ebook img

Residual profit allocation by income PDF

106 Pages·2017·0.91 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Residual profit allocation by income

Residual profit allocation by income A paper of the Oxford International Tax Group chaired by Michael P. Devereux WP 19/01 March 2019 Michael P. Devereux, Alan J.Auerbach, Paul Oosterhuis, Wolfgang Schön and John Vella Working paper | 2019 This working paper is authorisedor co-authored by Saïd Business School faculty. The paper is circulated for discussion purposes only, contents should be considered preliminary and are not to be quoted or reproduced without the author’s permission. RESIDUAL PROFIT ALLOCATION BY INCOME A paper of the Oxford International Tax Group, chaired by Michael P. Devereux Michael P. Devereux, Alan J. Auerbach, Paul Oosterhuis, Wolfgang Schön and John Vella March 2019 1 CONTENTS EXECUTIVESUMMARY 3 I. INTRODUCTION 6 II. THEGRADUALMOVETOWARDSPROFITSPLITS 13 III. THERPA-IINOUTLINE 19 IV. COMPARINGTHERPA-IWITHOTHERAPPROACHES 46 V. EVALUATINGTHERPA-I 59 VI. IMPLEMENTATION 82 VII. CONCLUSION 91 APPENDIX 93 REFERENCES 95 2 EXECUTIVE SUMMARY This paper is a draft chapter of a forthcoming book on the taxation of international businessprofitbytheauthorsofthispaper,tobepublishedbyOxfordUniversityPress. The group has been meeting regularly for five years, to identify and discuss the key problemsoftheexistinginternationaltaxsystem,andtodeveloppotentialoptionsfor reform.Thebookwillstudytwoproposalsforreformindepth.Oneisthedestination- basedcashflowtax–adraftchapteronthisproposalhasalreadybeenreleased.1The secondproposal–foraformofresidualprofitallocation-ispresentedhere. Thispaperislargelyself-standingandcanbereadwithoutnecessarilyreadingtherest ofthebook,althoughitdoesrefer inplacestoargumentssetout in otherdraftchap- ters.Wehopetomaketheseotherchaptersavailableshortly.Weinvitecommentson the contents of the two draft chapters which have been made available; they can be madetothechairofthegroup,MichaelDevereux,2ortoanyofthegroupmembers. WerefertotheproposalsetoutinthispaperasaResidualProfitAllocationbyIncome, orRPA-I.Itisoneofafamilyofschemesbasedonseparatingthetotalprofitofamul- tinational enterprise (MNE) into two parts – the “routine” profit and the “residual” profit.Thisdistinctionisfamiliarfromtheexistingsysteminthecontextofprofitsplits. Theproposalheregoesconsiderablyfurtherthantheexistingsystem;nevertheless,it isbased on existingfeaturesandconcepts.Assuch,althoughthe RPA-Iwouldinvolve substantial departures from the existing system, we believe that the transition to it couldbeachievedbroadlywithinthecontextoftheexistingsystem. The RPA-I allocates the right to tax routine profit to the country where functions and activitiestakeplace.Itallocatestherighttotaxresidualprofittothemarket,ordesti- nation,countrywheresalesaremadetothirdparties. We argue that the RPA-I has attractive properties – while it is far from perfect, it matches well the criteria by which we aim to evaluate proposals for tax reform: eco- nomic efficiency, fairness, robustness to avoidance, ease of implementation, and in- centive compatibility. The RPA-I’s superior performance under these criteria relative to the existing system stems primarily from allocating taxing rights for residual profit 1AlanJ. Auerbach,MichaelP.Devereux,MichaelJ.KeenandJohnVella(2017)“Destination-basedcash flowtaxation”,OxfordUniversityCentreforBusinessTaxationWorkingPaper17/01. [email protected] 3 to the destination country. The relative immobility of the third-party purchaser of goods and services sold by the company – especially in the case of individuals, rather thanbusinesses–impliesthatthelocationofthetaxationofresidualprofitisnoteasily manipulated. This is true of manipulation by shifting real economic activity – which creates economic distortions and hence inefficiencies – and also of the manipulation of the location of taxable profit.Thus the introduction of the RPA-I would be likely to resultinasignificantimprovementintheperformance ofthe existingsystem,bothin termsofeconomicefficiencyandrobustnesstoavoidance. Yet the RPA-Iisbased firmly on conceptsemployed bythe existingsystem. “Routine” profitistheprofitathirdpartywouldexpecttoearnforperformingaparticularsetof functions and activities on an outsourcing basis. In this outsourcing model the third- partyfunctionsessentiallyasaserviceprovider;itdoesnotshareintheoverallriskof theMNE,andearnsnoreturnbasedontheoverallsuccessorfailureoftheproductor businesstowhichitsactivitiesrelate.Theroutineprofitforanaffiliatewouldbebased ontherateofprofitearnedbyacomparablethirdparty,appliedtoanappropriatecost base,althoughothertransferpricingapproachescouldalsobeused.Inthissense,the RPA-I would not discriminate between activities that are undertaken within the busi- nessasopposedtooutsourcedtoanindependentbusiness. The residual profit of a MNE can be calculated in two ways. The first, bottom-up ap- proach,identifiesthe residual grossincome (RGI) earned in eachdestination country. Thisismeasuredasthevalueofsalestothirdpartiesinthatjurisdiction,lessthecosts of goods sold, including expenses incurred in that country plus the transfer value of goodsandservicespurchasedfromotherpartsoftheMNE.Thetransfervalueisbased on the costs incurred in the relevant functions and activities of the selling party to- getherwithanyroutineprofitassociatedwiththosecosts.Coststhatcannotbedirectly allocated to specific sales would then be apportioned to each destination country based on that country’s share of total RGI, and the apportioned costs would be de- ductedtodeterminetheresidualprofitineachdestinationcountry.Thisapproachcan be structured to yield identical resultsto a top-down approach by which the total re- sidualincome–calculatedsimplyastotalprofitlesstotalroutineprofit-isapportioned directlybyRGI.TheRPA-Iwouldapplyirrespectiveofthenatureofthepresenceofthe MNE in the destination country. Residual profit is allocated to destination countries whetherthereisasubsidiary,branch,orsimplyaremotesalethere. The RPA-I thus adheres to existing transfer pricing rules where they are generally deemed to work reasonably well (to calculate routine profit) and departs from these 4 rulesinthecontextofresidualprofit,wheretheserulesaregenerallydeemedtostrug- gle. This RPA-I proposal differs from other RPA options proposed in the literature in two important ways. First, routine profit is determined by common transfer pricing tech- niques,insteadofbeingbasedonafixedmark-upovercosts.Thatmakesitmoreable to reflect the specific conditionsfaced by individual businesses and aimsat neutrality oftreatmentbetweenactivitiesundertakenwithinthebusinessandthoseoutsourced toanindependentbusiness.Second,the apportionmentofresidualprofit isbasedon the location of RGI, rather than sales. This hasadvantages in terms of both economic efficiencyandrobustnesstoavoidance. Michael Graetz served as a member of the group until 2016. We would like to thank him for his many contributions to our deliberations, especially on the RPA-I proposal describedhere.MichaelwasnotinvolvedinthedraftingofthisChapter. 5 I. INTRODUCTION Thischapterpresentsandanalysesanalternativeapproachtothetaxationofinterna- tional businessprofit that we believe hassignificant advantages compared to current arrangements:theResidualProfitAllocationbyIncome(RPA-I). TheRPA-IisoneofafamilyofResidualProfitAllocation(RPA)schemesthatdividein- ternational business profit for tax purposes across countries in two steps.3In a first step, all business functions and activities within a multinational enterprise (MNE)— R&Dactivities,manufacturing,generalandadministrativeactivities,salesandmarket- ingactivitiesandothers—wouldbeallocateda“routineprofit”andtaxedinthecoun- trieswherethesefunctionsandactivitiesareperformed.Inasecondstep,theremain- ing “residual profit”—the MNE’s total profit less the sum of routine profits across all countries—wouldbeapportionedacrosscountriesaccordingtosomemechanicalrule. Options within this family of schemes vary most significantly in the manner in which routineprofitiscalculatedforthefirststep,andthechoiceoflocationandapportion- ment rule for the second step. An important option, first proposed by Avi-Yonah, Clausing and Durst,4calculates routine profit through a fixed mark-up over costs and apportionsresidualprofittothemarket,ordestination,countryentirelybysales.5The RPA-I proposed in this chapter calculates routine profit using existing transfer pricing techniques. It also apportionsresidual profit tothe destination country,though using as an apportionment formula not sales but ‘residual gross income’ (RGI), defined as salestothirdpartieslesscostsattributabletothosesales. TheRPA-I’sappeal The RPA-I offers important improvements over the current system, and, in some re- spects,alsoovertheDestinationBasedCashFlowTax(DBCFT)discussedinChapter7.6 ItalsooffersimprovementsoverotherRPAproposals. The RPA-I, and other recently-proposed RPA schemes, allocates taxing rights over re- sidualprofittodestinationcountries–thatis,thecountryofathird-partypurchaserof 3SeeAndrusandOosterhuis(2017)p.102etseq.andOosterhuisandParsons(2017). 4Avi-Yonah,ClausingandDurst(2009);seealsoAvi-Yonah(2010),Avi-YonahandBenshalom(2011)and Benshalom(2009). 5Luckhaupt,OvereschandSchreiber(2012),p.107etseqputforwardasimilarmodel. 6SeeAuerbach,Devereux,KeenandVella(2017). 6 goodsorservices.Itthereforepartlyharnessesthebenefitsofdestination-basedtaxes discussed in Chapter 5. Below we assess the RPA-I against the five criteria we use to evaluateanysystemfortaxinginternationalbusinessprofit.However,bywayofintro- duction,wenotetwomajoradvantagesrelativetotheexistingsystem:itwouldbeless susceptible to tax avoidance, and it would have a smaller distorting influence on real economicdecisions. These advantages stem primarily from the relative immobility of the third-party pur- chaser. This is particularly true when the purchaser is an individual consumer, but in manycasesisalsotruewhenthepurchaserisanindependentbusiness.Byapportion- ing residual profits to the destination country, the place of taxation becomes both more transparent and less mobile. The greater transparency arises because there isa transaction with an independent third party, as opposed to between affiliates of the same MNE; the value of the transaction istherefore observable, which greatlydimin- ishes, though, as will be seen, does not wholly eliminate, the opportunity to shift re- sidual profit to a tax-favoured jurisdiction. The relative immobility of the destination countryshouldalsomeanthatthelocationoftheactivitiesoftheMNEshouldbeless sensitive to differences in taxation between countries. For example, given the option ofproducinginonejurisdictionandsellinginanother,andignoringthecostsoftrans- porting goods and services produced, a tax in the place of sale should not affect the locationofproduction. Asdiscussedbelow,theRPA-Ishouldbelessdistortiveandsusceptibletotaxavoidance thanotherRPAschemes,includingthatproposedbyAvi-Yonahetal,althoughthisdoes comeatthepriceofgreatercomplexity.TheDBCFTdoes–inprinciple,atleast–have moreattractiveefficiencypropertiesandgoesfurtherineliminatingprofit-shiftingop- portunities and the scope for tax competition. But RPAs also have an important ad- vantage over the DBCFT and other pure destination-based options such as a sales- based formulary apportionment that vest taxing rights exclusively to the destination country. That is because RPAs allocate some taxing rights to all countries involved in the generation of an MNE’s profits. This reducesthe advantage from locating the tax in the destination country but gives RPAs a practical appeal since they accord more readilywithacommonperceptionoffairnessanddepartlessdramaticallyfromcurrent arrangementsintheallocationoftaxingrights. Asaresult,thebasicstructureofRPAschemesismorefamiliartotaxpractitionersthan that of pure destination-based options. In fact, the distinction between routine and residual profit, which is at the heart of RPAs, is the basis for most profit splits under 7 existingtransferpricingrules.RPAscanthusbeviewed asa significant expansion and modificationofanexistingtransferpricingmechanism. The RPA-I in particular would require a lessdramatic departure from theexisting sys- tem than other RPA schemes, since it uses familiar transfer pricing methods to calcu- late routine profits. Moreover, as explained below, the implied apportionment of re- sidual profitscanalsobeachievedbyusingtransferpricingmethodsandconceptsfa- miliartopractitioners.TheRPA-Ischemethusachievesfundamentalreform,address- ing many of the problems left outstanding by the BEPS project, but does so in a way thatisreadilycomprehensibletotoday’staxpractitioners. MoreontheRPA-I The RPA-I has the appeal of a hybrid: it uses familiar transfer pricing methods to achieve what they are generally thought to (or could) do relatively simply and effec- tively(calculateroutineprofits),anditreapsthebenefitsofaunitaryapproachwhere theydonot(inallocatingtheresidualprofit).Eveninthelattercase,however,itpartly uses well-known transfer pricing methods and concepts. This requires some further explanation. Under the RPA-I routine profit is determined using well-established transfer pricing methods.TherighttotaxthisroutineprofitisgiventothecountryinwhichtheMNE’s functionsandactivitiestakeplace.Theconceptofroutineprofitsisfamiliartotransfer pricingspecialists.7 Itistheprofitathirdpartywouldexpecttoearnforperforminga particular set of functional activities on an outsourcing basis, in which the third party is essentiallya service provider thatdoesnot share in the overall riskof the business. Typically, routine profit for functions and activities in a particular jurisdiction can be calculatedasamark-upover(certain)expensesincurred,8wherethemark-upisbased ontherateofprofitearnedinacomparable service provider,althoughothertransfer pricingtechniquescouldalsobeused.Butthe keytotheuseofthesemethodsinthis contextisthattheyaimtoidentifyonlytheroutineelementofprofit,andnottoinclude anyresidualprofit. 7SeeOECD(2017)AnnexIItoChapterII,p.433. 8Inprincipleamark-upshouldnotbegivenforexpensesincurredinpurchasingintermediategoods,as thiswouldresultindoublecounting.Thisisdiscussedinmoredetailbelow. 8 Therighttotaxtheremainingresidualprofitisgiventothecountriesinwhichsalesto independentthirdpartiesaremade:thedestinationcountries.Thecalculationofhow residual profit is allocated between destination countries can be undertaken in two ways,whichgenerateexactlythesameresults. Thefirstapproach(whichwelabel“bottom-up”)drawsmorecloselyonexistingtech- niquesandisintwosteps. Atthefirststep,theRGIineachdestinationcountryiscalculated.Asnoted,this is equal to the sales revenues in that country less “allocable” expenses (by whichismeantexpensesincurredinanycountrythatcanbedirectlyallocated to the goods or servicessold in the relevant destination country) and the rou- tine profit associated with those expenses. Allocable third-party expenses in- curred in the destination country, together with an associated routine profit where relevant, are simply deducted from sales revenues. Allocable expenses incurredbyotheraffiliatesareallocatedtodestinationcountriesbyconstruct- ingdeemedtransferpricesequaltotheexpensesandassociatedroutineprofits oftheotheraffiliates. Atthesecondstep,residualprofitineachdestinationcountryisdeterminedas RGIlessashareoftheMNE’stotal“non-allocable”expenses(bywhichismeant thoseexpensesthatcannotbedirectlyallocatedtoanyspecificsales,forexam- ple,researchanddevelopmentexpenses,generalandadministrativeexpenses andglobalsalesandmarketingexpenses)andtheroutineprofitassociatedwith those expenses. Each destination country is allocated a share of the non-allo- cableexpensesbasedonitsshareoftheMNE’stotalRGI. Thesecond,andequivalent,approachtoallocationofresidualprofitamongstdestina- tioncountries(whichwelabel“top-down”)istofirstcalculatetheMNE’stotalresidual profit, as its total profit less its total routine profit. This total residual profit can then beallocatedamongstdestinationcountriesinproportiontotheirRGI.Thisyieldsiden- ticalresultstothefirstapproach.9 The“bottom-up”approachtotheRPA-Iislikelytoappealmostnaturallytopractition- ers steepedintheuse oftransferpricestoallocate profits.The “top-down” approach may appeal more to economists and others familiar with the concept of formulary 9ThisisshownintheAppendix. 9

Description:
second proposal – for a form of residual profit allocation - is presented here. The RPA-I allocates the right to tax routine profit to the country where
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.