“A perceptive contribution to debate R The British Labour Party is in crisis. A E about the Labour Party which now prolonged period of government between B U EDITED BY KEVIN HICKSON faces a crisis of existence as a 1997 and 2010 saw the party intellectually IL D serious political force.” exhausted. The subsequent leadership of Ed I N Lord Neil Kinnock Miliband ultimately failed with the loss of the G 2015 General Election, and the party now finds S REBUILDING O “Every generation of social itself without a clearly defined set of aims and C I democrats must revise their ideology values. A L to reflect new times and this book Rebuilding Social Democracy is the first major D SOCIAL does exactly that.” reappraisal of social democracy and thinking EM Lord Raymond Plant, Labour Peer, on the centre left since the election of Jeremy OC House of Lords Corbyn. With a foreword by Peter Hain, it R DEMOCRACY A examines the key foundational principles of C “The arguments contained in this Y social democracy, including economic reform, book point to one way out of the equality, welfare, public service organisation, E D current impasse the Labour Party social cohesion, civil liberties, democratisation, IT E finds itself in.” and internationalism, in order to find a route D Polly Toynbee, Guardian Columnist back to political credibility for Labour. B Y “An incisive and eloquent collection Written by leading academics in the field, it KE TCheo rCeu prrreinntc Sipitlueast ifoonr atnhde acne nAtltreer nleafttive Future of essays which engage with the identifies the values and objectives needed VIN to move the party forward, and revive left and H underlying political principles centre-left thought and practice in Britain as an IC shaping centre-left politics in the K alternative to Conservative austerity. S world today.” O N Dr Kevin Hickson is Senior Lecturer in Politics Patrick Diamond, Queen Mary, at the University of Liverpool, where he teaches University of London and researches on British political ideologies. He has published widely, including to debates “A serious and timely attempt to find on the future of the Labour Party. He was a solution to Labour’s ‘existential Labour’s Prospective Parliamentary Candidate crisis’.” in East Yorkshire in 2015 and is a Labour Steven Fielding, Councillor in Crewe, where he was Leader of University of Nottingham the Council between 2013–15. P O L INIC SY IG P HR TE SS S ISBN 978-1-4473-3317-3 www.policypress.co.uk IN POLICY PRESS INSIGHTS S @policypress IG H SOCIAL ISSUES / POLITICS PolicyPress 9 781447333173 TS POLICY PRESS INSIGHTS HICKSON_Rebuilding social democracy_pbk.indd 1 8/23/2016 12:39:45 PM EDITED BY KEVIN HICKSON REBUILDING SOCIAL DEMOCRACY Core principles for the centre left POLICY PRESS INSIGHTS First published in Great Britain in 2016 by Policy Press North America office: University of Bristol Policy Press 1-9 Old Park Hill c/o The University of Chicago Press Bristol 1427 East 60th Street BS2 8BB Chicago, IL 60637, USA UK t: +1 773 702 7700 t: +44 (0)117 954 5940 f: +1 773 702 9756 [email protected] [email protected] www.policypress.co.uk www.press.uchicago.edu © Policy Press 2016 British Library Cataloguing in Publication Data A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data A catalog record for this book has been requested. ISBN 978-1-4473-3317-3 (paperback) ISBN 978-1-4473-3320-3 (ePub) ISBN 978-1-4473-3319-7 (Mobi) The rights of Kevin Hickson to be identified as editor of this work has been asserted by them in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. All rights reserved: no part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of Policy Press. The statements and opinions contained within this publication are solely those of the editor and contributors and not of the University of Bristol or Policy Press. The University of Bristol and Policy Press disclaim responsibility for any injury to persons or property resulting from any material published in this publication. Policy Press works to counter discrimination on grounds of gender, race, disability, age and sexuality. Cover design by Policy Press Front cover: image kindly supplied by www.alamy.co.uk Printed and bound in Great Britain by CMP, Poole Policy Press uses environmentally responsible print partners Contents Contributors iv Foreword: rediscovering confidence and soul v Peter Hain Introduction 1 Kevin Hickson One Political economy 9 Kevin Hickson Two Equality 25 Robert M. Page Three Welfare 43 Pete Redford Four Public services 59 Simon Griffiths Five Social cohesion 77 Jasper Miles Six Civil liberties 95 Judi Atkins Seven Citizenship and the constitution 111 Emily Robinson Eight Internationalism 127 Matt Beech Nine Conclusion 141 Kevin Hickson Index 145 III Contributors Judi Atkins is a lecturer in politics at Coventry University Matt Beech is a senior lecturer in politics and Director of the Centre for British Politics at the University of Hull Simon Griffiths is a senior lecturer in politics at Goldsmiths, University of London Peter Hain is a Labour Peer, formerly MP for Neath (1991–2015) and a Cabinet Minister Kevin Hickson is a senior lecturer in British politics at the University of Liverpool Jasper Miles is completing his PhD at the University of Liverpool Robert M. Page is Reader in democratic socialism and social policy at the University of Birmingham Pete Redford is completing his PhD at the University of Birmingham Emily Robinson is a senior lecturer in politics at the University of Sussex Iv Foreword: rediscovering confidence and soul Peter Hain1 Why have social democratic parties been in abject retreat at the very time when inequality has been so remorselessly widening, real wages for the middle and working class declining and financial capitalism plagued by instability? Of course frustration with social democratic parties is nothing new. The 1906 British general election sent 29 Labour MPs to the House of Commons. Yet, just two years after this pioneering political development, the leader of London’s dockers Ben Tillett issued a pamphlet entitled Is the Parliamentary Party a Failure?2 A healthy impatience for progress has certainly been one of the Labour membership’s key characteristics from the very start, guarding against complacency and what Ernest Bevin called ‘poverty of ambition’. But it is acutely relevant to European social democracy today where centre-left parties seem to have lost faith in their own philosophy, leaving voters wondering what they stand for and whose side they are on. In Britain former Labour Deputy Leader and Cabinet Minister Roy Hattersley put his finger on the deep-seated nature of the problem with his succinct indictment of Labour’s 2010 general election defeat: ‘The Party not only failed to set out a clear and coherent idea of what it proposed to do. It was not even sure about the purpose of its existence.’ Although in 2015 Labour won 740,000 more votes, its 30 per cent share of the votes cast fell well short of the 43 per cent in its 1997 v FOR YOURTEHBU WILDOINRGK SEORCISA LA DNEMDO YCORAUCTYH WORK landslide. Over four million votes had gone missing, the great majority under Tony Blair by 2005. Underlying the decline of Europe’s social democratic parties has been a striking loss of self-confidence in projecting a serious alternative to the right and its neoliberal ideology. Unable or unwilling to adopt a distinct anti-austerity stance, they have been settling for second best by offering a pale imitation of right-wing economic policies, and suffering a serious loss of support with voters looking elsewhere for hope of a better future. In Britain this meant Labour fighting the 2015 election on a vague call for ‘sensible cuts’ in public spending. That, it was claimed, would restore Labour’s lost credibility on economic policy by making the Party appear more ‘responsible’ in the eyes of an electorate that supposedly attributed big budget deficits to alleged Labour ‘overspending’ before the 2008 global financial crisis. Although it offered only a milder version of Conservative austerity, it was a stance widely backed, if not in detail then in general, by a range of Labour opinion including leading MPs, Fabians and Progress supporters. Paradoxically its principal architect, the then Labour Shadow Chancellor Ed Balls had argued something rather different in his August 2010 Bloomberg lecture. That was when he explained why, by trying to force the pace of deficit reduction, Tory Chancellor George Osborne risked stalling the engine of growth and trapping the UK economy in a slow growth/no growth equilibrium that could last for years. Which is what duly happened.Osborne’s austerity first halted Labour’s carefully nurtured growth following the global banking crisis and the ensuing recession, then caused the recovery to stall for fully three years. Growth took off for just a year before dropping back as the economy lost momentum. UK growth in 2015 was slower than in 2014 and is forecast to be slower still in 2016. The result? Osborne fell behind schedule on his debt targets and went significantly over- budget on borrowing where he became a serial offender. In the financial year 2015–16 he delivered a £76 billion borrowing figure – exceeding the figure forecast by Chancellor Alistair Darling in his final Labour budget in March 2010 when he planned to bring vI FOREWORD down Britain’s budget deficit over the following Parliament to £74 billion in 2014–15. Yet it was precisely Labour’s £74 billion level of planned borrowing that the new Tory Chancellor condemned when he took over at the Treasury. It would take Britain close to ‘the brink of bankruptcy’, he fulminated, insisting Labour could not be trusted. Instead he replaced it in June 2010 with new tougher targets, halving Labour’s planned borrowing in 2014–15 from £74 billion to £37 billion and setting himself a tight borrowing target of £20 billion for 2015–16. Both those targets were missed by a mile. By March 2016 debt was £275 billion above Osborne’s target and the 2015–16 budget deficit was £56 billion higher than he had planned in 2010. So much for the credibility of his ‘long term economic plan’. After the Brexit referendum on 23 June 2016, with the economy rocky, even Osborne shamelessly abandoned his destructively unattainable plan for a budget surplus by 2020. That, however, did not stop him continuing to play the Greece card which robbed his faint-hearted critics of their resolve just as effectively as kryptonite robbed Superman of his strength. They were afraid to back an alternative to austerity after swallowing the Osborne line that to do so would trigger inflation or lose confidence in the bond markets, raising the risk of being unable to borrow except at sky high interest rates or, like Greece, not being able to borrow at all – propaganda simply swallowed by spineless uncritical British newspapers and broadcasters, which made challenging it difficult for politicians. Yet all the Chancellor’s scaremongering about Britain becoming another Greece proved to be nonsense. Just like under Labour Chancellor Darling even during the banking crisis, Britain has had no problem financing its budget deficit and the yield on UK government debt dropped to an all-time low of 1.22 per cent in February 2016. The Chancellor kept crying wolf while the bond market kept behaving more like Britain’s best friend. vII FOR YOURTEHBU WILDOINRGK SEORCISA LA DNEMDO YCORAUCTYH WORK From consensus to financial crisis Fifty years after Ben Tillett’s outburst, Tony Crosland in his seminal book, The Future of Socialism,3 pointed out that the 1945–51 Labour government had overcome severe postwar austerity to carry out a social revolution that exceeded even the most optimistic expectations of 1930s radicals such as GDH Cole and Evan Durbin. What is more, Crosland was confident that the Conservative Party had accepted the postwar social framework. A political consensus saw cross-party support for a welfare state inspired by Beveridge, full employment policies based on Keynes, and tax and spending measures that encouraged greater equality and fewer class differences. That consensus lasted until the advent of Thatcherism when the neoliberal challenge to the hegemony of social democratic ideas began – and from which we are still suffering today. Since 1980 neoliberals have disputed the role of the state acting on behalf of society in support of the public interest. Instead, they denigrate collective action and back market forces and self-reliance.Of course social democrats, or democratic socialists, respect the productive power of markets. We want to harness market forces to the promotion of the common good. When Brad DeLong in 2014 compared GDP per head in east European centrally-planned economies with that in matched west European market-based economies before the fall of the iron curtain, he found that productivity in the soviet bloc states was less than 20 per cent that of the market-based economies. Only a dogmatist would ignore such evidence.4 Social democrats, however, also know that markets require regulation because they often fail, sometimes spectacularly so, as in 2008 when a global financial crisis brought the entire economic system to the brink of complete collapse. Progressive economic management requires a deft balance between free-market forces and responsible state intervention. As JK Galbraith explained in The Great Crash, we are conservatives who seek antidotes to the suicidal tendencies of the capitalist system and are therefore dismissed as radicals.5 In retrospect, the 2007–08 global banking crisis showed that Labour had been blind to a threat of financial instability. Critically, vIII FOREWORD we had allowed recklessly irresponsible bank lending to become a law unto itself, untroubled by a flawed system of financial regulation. In common with most other governments across the world, we had permitted market forces to have their head, and they had run away with us, as, like lemmings, the herd instinct took financial institutions right over the edge. Today, the casino side of banking still poses a deadly threat to economic stability, with bankers facing the same temptation to take reckless risks in the belief that the taxpayer will step in to save them when things go wrong again. As they surely will, because free-market systems are inherently unstable and financial markets are prone to periodic failure. Except that next time the banks may become too big to save. It is all very well saying, as the IMF did in 2014, that across the advanced economies the net cost of rescuing the banks was at most 3 per cent of GDP, once the crisis had passed and government equity stakes in bailed-out banks had been recovered. But at the peak of the crisis the total value of support from governments and central banks by injecting capital, providing liquidity and guaranteeing liabilities, was equivalent to 74 per cent of UK GDP and overall 25 per cent of world GDP. Former IMF chief economist Simon Johnson has summed up the situation: ‘We are nearing the end of our fiscal and monetary ability to bail out the system. We are steadily becoming vulnerable to disaster on an epic scale.’6 The left should be insisting upon stricter rules for all financial institutions, including the shadow banking sector of private equity outfits and hedge funds, so that the public interest becomes paramount. Neoliberalism ought to be lying in pieces, fit only for the rubbish bin of history. The global financial crisis that threatened to plunge the world economy into a second great depression and from which after eight long years European economies are still only slowly recovering, ought never to have happened according to the efficient markets hypothesis. Neoliberal theory says that the financial system is self- correcting. Sudden shocks on the scale of the 2008 banking crisis ought not to occur, and if they do the system is supposed to correct Ix