Maitah, Mansoor; Kuzmenko, Elena; Smutka, Lubos Article Real effective exchange rate of rouble and competitiveness of Russian agrarian producers Economies Provided in Cooperation with: MDPI – Multidisciplinary Digital Publishing Institute, Basel Suggested Citation: Maitah, Mansoor; Kuzmenko, Elena; Smutka, Lubos (2016) : Real effective exchange rate of rouble and competitiveness of Russian agrarian producers, Economies, ISSN 2227-7099, MDPI, Basel, Vol. 4, Iss. 3, pp. 1-19, https://doi.org/10.3390/economies4030012 This Version is available at: http://hdl.handle.net/10419/167741 Standard-Nutzungsbedingungen: Terms of use: Die Dokumente auf EconStor dürfen zu eigenen wissenschaftlichen Documents in EconStor may be saved and copied for your Zwecken und zum Privatgebrauch gespeichert und kopiert werden. personal and scholarly purposes. Sie dürfen die Dokumente nicht für öffentliche oder kommerzielle You are not to copy documents for public or commercial Zwecke vervielfältigen, öffentlich ausstellen, öffentlich zugänglich purposes, to exhibit the documents publicly, to make them machen, vertreiben oder anderweitig nutzen. publicly available on the internet, or to distribute or otherwise use the documents in public. Sofern die Verfasser die Dokumente unter Open-Content-Lizenzen (insbesondere CC-Lizenzen) zur Verfügung gestellt haben sollten, If the documents have been made available under an Open gelten abweichend von diesen Nutzungsbedingungen die in der dort Content Licence (especially Creative Commons Licences), you genannten Lizenz gewährten Nutzungsrechte. may exercise further usage rights as specified in the indicated licence. http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/ economies Article Real Effective Exchange Rate of Rouble and Competitiveness of Russian Agrarian Producers MansoorMaitah*,ElenaKuzmenkoandLubosSmutka DepartmentofEconomics,FacultyofEconomicsandManagement,CzechUniversityofLifeSciences, Prague16521,CzechRepublic;[email protected](E.K.);[email protected](L.S.) * Correspondence:[email protected];Tel.:+420-224-38-21-39 AcademicEditor:RalfFendel Received:3March2016;Accepted:15June2016;Published:27June2016 Abstract: AnumberofdevelopmentprojectswerelaunchedinRussiatosupportagro-producers, emphasizing increasing potential and perspective significance of Agrarian sector in the Russian economy. In light of this, it becomes interesting to investigate the position of agro-producers both in comparison to producers from other domestic sectors and relatively to its main foreign competitors. Ananalysisoftherecentdynamics(from2000to2014)oftherealeffectiveexchange rateofRussianroubleservesinthepresentstudyasanindicatorofpricecompetitiveness,which determinesrelativepositionofdomesticproducersinexternalmarkets. Theactualcompetitivestate of Russian agro-producers is analyzed by the means of revealed comparative advantage indices proposedbyBalassa,VollrathandLafay. Thecalculationshaveshownthattheentireanalyzedperiod canbegenerallycharacterizedastheperiodofsignificantrealappreciationoftheRussianroubleand thereasonbehindthisisthedifferenceininflationratesinRussiaanditsmainforeigntradepartners. Thispredeterminedtherelativelylowpricecompetitivenessofagro-producers,whichwasmostly confirmedbycalculatedvaluesofBalassaRevealedComparativeAdvantage(RCA)index,Vollrath RevealedCompetitivenessindex(VRC)andLafayTradeSpecializationindex(LFI).Theshort-term realdepreciationsoftheroubledidnothaveanyexpectedsubstantiallypositiveimpactsontheir competitiveposition. Keywords: real effective exchange rate; agrarian producers; economic sectors; competitiveness; Balassaindex;Vollrathindex;Lafayindex;Russia JELClassification: F31;Q17 1. Introduction TheRussiangovernment’sactivityaimedatregulationandsupportofagriculturehasincreased recently. Thenecessityofreceivingbyagricultureastatesupport,includingfinancialsupport,aimed at stimulation of its efficiency growth, is determined by the characteristics of the agrarian sector. Among these characteristics can be listed the following ones: the impact of climatic factors that determinethecreationanddevelopmentoftheinsurancesystemwiththedirectparticipationofthe state;pricevolatility,whichdependsonmarketconditionsandischaracterizedbylowelasticityof demandforagriculturalproducts;alowdegreeofmonopolizationofagriculturalproductioncompared withothersectorsoftheeconomy;andlackofcapitalinflowsintointensiveagriculture,whichcannot haveareturnoninvestmentgreaterthaninotherareas(Shkarupa,2010[1];Batmanovaetal.,2014[2]). ProminentAmericanspecialistontheRussianeconomyCliffordGaddypointsoutthatRussia’soiland gassectorwillcontinue,forthepredictablefuture,tobethekeytothecountry’seconomicdevelopment (Gaddy,2004[3]). Nevertheless,therecentpolicydirectionforreformingRussia’sindustrialstructure shouldalsobenoted. Asitisknown,theRussiangovernmenthasadoptedapolicytotargeteconomic Economies2016,4,12;doi:10.3390/economies4030012 www.mdpi.com/journal/economies Economies2016,4,12 2of19 developmentawayfromheavydependenceonoilandgas(Kuboniwa,2011[4]). Themostimportant events in agricultural policy during the years selected for the analysis in the present paper (from 2000to2014)werethenationalproject“TheDevelopmentofAgriculturalComplex”(2006–2007),the FoodSecurityDoctrineoftheRussianFederation(2010),andRussia’saccessiontotheWorldTrade Organization(2012). Theadoptionofthesedocumentshasestablishedanewformalframeworkfor agricultural business, and created a space for emerging possibilities to change the situation in the country’s agriculture (Barsukova, 2013 [5]). Within the frameworks of these directives, a number ofdevelopmentprojectswerelaunchedtosupportagrarianproducers,whichemphasizesthefact ofincreasingpotentialandperspectivesignificanceoftheAgrariansectorintheRussianeconomy (Shkarupa, 2010[1]). Inlightofthis, itbecomesinterestingtoinvestigatethecompetitiveposition of Russian Agrarian producers both in comparison to domestic producers from other sectors and inrelationtoitsmainforeigncompetitors. (MaitahandSmutka,2016[6]),(Smutkaetal.,2015[7]), (Maitahetal.,2016[8]). Economists employ the notion of “competitiveness” in various ways. One is exclusively macroeconomic: theabsenceofcompetitivenessisconsideredasarealexchangerateposer,whena countryatfullemploymentexperiences“apersistent(andunwelcome)currentaccountdeficitwhich wouldinduecourserequireadjustment,usuallyviaamixtureofdeflationanddepreciation”(Boltho, 1996[9]). Themeasureofcompetitivenesshereis“relativepriceand/orcostindicesexpressedinsome commoncurrency”(Boltho,1996[9]). Thisapproachimpliesthat“underlyingstructuralfactorsare constant(orirrelevant)andfocusesonthekindsofshort-termmacroeconomicmanagementthataffect relativepriceofnationalgoodsandservicesrelativetoothercountries”(Lall,2001[10]). Accordingto economictheory,oneofsuchmacroeconomictoolsenablingmonitoringandtheadjustmentofprice competitivenessofdomesticproducersistherealeffectiveexchangerate(Klvacˇová,2005[11]). Itis important that the real effective exchange rate does not deviate steadily and too much from its equilibriumlevelgivenbyeconomicfundamentalssothatrelativepriceskeepneartotheequilibrium overtimeallowingacountry’sexternalpositionbesustainable(Ajevskisetal.,2014[12]). BothfundamentalcharacteristicsoftheRussianeconomyandexternalenvironmentplayaleading roleinshapingtherealeffectiveexchangerateinRussia. Theobservedchangesintherealeffective exchangeratearelargelycausedbyfluctuationsinworldcommodityprices,andmainlycrudeoil prices. At the sametime, the monetaryauthorities may to a certainextent influence the exchange rate. TheformerMinisterofFinanceintheRussianFederationAlekseyKudrin(2006)[13]assertsthat ahighgrowthrateofnationalcurrencyappreciationisdangerousforanyeconomy,andgenerally governmentsavoidthepolicyof“strong”nationalcurrencies. Thestrongestnegativeimpactofthe rapidappreciationoftheroubleisperceivedbybusiness,sincetheinternalcostsstarttoexceedthe costsofsimilarproducts’producinginothercountries. Theinfluenceoftheexternalenvironment ontheexchangerateoftheRussianroublewasmitigatedbyappropriatemeasuresoftheRussian Federation’sCentralBank. ThemaintoolforsolvingthisproblemistheBankofRussia’sintervention inthecurrencymarket. Whenthetermsoftradeimprovesuchinterventionsleadtoanincreasein foreignexchangereserves,whileduringtheperiodsofdecliningexportpricestheBankofRussia’s interventionsresultindeclineinforeignexchangereserves. Inconductingtheexchangeratepolicy, The Bank of Russia takes into account its impact on the competitiveness of Russian goods in the domestic and foreign markets. Adhering to the policy of maintaining an undervalued currency, governmentstherebyseektoprotecttheireconomiesfromforeigncompetition. One of the strongest propositions of classical trade theory is that the pattern of international trade,whichreflectsacountry’sexternalposition,isdeterminedbycomparativeadvantage. Inother words,acountrywiththecomparativeadvantageinagivencommodityexports,andtheotherwith thecomparativedisadvantage—imports(Sanidas,2010[14]). Traditionally,RevealedComparative Advantage (RCA) indices have been used as measures, which can be interpreted in three ways. “First,theycanprovideademarcationregardingwhetherornotagivencountryenjoysacomparative advantage on a given commodity (dichotomous measure); second, they can provide rankings of Economies2016,4,12 3of19 sectorswithinagivencountryincross-sectoranalysis,andrankingsofcountrieswithrespecttoa givencommodityincross-countryanalysis(ordinalmeasure); lastly, theycanquantifythedegree ofcomparativeadvantageenjoyedbyagivencountrywithrespecttoagivencommodity(cardinal measure)”(Ballanceetal.,1987[15]).Accordingly,afewwaysofusingtheRCAindicesexistinorderto analyzeacountry’stradeperformance.Themostcommonwayisto“makeacomparisonacrosssectors withinagivencountryoracrosscountrieswithrespecttoagivensectorsbyusingrankingsinorder ofthecalculatedindexvaluesortoexaminehowmuchofcomparativeadvantageordisadvantagea givencountrygainedduringtheperiodofinterestbydirectlycomparingthecalculatedindexvalues” (Sanidas,2010[14]). “Themainaimofcompetitivenessstrategyistohelpcountriestorealizeorbuild dynamiccomparativeadvantage ... whatassumesthatstaticadvantagesbasedonexistingfactor endowmentsarealreadyfullyrealized”(Lall,2001[10]). Theimportantquestionthatthenarisesis whattheconditionsareunderinwhichsuchstrategiescanbeestablishedsuccessfully. Inordertotry toanswerthisquestion,oneneedsfirsttoanalyzethecurrentstateofaffairsinthatfieldinacountry reflectedbythefollowing(amongothers)macroeconomicindicators: realeffectiveexchangerateof localcurrencyunit(LCU),andRCAindices,whichtakeintoaccountbothexportandimportflowsof differentcommoditygroups. Everythingmentionedabovepredeterminedthemainaimofthepresentpaper: toanalyzethe recent dynamics (from 2000 to 2014) of the real effective exchange rate of the Russian rouble and compareitsevolutionwiththepositionofRussianAgrarianproducers(alongwithotherproducers ofselectedcommoditygroups)incorrespondinginternalandexternalmarkets. Theinternalmarket positionisrepresentedinthepresentstudybymarketshareofRussianproducersindomesticmarkets. ThepositionofdomesticproducersincorrespondingexternalmarketsisreflectedbyBalassa,Vollrath andLafayindicesofthekeycommoditygroupsoftheRussianFederation’sforeigntradeflows. 2. Methodology Themethodologyofthepresentstudy, beingbasedonthemainpropositionsoftheClassical trade theory and Keynesian theory of exchange rate, employs correspondingly both foreign trade performanceindicatorsandrealeffectiveexchangerateindex. Thus, inordertoachievethemain goalofthepresentpaper,i.e.,toanalyzetherecentdynamics(from2000to2014)oftherealeffective exchangerateofRussianrouble(REER)andcompareitsevolutionwiththedynamicsofcompetitive positionofRussianagrarianproducers(alongwithotherselectedsectors’producers)incorresponding internalandexternalmarkets,theresearchwillconsistofthefollowingthreemainsections: 1. ThecalculationoftherealeffectiveexchangerateofRussianrouble. 2. TheanalysisofRussianagro-producers’competitivenessininternalmarkets.Thissection,inturn, consistsoftwosubsections: - the calculation of average annual growth rates of industrial manufacturing (selected commodity groups) in Russia and average annual growth rates of corresponding Russianimports; - thecalculationofdomesticproducers’(selectedcommoditygroups)marketshare. 3. TheanalysisofRussianagro-producers’competitivenessinexternalmarkets. ThissectiondealswithcalculationofBalassaRevealedComparativeAdvantageIndex,Vollrath RevealedCompetitivenessIndexandLafaytradespecializationindex. Thesethreemethodological partsaredescribedinmoredetailbelow. 2.1. ThecalculationoftheRealEffectiveExchangeRateofRussianRouble According to the methodology of the Russian Federation’s Central Bank, when constructing the real effective exchange rate index to a basket of foreign currencies, currencies of those foreign trade-partnershavetobetakenintoaccount,theweightofwhichintotalforeigntradeturnoverisnot Economies2016,4,12 4of19 lessthan0.5%. Thenumberofthesecountriesovertheperiodunderanalysiswasaround30andtheir sharecountedforslightlymorethan85%intotalRussia’sforeigntradeturnover. SomeofRussia’s mostimportantforeigntradepartnersarelistedintheTableA1(seeAppendixA).Selectedcountries aregroupedaccordingtotheirmembershipinaparticulareconomic/regionalblock. However,thevastmajorityofthesecountries’currenciesaccountsforaveryinsignificantshareon Russiancurrencymarket. Takingintoaccountthefactthatpaymentforthesupplyofmainexportedby RussiaproductsiscarriedoutinUSD,namelytheUSDtakesthedominatingpositionontheRussian currencymarket. Atthesametime,“theaveragetotalshareofEuroincurrencyturnoverofMoscow InterbankCurrencyExchangewas2.6%in2007,whereastheshareofEurointhebasketofforeign currenciesaccountsforupto44.5%”(Panilov,2009[16]). Forthesereasons,theconstructionofREERinthepresentstudywasdoneonthebasisofbothUSD andEURcurrencies. ThecorrespondingweightswillbecalculatedastotalturnoverofUSD/RURand EUR/RURinMoscowInterbankCurrencyExchange. EquationforcalculationofREERisgivenbelow: ˜ ¸ źn P NERMk wmk REER “ m ¨ m (1) m Pk NERMk i“1 m m´1 whereREER isthemonthlyrealeffectiveexchangeratetoUSDandEUR;P isapriceindexthat m m demonstratestheratioofinflationrateforthemonth-mtopreviousmonth-(m´1)inRussia;P kisthe m sameindexforcountry-k;NERM kisthemonthlyaveragenominalexchangerateofRussianrouble m (indirectquotation)tok-currencyinmonth-m;NERM kisthesameforthepreviousmonth-(m´1); m´1 w kisnormalizedmonthlyweightofk-currency;n=2(USDandEUR);andkiscountry(impliesUSA m andEU). IfthecalculatedvalueofREERindexishigherthanunityitmeansthegrowthofindexrelative to the previous month and vice versa. The growth and decline in index values are expressed in percentages. Thelevelofthepreviousmonthwastakenas100%sothatapercentagegrowth/decline in REER index values was calculated as (REER ´ 1) ˆ 100%. REER index curve measured in m percentagesisthencalculatedwiththeuseofthefollowingequation: REER p%q “ REER p%q´pREER ´1qˆ100% (2) m m-1 m According to the Equation (1), the REER index is influenced by the values of inflation rate (expressedasConsumerPriceIndex)P , P k andnominalexchangerateindexNER k. Thus, the m m m resultingvalueoftheREERindexcanberewrittenas: REER “ REERpP qˆREERpNER q (3) m m m whereREER(P )isaREERindexpurifiedfromNER influence(orwhenNER isconstant), but m m m influencedbychangesininflationrate;andREER(NER )isaREERindexpurifiedfromP influence m m (orwhenP isconstant),butinfluencedbychangesinNominalexchangerateindex. m FollowingthesamelogicasinEquation(1),weget: źn ´ ¯wk REERpP q“ P {Pk m (4) m m m k“1 źn ´ ¯wk REERpNER q“ NERk m (5) m m k“1 Economies2016,4,12 5of19 CalculationofpercentagechangesinREER(P )andREER(NER )isconductedinthesameway m m asitwassuggestedbyEquation(2): REERpP , %q “ REERpP , %q´pREERpP q´1qˆ100% (6) m m-1 m REER (NER , %q “ REERpNER , %q´pREERpNER q´1)ˆ100% (7) m-1 m-1 m UsingEquations(2)and(3),weget: REER p%q “ REER p%q´pREERpP qˆREERpNER q ´ 1qˆ100% (8) m m-1 m m InaccordancewithPanilov(2009)[16],since(x´1)ˆ(y´1)=xˆy´x´y+1,thenforanyx andythefollowingidentityistrue: xˆy=x+y´1+(x´1)ˆ(y´1). Ifxandyvaluesdifferlittlefromunity,thenthefollowingapproximateequationistrue: xˆy « x ` y´1 (9) TheerrorforEquation(9)expressedinpercentagesisthen: ((x´1)ˆ(y´1))/100%. Errorvalues becomesignificant,incaseif(x´1)and(y´1)equalto10%ormore(Orlov,2002). TakingintoaccountthatREER(P )andREER(NER )donotexceed5%,wecanconsequently m m assertthat: REERpP qˆREERpNER q« REERpP q ` REERpNER q´1 (10) m m m m SubstitutingexpressionEquation(10)intoEquation(8),weget: REER p%q«REER p%q´pREERpP q ` REERpNER q´2qˆ100% (11) m m-1 m m IfweconsidertherightpartoftheEquation(11)separatelyandsimplifyitusingEquations(6) and(7),weget: REERm´1(%)´(REER(Pm)+REER(NERm)´2)ˆ100=REER(Pm´1,%)´(REER (Pm)´1)ˆ100+REER(NERm´1, %)´100´(REER(NERm)´1)ˆ100=REER(Pm, %)+REER (NER ,%)´100. m Thus,REERindexwhereinfluencesofinflationandnominalexchangerateareseparatedcanbe writtenas: REER p%q« REERpP , %q ` REERpNER , %q´100 (12) m m m Equations (3)–(12) show the logic according to which the initial Equations (1) and (2) were representedthewayallowingdistinguishinginfluencesexertedbyinflationrateandnominalexchange rateonREER.Thisdecompositionhelpstoseewhatfactorwasthestrongestcauseoftherealeffective exchangerateappreciationordepreciation. Takingintoaccountthefactthatoneofthepartialaimsof theresearchistoanalyzetherecentdynamicsoftherealeffectiveexchangerateofRussianrouble,the decompositionanalysisisseenasjustifiedsinceitshedsomelightontherootsofREERfluctuations. TheresultsofthecalculationsarepresentedinFigure1(seeSection3). 2.2. AnalysisofRussianAgro-Producers’CompetitivenessinInternalMarkets For a meaningful assessment of any phenomenon development in time, a number of various analyticalindicatorscanbeused. Oneofthemostcommonamongthemistheaveragegrowthrate. Theaverageannualgrowthrateinindustrialmanufacturingofselectedgroupsofcommoditiesin theRussianeconomyaswellastheaveragerateofincreaseinimportsofcorrespondinggroupsof commoditiesiscalculatedinthepresentstudyemployingastandardstatisticalapproachforatime series. Theperiodfortheanalysisisfrom2000to2014. Theobtainedvalueswillthenbecompared. TheresultsofthatcomparisonaregiveninTable2(seeSection3.1). Economies2016,4,12 6of19 Theequationusedforthecalculationoftheaveragegrowthrateisasfollows: GRAi “ ppGOi {GOi q1/n´1qˆ100% (13) GO t t0 whereGRAisaveragegrowthrateexpressedin%; GO isgrossoutputinsectoriin2014; GO is t t0 grossoutputinsectoriin2000;andnisnumberofobservationswiththesameperiodicintheselected period(inourcasen=15). Thesameapproachwasemployedforcalculationoftheaveragerateofincreaseinimports: GRAi “ ((IMi {IMi )1/n´1qˆ100% (14) IM t t0 Themethodologyforcalculatingmarketshareofdomesticproducersusedinthepresentresearch isbasedonthestudyofBlank,GurvichandUlyukaev(2006)[17]. Tocalculatetheshareofdomestic producersincorrespondinginternalmarketsthefollowingdatawillbeused: thevolumesofindustrial productionbyselectedEquation(9)commoditygroupsrepresentingcorrespondingtypesofeconomic activity(valuesareexpressedinRussianroubles(RUR)),dataonimportsandexportsofthesame commoditygroups(rawdatawereexpressedinUSdollarsandthenwiththeuseofcorresponding to each period exchange rates were converted to RUR). These data allow for the estimation of the domesticsupply(S)anddomesticdemand(D)volumes: i i S “ Y ´Ex ˆe (15) i i i D “ S ` Im ˆe (16) i i i whereY isvolumesofproductionini-commoditygroup; Ex andIm arevolumesofexportsand i i i importsofi-commoditygroup(inUSD),respectively;andeistheRUR/USDnominalexchangerate. Theshareofdomesticproducerincorrespondinginternalmarketisthencalculatedwiththeuse ofthefollowingratio: v “ S{D (17) i i i TheobtainedresultsarepresentedinTable3(seeSection3.2). 2.3. AnalysisofRussianAgro-Producers’CompetitivenessinExternalMarkets Theclassicaltheoryofcomparativeadvantagepredictedthatgainsfromtheexchangeofgoods maximize welfare and free trade would lead to world economic prosperity. The determinants of the comparative advantage, however, differ among various trade theories. The Ricardian theory, forinstance, explainscomparativeadvantagefromcostsandtechnologicaldifferences, the Heckscher–Ohlin–Samuelsontheoryconsidersfactors’pricedifferences,thetheoryofproductcycle examinestechnologicalinnovation,neo-technologicaltheorylooksatfactorefficiency,butconsiders alearning-by-doingeffect(softtechnologicalchange)asthemaincauseofcomparativeadvantage differences. Comparativeadvantagefacesameasurementproblem,asitisdefinedintermsofautarkic pricerelationshipsthatarenotobservable.Tradestatisticsreflectonlypost-tradesituations(Benderand Li,2002[18]). Therevealedcomparativeadvantage(RCA)approach,pioneeredbyBalassa(1965)[19], assumesthatthetruepatternofcomparativeadvantagecanbeobservedfrompost-tradedataonly. BalassaRCAcomparestheexportshareofagivensectorinacountrywiththeexportshareofthat sectorintheworldmarket. TheRCAindexiscalculatedasfollows(Balassa,1965[19]): RCA “ pX {X q{pX {X q “ pX {X q{pX {X q (18) ij it nj nt ij nj it nt whereX isexportsofj-commodityfromi-country;nisasetofcountries;andtisasetofcommodities. ij RCAindexisbasedonexportperformanceandexistingtradepatterns. Itmeasuresacountry’s exportsofacommodityrelativetoitstotalexports. Thus,ifRCA>1,thenacomparativeadvantage Economies2016,4,12 7of19 is revealed. Up to the present time, the Balassa’s RCA index was the most common method of calculatingthecomparativeadvantages(SvatošandSmutka,2012[20]). Itservedasabaseforlater developmentsofnew,morerelevanttomoderneconomicrealitiesindices. Amonglateralternative attemptstomeasurecomparativeadvantagethefollowingmostpopularindicescanbelisted: Vollrath Competitiveindex(VCA)andLafayindex. AccordingtotheapproachsuggestedbyVollrath,therevealedcompetitiveness(RC)iscalculated asthelogarithmoftherelativeexportadvantage(lnRXA)minusthelogarithmoftherelativeimport advantage(lnRMA).Itisexpressedas: VRC “ RC “ lnRXA´lnRMA (19) whereRXAequalstoBalassaRCAindex,andRMAiscalculatedonthebasisoftheEquation(18),but, insteadofexportflows,importsareconsidered. Valuesgreaterthanzerorevealacomparativeadvantage;alternatively,negativevaluesreveala comparativedisadvantage(Vollrath,1991[21]). Thenextindicator,whichwasproposedbyLafay(1992)[22],measurestheextentofacountry’s specialization in a given sector in international dimension. The Lafay index (LFI), by taking into accountimports,allowsforcontrolofintra-industrytradeandre-exportflows. LFIindexweightseach product’scontributionaccordingtotherespectiveimportanceintotaltrade. Foragivencountryi,and foranygivenproductj(N,isaselectedsetofproducts),theLafayindexisdefinedas: ř xi´mi N pxi´miq xi`mi LFIi “100p j j ´ řj“1 j j qř j j (20) j xi`mi N pxi`miq N pxi`miq j j j“1 j j j“1 j j wherexi andmi ,are,respectively,exportsandimportsofj-commodityfromi-country. j j Usingthisindex,weconsiderthedifferencebetweeneachitem’snormalizedtradebalanceand overallnormalizedtradebalance(Smutkaetal.,2014[23]). Giventhattheindexmeasureseachgroup’s ř contribution to the overall normalized trade balance, the following relation holds: N LFIi = 0. j“1 j PositivevaluesoftheLafayindexindicatetheexistenceofcomparativeadvantagesinagivenitem; thelargerthevalueisthehigherthedegreeofspecialization. Onthecontrary,negativevaluespointto de-specialization(Zaghini,2003[24]). 3. ResultsandDiscussion Figure1illustratesthecalculationsonREERofRURindextoEUR-USDcurrencies(REER_EUR-USD) alongwithREERindicesreflectingseparateinfluencesofinflationratechanges(REER_EUR-USD_P) andnominalexchangeratechanges(REER_EUR-USD_NER)onREER_EUR-USD.Thedownward slopeoftheREERindexcurvecorrespondstotheREERgrowth,i.e.,RURappreciationwithregardto EUR-USDcurrencypair,andviceversa. The first thing that deserves attention is that the observed dynamics of REER index curve confidently points to the real appreciation of the domestic currency. The latter at the end of the analyzedperiodcomparedtothebeginningamountedtoapproximately56%. However,in2013,the realappreciationoftheRussianroubleachievedevenmoredramaticvaluesof94%. Therecoveryof theREERofRUR(itsdepreciation)inthelastanalyzedyear,2014,wasduetoasharpdeclineinthe nominalexchangerateofRURinrelationtoEUR-USDcurrencypair. Economies 2016, 4, 12 7 of 19 (cid:1876)(cid:3036)(cid:3398)(cid:1865)(cid:3036) ∑(cid:3015) (cid:4666)(cid:1876)(cid:3036) (cid:3398)(cid:1865)(cid:3036)(cid:4667) (cid:1876)(cid:3036)(cid:3397)(cid:1865)(cid:3036) (cid:1838)(cid:1832)(cid:1835)(cid:3036) (cid:3404)100(cid:4666) (cid:3037) (cid:3037) (cid:3398) (cid:3037)(cid:2880)(cid:2869) (cid:3037) (cid:3037) (cid:4667) (cid:3037) (cid:3037) (20) (cid:3037) (cid:1876)(cid:3036)(cid:3397)(cid:1865)(cid:3036) ∑(cid:3015) (cid:4666)(cid:1876)(cid:3036) (cid:3397)(cid:1865)(cid:3036)(cid:4667) ∑(cid:3015) (cid:4666)(cid:1876)(cid:3036)(cid:3397)(cid:1865)(cid:3036)(cid:4667) (cid:3037) (cid:3037) (cid:3037)(cid:2880)(cid:2869) (cid:3037) (cid:3037) (cid:3037)(cid:2880)(cid:2869) (cid:3037) (cid:3037) where xij and mij, are, respectively, exports and imports of j‐commodity from i‐country. Using this index, we consider the difference between each item’s normalized trade balance and overall normalized trade balance (Smutka et al., 2014 [23]). Given that the index measures each group’s contribution to the overall normalized trade balance, the following relation holds: ∑(cid:3015) (cid:1838)(cid:1832)(cid:1835)(cid:3036) (cid:3037)(cid:2880)(cid:2869) (cid:3037) = 0. Positive values of the Lafay index indicate the existence of comparative advantages in a given item; the larger the value is the higher the degree of specialization. On the contrary, negative values point to de‐specialization (Zaghini, 2003 [24]). 3. Results and Discussion Figure 1 illustrates the calculations on REER of RUR index to EUR‐USD currencies (REER_EUR‐USD) along with REER indices reflecting separate influences of inflation rate changes (REER_EUR‐USD_P) and nominal exchange rate changes (REER_EUR‐USD_NER) on REER_EUR‐USD. The downward slope of the REER index curve corresponds to the REER growth, Economies2016,4,12 8of19 i.e., RUR appreciation with regard to EUR‐USD currency pair, and vice versa. I II III IV 180 160 140 I. The period of declining price competitiveness 120 II. The period of increasing price 100 competitiveness III. The "turbulence" period with 80 relatively low competitiveness 60 IV. Price competitiveness of Russian producers began to grow 40 20 0 171717171717171717171717171717 000000000000000000000000000000 ‐20 0_0_1_1_2_2_3_3_4_4_5_5_6_6_7_7_8_8_9_9_0_0_1_1_2_2_3_3_4_4_ 000000000000000000001111111111 000000000000000000000000000000 222222222222222222222222222222 ‐40 REER_EUR‐USD REER_EUR‐USD_NER REER_EUR‐USD_P FFiigguurree 11.. TThheeR REEEERRo forfo ruobuleblteo taob aa sbkaestkoeftU oSfD U-ESUDR‐EcUurRr ecnucrieresn1c(i2e0s0 01 –(22001040)–,2in01%4.),N ino te%:.1 NREoEteR: i1n RdeExEiRs CinPdIeaxd jiuss tCePdIa anddjuthsetetodt aalntudr nthoev etrootaflU tSuDrn/oRvUeRr oafn dUESUDR/R/URUR Rancudr rEeUncRy/pRaUirRs wcueirgrhentecdy. Spoauirrsc ew:Aeuigthhoterd’s. cSaolucurclaet: ion,Aruawthodra’sta takcaelncufrloatmio:nw, wwr.amwi cex.druat[a2 5]atankdehnt tpsf:/ro/mw:w ww.stwatwbu.mreiacuex.o.rrug [26[,2257]] . and https://www.statbureau.org [26,27]. Still, in 2009, the impact of the world financial crisis made the Russian monetary authorities The first thing that deserves attention is that the observed dynamics of REER index curve pass “Basic directions of general state monetary and credit policy for 2009 and for the period of confidently points to the real appreciation of the domestic currency. The latter at the end of the 2010–2011”inlateOctober2008. Thepolicyofmilddepreciationoftheroubleexchangerateendedin analyzed period compared to the beginning amounted to approximately 56%. However, in 2013, the March2009withachievingthecurrencybandatRUR38–41pertheUSD/EURbasketcomparedto real appreciation of the Russian rouble achieved even more dramatic values of 94%. The recovery of RUR29–30perthebasketinSeptember2008. ThementionedbasketconsistsofUSD0.55andEUR the REER of RUR (its depreciation) in the last analyzed year, 2014, was due to a sharp decline in the 0.45. In early 2010, the Russian Federation monetary authorities made the currency band floating nominal exchange rate of RUR in relation to EUR‐USD currency pair. anditreachedRUR33.7–36.7perthebasketinApril2010duetotheriseinworldpricesofRussian Still, in 2009, the impact of the world financial crisis made the Russian monetary authorities major export commodities” (according to the All-Russian Market Research Institute’ report [28]). pass “Basic directions of general state monetary and credit policy for 2009 and for the period of Withregardtothelatestsituation,afloatingexchangerateregimeiscurrentlyunderwayinRussia. 2010–2011” in late October 2008. The policy of mild depreciation of the rouble exchange rate ended “Effectivefrom10November2014,theBankofRussiaabolishedtheexchangeratepolicymechanism in March 2009 with achieving the currency band at RUR 38–41 per the USD/EUR basket compared to throughcancellingthepermissiblerangeofthedual-currencybasketroublevalues(operationalband) RUR 29–30 per the basket in September 2008. The mentioned basket consists of USD 0.55 and EUR andregularinterventionsonandoutsidethebordersofthisband. However,thenewapproachofthe 0.45. In early 2010, the Russian Federation monetary authorities made the currency band floating BankofRussiatooperationsinthedomesticmarketdoesnotprovideforcompleteabandonmentof and it reached RUR 33.7–36.7 per the basket in April 2010 due to the rise in world prices of Russian foreignexchangeinterventions,whichcanbeimplementedincaseoffinancialstabilitythreats... Asa result of the implementation of this decision, the rouble exchange rate will be determined by the marketfactorsthatshouldenhancetheefficiencyoftheBankofRussiamonetarypolicyandensure pricestability. Besides, the newapproach tooperationsin thedomestic ForeignExchange market willcontributetofasteradjustmentoftheeconomytochangesofexternalconditionsandenhanceits resistancetonegativeshocks”(TheCentralBankoftheRussianFederation(BankofRussia),2014[29]). Thisimpliesthattheexchangerateoftheroubleisnotfixedandtherearenotargetssetfortheexchange ratecorridororitsfluctuations. Undernormalconditions,theBankofRussiadoesnotinterveneto affecttheexchangerateofrouble. Nevertheless,incaseofnecessityandinordertomaintainfinancial stability,theBankofRussiamonitorsdevelopmentsintheForeignExchangemarketandmayresortto foreignexchangeoperations. TheresultsoftherealeffectiveexchangerateofRussianroublecalculationhaveshownthatits influenceinaccordancewiththetheoryisexpectedtobeunfavorableinrelationtodomesticproducers sincerealappreciationaffectspricecompetitivenessofthelatternegatively. Theobserveddynamics ofREER_EUR-USDindexallowsustoconcludethatRURgraduallyappreciatedfromJanuary2000 toJuly2008. TherealappreciationoftheRURduringthatperiodamountedtoapproximately97% (periodI).However,innominaltermstheappreciationofRURamountedtonearly18%attheend Economies2016,4,12 9of19 ofthesameperiod. InthenextperiodII,RURdemonstratedadepreciation;thelatterlastedupto February2009andamountedtoapproximately40%relativelytoitsvalueattheendoftheprevious periodinnominaltermsandaround28%inrealterms.Afterthat,thedynamicsoftheREER_EUR-USD indexcurvecanbecharacterizedasturbulentwithadecliningoveralltrend(periodIII).Itimpliesthat duringthisperiodRURagainbegantoappreciateinrealterms. TherealappreciationofRURintheperiodIIIapproximatelyamountedto25%relativelyitsvalue attheendoftheperiodII;however,valuesofthenominaleffectiveexchangerateofRURwereatthe endofthesameperiodalmostidenticaltothoseinthebeginning. ThenextperiodIVdemonstratesa sharpgrowthofREER_EUR-USDindex,whichmeansRURrealdepreciation. Decompositionofinflation’andNER’influencesonREERhasshownthatthegreatestimpacton REERappreciationwasexertedbythedifferenceininflationratesinRussiaanditsmainforeigntrade partners(oncurrencymarket). NominalexchangeratefluctuationsaffectedREERtoamuchlower extentthanitinflationratedid(seeTable1). Table1. Contributionsofinflation(REER_P)andnominalexchangerate(REER_NER)tochangein REER1,in%. Year REER REER_NER REER_P 2000 15.10 8 92 2001 8.64 30 70 2002 5.99 31 69 2003 18.48 47 53 2004 13.89 42 58 2005 3.94 29 71 2006 15.80 61 39 2007 14.24 50 50 2008 ´1.94 51 49 2009 ´1.59 56 44 2010 4.27 23 77 2011 0.63 41 59 2012 6.08 38 62 2013 ´3.69 66 34 2014 ´35.55 82 18 Note:1REER—therealeffectiveexchangerateofRussianrouble.ValuesofREERindex,calculatedasitaverage changeincorrespondingyearrelativelytothepreviousone,arealsogivenin%.Positivevaluescorrespondto REERindexgrowth(i.e.,roubleappreciation).Source:Author’scalculation. According to Brodsky (2006) [30], real appreciation of the national currency reduces competitiveness of all domestic producers and entails a number of other negative consequences. Inparticular,REERappreciationreducesgrossoutputsaswellasexportsofmanufacturingindustries. Iteventuallyleadstounemploymentgrowth,increaseinimports,decliningnetexportsand,ultimately, adropinthevolumeofthegrossdomesticproduct. Increaseinimportsisanotheralarmingsymptom of a declining national competitiveness. In the next subsection, namely the interrelation between productionvolumesandvolumesofimportswillbeanalyzed. 3.1. CompetitivenessofRussianAgro-ProducersinInternalMarkets To investigate the position of Russian agro-producers in internal markets relative to both its foreigncompetitorsanddomesticproducersrepresentingothersectors,itwasdecidedtoestimate theirmarketsharesincorrespondingmarkets. Priortothat,itwasnecessarytocollectdatabothon volumesofproductionandcorrespondingexportandimportflows. Table2givenbelowpresentsthe resultsofthecalculationsofaverageannualgrowthratesofproductionvolumesincomparisonto averagegrowthratesofcorrespondingimports(Equations(13)and(14)wereused). Accordingtotheobtainedresults,wecanconcludethatduringtheanalyzedperiod,theaverage annual growth rates of production volumes in almost all sectors (except Mineral Products) were
Description: