguresareshownfordebtowedtotheUnitedStatesandtotheUnitedKingdomseparately.The sourcesarethesameasinTable1.Thepresentvalueestimatesuseanannualdiscountrateof5%and thecontractualdebtservicestreamsoftheoriginalagreementsasinMoultonandPasvolsky(1932). 2.2. ExternalSovereignDebtCrisesinEmergingMarketssince1978 Wenowturntoasecondsignificanteraofsovereigndebtreliefofthepast100years: the defaults and restructurings of emerging market debts vis-a`-vis private creditors (foreignbanksorbondholders).Ouranalysisisrestrictedtothemiddle-to-highincome emergingmarkets.WerelyontheCrucesandTrebesch(2013)database,whichprovides detailedinformationonthenear-universeofsovereigndebtrestructuringswithforeign banksandbondholdersover1978–2010,includingdataontheamountofdebtaffected aswellasestimatesonthesizeofcreditorlosses(haircuts)agreeduponineachdeal. Their approach to estimate haircuts closely follows Sturzenegger and Zettelmeyer (2006,2007,2008),whoestimateinvestorlossesforeightemergingmarketcrises. Theinformationonhaircutsinindividualdebtrestructuringsallowsustocompute acumulativehaircutmeasurefortheentiredefaultspell,thussummarizingtheoutcome

Description:
We would like to thank Michael Bordo, Josefin Meyer, Maurice Obstfeld, Vincent . More generally, like Gourinchas and Obstfeld (2012), . Treasury Department and from the Moody's Manuals on Foreign Securities (although. 14.
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.