This PDF is a selection from a published volume from the National Bureau of Economic Research Volume Title: Innovation Policy and the Economy, Volume 2 Volume Author/Editor: Adam B. Jaffe, Josh Lerner and Scott Stern, editors Volume Publisher: MIT Press Volume ISBN: 0-262-60045-5 Volume URL: http://www.nber.org/books/jaff02-1 Conference Date: April 17, 2001 Publication Date: January 2002 Title: Some Economic Aspects of Antitrust Analysis in Dynamically Competitive Industries Author: David S. Evans, Richard Schmalensee URL: http://www.nber.org/chapters/c10784 1 of Antitrust Analysis in Some Economic Aspects Dynamically Competitive Industries David S. Evans, National EconomicResearch Associates Richard Schmalensee, National Bureau ofEconomic Research, MIT Sloan School of Management Executive Summary Competition in many important industries centers on investment in intellec- Schumpeterian competition for the tual property. Firms engage in dynamic, to produce drastic innova- market, through sequential winner-take-all races price/output competition in the market. Sound tions, rather than through static antitrust economic analysis of such industriesrequires explicit consideration of dynamic competition. Most leading firmsin these dynamically competitive in- market power, for instance, but ignoring dustries have considerable short-nm their vulnerability to drastic innovation may yield misleading conclusions. Similarly, conventional tests for predation cannot discriminate between prac- tices that increase and those that decrease consumerwelfare in winner-take-all competitive industries often in- industries. Finally, innovation in dynamically volves enhancing feature sets; there is no sound economic basis for treating such enhancements as per se ifiegal ties. I. Introduction of antitrust in industries that are un- This paper is about the economics dergoing rapid technological change and in which competition centers intellectual property In many of these industries, on investment in for the marketusually through firms engage in dynamic competition research-and-development (R&D) competition to develop the "killer" market leadership and thus product, service, or feature that will confer diminish or eliminate actual or potential rivals. Static price/output competition on the margin in the market isless important. Heavy investment in the creation of intellectual property typically leading to substantial seller con- results in significant scale economies, nevertheless be contestable as a centration.' Market leadership may innovations by rivals. In the pop- result of the constant threat of drastic ular press, these industries are sometimes referred to as new-economy or 2 Evans and Schmalensee high-technology. Many have aspects that economists would call Schumpeterian, after the economist who described the process of "cre- ative destruction" whereby innovation destroys oldindustries and cre- ates new ones.2 In contrast, in old-economy industries, competition takes place primarily through traditional price/output competition on the margin in the market and through incremental innovation, not through efforts to create drasticmarket-destroying_mnnovatjons.3 The federal antitrust enforcement agencies have viewed new- economy industries as particularly susceptible to breakdownsin com- petition and thus deserving of particularly close antitrust scrutiny.4 We argue that this broad-brush approach is unlikely to enhanceconsumer welfare. We do not contend that dynamically competitive industries should be immune to careful antitrust scrutiny, nor that the basic prin- ciples of antitrust should be modified in these sectors. Fixing prices or preventing competitors from distributing their productswill generally harm consumers even if dynamic competition is vigorous. Nonethe- less, the application of antitrust principles should take account of the important ways new-economy industries differ from traditional ones. In recent decades, careful use of economic analysis has generally aligned antitrust policy more closely with the interests of consumers. To continue this trend, antitrust policy must reflect the features of dy- namically competitive industries (manynew-economy industries) that differentiate them from statically competitive industries (most old- economy industries). Section II briefly documents the growing importance of new- economy industries, identifies some important industries in which competition is mainly dynamic, and discusses keyeconomic aspects of new-economy industries. Section III considers how the central features of new-economy industries affect the market definition and market power analysis that have become central to the practice of antitrust economics. Section IV examines how these economic characteristics af- fect the analysis of predation claimscharges that a business has acted to exclude or eliminate rivals to acquire or maintain a monopoly. Sec- tion V then examines the antitrust economics of tyingrequiring cus- tomers to purchase one product as a condition of purchasing anotherin new-economy industries. Finally, Section VI summarizes lessons for antitrust policy in thenew economy. Although our analysis applies generally, we draw our examples in Sections Ill-V mainly from United States v. Microsoft Corp., the leadingantitrust case to date involv- ing a new-economy industry.5 Some Economic Aspects of Antitrust Analysis 3 II. New-Economy Industries What's New? The defining feature of new-economy industries is a competitive pro- cess dominated by efforts to createintellectual property through R&D, which often results in rapid and disruptive technological change. Par- ticularly at the height of the boom in "dot-corn" stock prices, many au- thors have exaggerated the importance of such industries and of intellectual property more generally. Nonetheless, the U.S. economy has undergone an important transformation in the last 30 years that has resulted in much "creative destruction" and increased investment in innovation.6 Table 1.1 compares the U.S. companies with the20 larg- est market capitalizations at the end of 1970, 1985, and 2000. Only five companies from the 1970 and 1985 lists (IBM, General Electric, BP Amoco, Exxon Mobil, and Coca-Cola) made the top 20 in 2000; more than half of the companies on the 2000 list did not even exist in1970, in- cluding Microsoft, Cisco Systems, Oracle, and EMC.7 The top three firms in 1970 (IBM, AT&T, and General Motors) were still in the top five in 1985 but had been substantially displaced by 2000. AT&T and Gen- IBMan "old" eral Motors fell out of the top 20 altogether, while new-economy company that barely survived the drastic innovations that sharply reduced the demand for its mainframe computersfell to 18th place. Many of the new firms on the list in 2000 are part ofwhat has come to be called the new economy: companies whose fortunes are tied to suc- cess in the creation of intellectual propertyand are highly vulnerable to successful innovation by others. The firms listed in 1970 and 1985 but not in 2000 are what have come to be called theold-economy companies: firms whose fortunes are tied to the use of mature technologies in which drastic innovation is rare, such as food manufacturing and pe- troleum production. For example, 1999 R&D expenditures averaged 3.6% of sales for still-existing companies that had been on the top-20 list for 1970 and 3.0% for those on the 1985 list, while the average ratio was 6.8% for the companies on the top-20 list for 2000.8 We see the increased importance of the creation of intellectual prop- erty in other ways. Company-funded R&D as a percentageof GDP was generally below 1.0% from 1958 to 1979; it was generally above 1.4% in the 1990s.9 In 1950 not one of the 100 highest valued firms spent more than 5% of revenues on R&D, and in 1970 only nine of the top 100 4. alue n all v o Market $475.0$302.2$290.2$275.0$256.4$237.3$230.6$228.2$219.7$215.1$202.4$202.3$201.9$162.2 $161.6$155.5$151.1$150.8$146.1$145.5 y traded cl bli p u u p 2000 2000 Company General Electric Co.Exxon Mobil Corp.Pfizer Inc.Cisco Systems Inc.Citigroup Inc.Wal-Mart StoresMicrosoft Corp.American International GroVodafone Group.Merck & Co.Nokia Corp.Intel Corp.GlaxoSmithKlineOracle Corp. SBC Communications Inc.BP Amoco.Coca-Cola Co.IBM Corp.Johnson & JohnsonEMC Corp. s with outstanding securities d m ons of dollars)as of December 31, 1970, 1985, an 1985 CompanyMarket value IBM Corp.$95.7Exxon Corp.$40.3General Electric Co.$33.2AT&T Corp.$26.7General Motors Corp.$22.3Royal Dutch Pet.$16.9British Telecom$16.8Du Pont de Numours$16.3Toyota Motor Corp.$16.2Amoco Corp.$16.0Bellsouth Corp.$15.0Sears Roebuck & Co.$14.2Chevron Corp.$13.0Mobil Corp$12.4 American Express$11.8Procter & Gamble Co.$11.7Standard Oil Co.$11.7Matsushita Electric$11.5Atlantic Richfield Co.$11.5Eastman Kodak Co.$11.4 et collects financial data fromthe 10-Qs of the fir n billi value FactS Table 1.1Top 20 companies ranked by market value (i 1970 RankCompanyMarket IIBMCorp.$36.42AT&T Corp.$26.83General Motors Corp.$23.04Exxon Corp.$16.45Eastman Kodak Co.$12.2Sears Roebuck & Co.6$11.87Texaco Inc.$9.58General Electric Co.$8.5Xerox Corp.9$6.8Gulf Corp.10$6.7Du Pont de Nemours11$6.312Ford Motor Co.$6.1Royal Dutch Pet.13$6.014Mobil Corp.$5.815Minnesota Mining &Mfg Co.$5.616Avon Products$5.117Coca-Cola Co.$5.018Procter & Gamble Co.$4.7Chevron Corp.19$4.620iTT Industries$3.6 Source: FactSet Research Systems, Inc. (2001). U.S. markets. Some Economic Aspects of Antitrust Analysis 5 exceeded this level. But in 1999, 38 of the 100 highest valued firms spent at least 5% of revenue on R&D, with 22 firms spending more than 10%. 10 The new economy is almost synonymous with the information- technology industries. Of course, these industries, broadly defined, have been around for a long time. The Bell System, formed in the late nineteenth century was a network industry created by a revolutionary invention and based on the transmission of information. Mainframe computers became a big business in the 1950s and wereconsidered a mature industry by the late 1970s. But rapid increases in microproces- sor speeds, decreases in the cost ofproviding bandwidth, and the de- velopment of the Internet have, in the last 25 years, fostered the creation of many industries that have Schumpeterian dimensions. These include computer software (e.g., operating systems, applica- tions, and utilities), computer hardware (e.g., microprocessors, per- sonal computers, and servers), and Internet-based businesses (e.g., portals, business-to-business exchanges, and content providers).1' There are other industries, however, that have been born or revolu- tionized in the last quarter century and in which dynamic competition is fundamental. These include communications networks (routers and related equipment), mobile telephony, and biotechnology. A much older industry pharmaceuticals, has some Schumpeterian characteris- tics as well.12 Table 1.2 lists the leading industrial firms whose expendi- tures on R&D accounted for more than 10% of their sales in 1997.' More than one-quarter of these R&D-intensive companies were among the 50 highest-valued companies at the end of 2000.14 Most of these would be characterized as high-technology or new-economy compa- nies and have their fortunes tied to their success at innovation. Key Characteristics Industries in which dynamic competition for the market is important have several of the following characteristics. Each characteristic reflects a deviation from the textbook modelof static price/output competition and has important implications for antitrust analysis. Firms in new-economy in- Low Marginal Costs and High Fixed Costs dustries tend to have high fixed costs and low marginal production costs. They often must invest a great deal to develop their products, either because they must make substantial investments in R&D, or Industry categoly PharmaceuticalsPharmaceuticalsPrepackaged softwarePharmaceuticalsElectronic componentsElectronic componentsPharmaceuticalsElectronic componentsPrepackaged softwarePharmaceuticalsTelephone equipmentElectronic componentsMedical instrumentsPharmaceuticalsMachineryComputer networkingequipmentElectronic componentsComputer networkingequipmentIndustrial chemicalsPharmaceuticals %) y ( sit n e nt D I R& 42.528.128.126.319.919.018.117.816.916.216.015.815.715.413.913.2 13.112.9 12.512.5 n) o milli $ Sales ( 9481,0561,0072,4012,3562,5376,7101,29011,3588,5181,5751,2431,32812,5044,0741,377 3,6632,093 7,5146,778 n) o milli $ s ( e ur dit n e p x ales R&D E 403.3296.5282.7630.8467.9482.01,217.0229.11,925.01,382.0252.1196.1208.31,928.0567.6181.6 479.1269.8 939.0847.0 s o e t Table 1.21997 R&D expenditures relativ Company Genentech Inc.Chiron Corp.Novell Inc.Amgen Inc.Advanced Micro DevicesNational Semiconductor Corp.Pharmacia & Upjohn IncLSI Logic Corp.Microsoft Corp.Lilly (ELI) & Co.DSC Communications Corp.Analog DevicesGuidant Corp.Pfizer Inc.Applied Materials Inc.Cabletron Systems Silicon Graphics Inc.Bay Networks Inc. Monsanto Co.Schering-Plough Industry category CommunicationsequipmentTelephone equipmentMedical instrumentsCommunicationsequipmentElectronic components PharmaceuticalsPharmaceuticalsComputer networkingequipmentComputer networkingequipmentMedical instrumentsPrepackaged software %) y ( CO. ensit od, R&D Int 11.811.811.4 11.311.0 11.011.0 10.8 10.710.5 10.1 Englewo at, st u p n) m o o milli s C $ or' Sales ( 1,76426,3602,605 2,0969,750 14,19611,883 6,440 5,4201,8727,144 & Pod ar d n a St m n) o millio wn fr ditures ($ ata are dra n D R&D expe 207.83,100.6297.2 235.91,075.0 1,558.01,302.4 698.2 581.6196.7719.1 Table 3). 9, 9 9 1 n ( o s Table 1.2 (continued): Company General Instrument Corp.Lucent Technologies Inc.Medtronic Inc. Qualcomm Inc.Texas Instruments Inc.American Home ProductsCorp.Abbott Laboratories Cisco Systems Inc. 3COM Corp.Boston Scientific Corp.Oracle Corp. Source: Shepherd and Pay 8 Evans and Schmalensee because they must invest in a physicalor virtual network to create and deliver the product. But once they make this initial investment, it is cheap to create additional units. It does not cost much to produce an- other copy of, say, the Adobe Acrobat Reader; nor, once a fabrication facifity has been set up, to produce another Intel Pentiummicroproces- sor. That is, production in new-economy industries exhibits increasing returns.'5 For example, in 1998 materialexpenses accounted for 52% of revenues in manufacturing industries overall,'6 while innew-economy industries material expenses averaged less than 30% of revenues (for example, software (19%),' pharmaceuticals (29%),18 and semiconduc- tor manufacturing (19%)'). Labor and Human Capital Intensity Many new-economy industries make more intensive use of labor and less intensive use of tangible cap- ital than old-economy industries. That is because the fixed costs in- curred by high-technology firms are mainly for the labor used to develop their products, by developing intellectualproperty (or intangi- ble capital). Thus, even if the subsequent production process is fairly capital-intensive, as in chip manufacturing for instance, new-economy industries are generally relatively labor-intensive overall. Labor costs are 15% of revenue in manufacturing industries overall as compared to 22% in electromedical equipment, 30% in software publishing, and 48% in computer programming services.20 Another important reason why labor compensation accounts for a high fraction of the costs in high-technology industriesis that they tend to have more highly educated workforces than old-economy indus- tries; accordingly they tend to use more human capital.2' For example, the median education level of workers in the software industry is 15 years, while workers in all manufacturing have a median education level of 12 years. Moreover, 15.6% of workers in the software industry have a graduate degree, as compared to 4.6% in all manufacturing.22 Because intellectual property is the critical asset innew-economy in- dustries, entry costs can be quite low, and the risk that a dangerous ri- val will emerge seemingly from nowhere can be quite high. For example, the Linux operating system, initially written by a graduate student as a hobby and further developed by volunteers working through the open-source movement on the Internet, has captured a 24.4% share of new installations on servers.23 Another open-source product, Apache, has captured a 60% share of installations on Web servers.24 Some Economic Aspects of Antitrust Analysis 9 Network and System Effects Many high-technology industries,particu- larly those based on computer software, the Internet, or telecommuni- cations generally, have network effects. An industry is often described as a network industry if the value of the network to any one consumer depends importantly, either directly or indirectly, on the number of other consumers on the network.25 Such an industry may or may not involve an actual physical network. Commonly citedexamples of net- work industries include telephones, fax machines, credit card systems, and e-mail. Many of these involve a physical network to link consum- ers,26 but the physical network is not really what makes these network industries in an economic sense. Some other network industries are clearly virtual (not physical) networks, in which consumers benefit in- directly from the number of users of the network. In all cases, the use of common standards plays a critical role in linking network users. Net- work effects are a source of scale economiesin consumption rather than productionand thus tend to produce markets with at most a small number of clear leaders, making it difficult forfirms with small shares to survive unless they produce significantinnovation. Many of the high-technology industries that haveemerged in the last twenty years have significant network effects. Wintel computers (i.e., computers in which Windows software runs on Intel-compatible hard- ware) are more valuable to each consumer the more other consumers use this standard. Software developers will invest more in writing ap- plications for this standard, making it more likely that consumers will have the applications they desire. Also, use of a common standard makes it easier for consumers to exchange input and outputfiles (such as data sets, text documents, or spreadsheets) with each other. Many Internet-based businesses also have significant network ef- fects. That is perhaps most clearly true for messagingservices and chat rooms, the value of which directly increases with the number of people on the same network. It isalso true for market-making services such as eBay, where buyers benefit from there being more sellers, and sellers benefit from there being more buyers. Firms that are not leaders in network industries generally have little hope of reaching that status unless they come up with amajor innova- tionone that can defeat the natural advantage that network effects bestow on the industry leaders. Incremental innovation(making slight improvements in the leaders' products) will not enable a small firm to overtake a leader that enjoys the benefits of network economies. Simi- larly, the possibility of being displaced by a major innovation will
Description: