ebook img

Quantifying Sustainable Development. The Future of Tropical Economies PDF

763 Pages·2000·16.182 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Quantifying Sustainable Development. The Future of Tropical Economies

CONTRIBUTORS Numbers in parentheses indicate the pages on xvhich the authors' contributions begin. SERGIO ABARCA (423), Ministry of Agriculture and Livestock, San Jose, Costa Rica BERNARDO AGUILAR (19, 595), Present address: Department of Ecological Economics and Environmental Law, Prescott College, Prescott, Arizona 86301 ALFREDO ALVARADO (265), Agronomy Investigation Center, University of Costa Rica, San Jose, Costa Rica FLORIA BERTSCH (265), Agronomy Investigation Center, University of Costa Rica, San Jose, Costa Rica MARK BROWN (695), Department of Environmental Engineering Sciences, University of Florida, Gainesville, Florida 32611 SANDRA BROWN (503), U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, National Health and Environmental Effects Research Laboratory, Corvallis, Oregon 97333; Present address: Winrocle International, Arlington, Virginia 22209 MEEGHAN CARROLL (527), Department of Forestry, State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13210 JOSEPH D. CORNELL (543), Department of Environmental and Forest Biol ogy, College of Environmental Science and Forestry, State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13210 OSCAR FLORES (423), University of San Carlos, Guatemala CYNTHIA FRIDGEN (563), Department of Resource Development, College of Agriculture and Natural Resources, Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan 48824 XVI Contributors CHARLES A. S. HALL (3, 19, 45, 91, 121, 159, 177, 223, 295, 349, 563, 647, 695, 715), Department of Environmental and Forest Biology and Program of Environmental Science, College of Environmental Science and Forestr>\ State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13078 MYRNA HALL (19, 177), College of Environmental Science and Forestry, State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13078 E. H. HELMER (503), Department of Forest Science, Oregon State University, Corvallis, Oregon 97331; Present address: Institute of Tropical Forestry, South ern Forest Experiment Station, U. S. Forest Service, Rio Piedras, Puerto Rico CARLOS HENRIQUEZ (265), Agronomy Investigation Center, University of Costa Rica, San Jose, Costa Rica CARLOS HERNANDEZ (563), Central Administration, Earth College, Gua- piles, Costa Rica GERRIT HOOGENBOOM (403), Department of Biological and Agricultural Engineering, University of Georgia, Griffin, Georgia 30223 GLENN HYMAN (205, 449), Centro de Computo, CATIE, Turrialba, Costa Rica; Present address: CIAT, Cali, Colombia MUHAMMED IBRAHIM (423), Department of Agroforestry, CATIE, Turri alba, Costa Rica JULIE KLOCKER (595), Comparative Extension, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, Minnesota 55455 JAE-YOUNG KO (91), College of Environmental Science and Forestr>% State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13078; Present address: Center for Wetlands, Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, Louisiana 70803 TIMM KROEGER (629, 665), Graduate Program in Environmental Science, College of Environmental Science and Forestry, State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13210 LOIS LEVITAN (121), Environmental Risk Analysis Program, Center for the Environment; Cornell University, Ithaca, New York 14850 GREGOIRE LECLERC (159, 223, 295), Laborator\^ of Geographical Analysis, CATIE, Turrialba 7170, Costa Rica; Present address: CIAT, Cali, Colombia CARLOS LEON PEREZ (349, 403), Ministry of Agriculture, San Jose, Costa Rica PABLO MARTINEZ (527), Departmento Ambiental, Avila Cathohc University, Los Cantero sin 05005, Avila, Spain Contributors XVll RAFAEL MATA (265), Agronomy Investigation Center, University of Costa Rica, San Jose, Costa Rica DAWN R. MONTANYE (647, 665), Graduate Program in Environmental Science, College of Environmental Science and Forestry, State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13210; Present address: Friends of the Earth, Washington, DC 20005 PATRICK G. MOTEL (527), Schenectady, New York 12303 WILL RAVENSCROFT (91, 349), Department of Environmental and Forest Biology, College of Environmental Science and Forestry, State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13210; Present address: Cooperative Fish and Wildhfe Unit, College of Agriculture and Forestr)^ West Virginia University, Morgantown, West Virginia 26506 TENG REYES (223), CATIE, Turrialba, Costa Rica DAVID ROSSITER (403), Department of Agronomy, Cornell University, Ith aca, New York 14850; Present address: International Institute for Aerospace Survey and Earth Sciences, Enshede, The Netherlands BENJAMIN RUBIN (449), Department of Environmental and Forest Biology, College of Environmental Science and Forestry, State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13210 OLEGARIO SAENZ (91), Department of Economics, University of Costa Rica, San Jose, Costa Rica G. ARTURO SANCHEZ-AZOFEIFA (473), Department of Civil Engineering, University of Costa Rica, San Jose, Costa Rica; Present address: Department of Earth and Atmospheric Sciences, University of Albera, Edmonton, Canada T6G 2E3 TOMAS SCHLICHTER (121), Program on Sustainable Development, CATIE, Turrialba, Costa Rica; Present address: Instituto Nacional de Techologia Agro- pecuaria (INTA), EEA Bariloche, CC 277, San Carlos de Bariloche, Argentina MARSHALL TAYLOR (177), Resources Planning Associates, Ithaca, New York 14850 PATRICK VAN LAAKE (159, 205, 403), Forest Resources Division, Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, San Jose, Costa Rica; Present address: Department of Earth and Atmospheric Sciences, University of Albera, Edmonton, Canada T6G 2E3 JUAN-RAPHAEL VARGAS (91, 647), Department of Economics, University of Costa Rica, San Jose, Costa Rica XVIU Contributors MATHIS WACKERNAGEL (695), Indicators Program Redefining Progress, San Francisco, California 94108 HONGQING WANG (349), Department of Environmental and Forest Biology, College of Environmental Science and Forestry, State University of New York, Syracuse, New York 13210 SCOTT G. WITTER (563), Department of Resource Development, College of Agriculture and Natural Resources, Michigan State University, East Lansing, Michigan 48824 FOREWORD In the temperate zones north and south of the equator there are, and have been, wealthy countries. South of the equator AustraUa and New Zealand are weaUhy. Argentina and Chile were two of the twenty wealthiest countries in the world in the late 19th century. Since the industrial revolution, no country within the tropics—with the exception of one very small city state (Singa pore)—has been anything but poor. Even within the same country this iron law of experience seems to hold. Those parts of Brazil south of the Tropic of Capricorn are much richer than those parts of Brazil within the tropics. Understanding why this should be so is a bit like a murder mystery. There are lots of suspects (the tropics have more problems with diseases because cold weather controls many diseases; leached soils from too much rainfall may present problems more difficult to solve than those of the deserts with inadequate rainfall found outside the equatorial regions), but no obviously guilty killer. If anything, the tropics have more than their share of natural resources. Big oil producers include Indonesia, Nigeria, and Venezuela. Paying for oil is a big problem for Costa Rica (the country most analyzed in this book), but lots of tropical countries with lots of oil are much poorer than Costa Rica. Tropical population growth rates are certainly a problem. No country has ever become rich without at least a century or more of population growth rates of 1% or less. Rates much above this level cause a poor country to devote too many of its resources to bringing new people up to existing economic levels, and essentially no resources are left after this is done to devote to raising the income levels of those people who already exist. But almost universally, countries within the temperate zones have managed to limit their population growth rates, while almost none within the tropics have been able to do so. Why? XX Foreword It is easy to attack existing models of economic development (this book does some of that) since they haven't worked in the tropics. Developmental economists would probably say that the people who tried to make them work in the tropics have not been disciplined enough to make them work. Using standard economic models, China after all has leapt ahead while Africa, not using those models, has fallen behind—poorer per capita now than it was in 1965. When it comes to the social discipline to get village schools organized, levels of illiteracy are orders of magnitude higher in the tropics than they are in the most illiterate countries in the temperate zones. Why? So too within countries—education levels in northern Brazil are far below those in south ern Brazil. There is a fundamental problem for all those, including the authors of this book, who would produce alternatives. Since the industrial revolution, no form of economic organization other than competitive markets has managed to generate high standards of living anywhere in the world. Many alternatives have been tried—socialism, communism, feudalism, cooperatives—all have failed. Even with all of the positive ideology that they once had behind them, the kibbutzes are dying out in Israel. Finding an alternative to the existing conventional wisdom is not easy—and maybe not even possible. In any case, it has yet to be discovered, much less tested. The burden of proof is on those who call for other solutions. As this book points out, one of the alternatives is to call for sustainable development. But the definition of sustainability is a slippery concept. If sus- tainability means a much lower standard of living than that which now exists, "sustainability" isn't sustainable. If sustainability means the ability to sustain economic development, the ability differs radically from country to country. From space, Argentina and the United States look very similar. Both were given similar natural endowments, and Argentina if anything inherited a more favorable natural position than the United States. Indeed in the 19th century, it was one point wealthier per capita than the United States. Yet Argentina's economic development was not sustainable while America's was. If one visits agricultural villages in a poor country (I recently did so in Laos), one finds villages with very different standards of living situated right next to each other with the same natural endowments. Some are well organized and some are completely disorganized. Their ability to get organized determines their ability to generate high or low standards of living for their inhabitants. Sociology in the end may be more important than biology. If a detective has an unsolved murder case, he or she interviews all of the potential witnesses (reliable or unreliable) to see if something somewhere will yield a clue to who the murderer was. This is the right frame of reference with which to approach any book on tropical development. Within it are clues to why tropical economic development is almost an oxymoron. Foreword XXI Like you, the reader, I do not claim to know the exact reasons that tropical countries are universally economic failures. But some of the clues that may lead you and me to find the murderer are certainly found within the new perspectives and extensive data analysis contained within this book. Lester C. Thurow Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology PREFACE This book is about the myths and reahties of the developing tropics. It is also about the inadequacy of our dominant intellectual paradigms for under standing and guiding that development. It considers the continuing failure, despite large efforts, of programs based on these dominant paradigms to resolve major economic and environmental problems there. Our book also uses new tools to develop a more comprehensive and realistic framework for analysis and decision making. These include biophysical and systems perspectives that integrate environment and economics, and some cutting-edge technology that combines GIS, modeling, and extensive geographical and time series databases. We have two underlying objectives: first, to examine the possibilities and limitations of "sustainable development" for guiding the future of national economies, and second, to understand more precisely the relation of the biolog ical and physical properties of a region to important components of its econ omy, including its development and conservation possibilities. We offer no silver bullets to magically resolve difficult problems, but offer instead a suite of conceptual and computer tools that enable a systems approach and conse quently, we believe, a more rigorous and detailed analysis than has been possible in the past. We focus on these issues for two reasons: One is that I, and most of the contributors to this book, believe that the conceptual basis for current eco nomic and development theory is in many respects fatally flawed. If we are to understand the principles of operation and the potential for development— sustainable or otherwise—of tropical economies, we must use a different kind of economics. We can do this by expanding the range of what we do under its aegis by again focusing on explaining, in accounting terms, what happens in society and then using the scientific method, rather than ideology, to ask why. Another way of saying this is that we need to question and test what XXIV Preface economics as a discipline has assumed and promoted. We believe this to be essential if any sort of sustainable approach to economic health and well-being is ever to be generated in developing countries. We also beheve that most of the "environmental" or "green" alternatives offered to date, including many under the rubric of "sustainability," are not particularly useful for solving the deficiencies in the traditional economic approach because they tend to focus on issues that are economically trivial. Thus, our second reason for writing this book is to examine the potential of an alternative to the dominant economic paradigm, namely, a biophysical perspective. To paraphrase Von Clauswitz, who said the "war is too important to leave to the generals," we believe that "economics is too important to leave to the economists." Our intended audience is anyone interested in a fresh and rigorous approach to understanding how developing nations operate, or might operate, as systems. The book is interdisciplinary, analytical, and academic and is appropriate for graduate courses in the environmental sciences, public administration, international relations, and economics. We especially hope that it will find an interested audience in graduate schools in the developing world and in development and governmental agencies. If we are truly successful it will serve as a blueprint for how economics "should" be done in developing countries, and the chapter-by-chapter procedures given here can serve as a basis for many countries that want to generate a full resource inventory and incorporate it into economic analysis. But the level of writing and the importance of the subject material make the book appropriate for any intelligent person interested in the intertwining of environments and economies in developing countries. Finally, because the approach is in many respects very different from what has been written about previously, we hope that anyone who wants a different perspective on the developing tropics will find the book interesting. I write as a professional ecologist. This introduces several potential miscon ceptions because of the use of the term in the popular media. "Ecologist" means to me a professionally trained person who studies some aspect of ecosystems, in much the same way as we might use "chemist" or "mathematician." As such the word "ecology" includes no implied advocacy or pohtical position. I have no problem with advocates of certain environmental policies calhng themselves ecologists, but for that usage 1 prefer the term "environmentalist." A second issue relates to the subject matter pursued by professional ecologists. My own interest has always been in asking how ecosystems work, especially those ecosystems dominated by human activities. Curiously, most professional ecolo gists do not study human-dominated ecosystems, such as cities or agricultural regions, except as they impinge upon "natural" ecosystems. Instead they seek out remnant and often remote "natural ecosystems." Thus, the structure and function of human-dominated systems, the ecosystems that increasingly and overwhelmingly dominate the surface of this planet, are rarely examined as Preface XXV ecosystems using the tools of natural science, but instead are studied mostly using the approaches of the social sciences. To me this is a serious omission, as they are just as much "ecosystems" as "social systems," and as such are characterized and constrained by energetics and material fluxes just as are the remaining "natural" ecosystems. On the other hand, the one great disappointment that I have had in writing this book is that despite my large efforts to include a chapter on the important issue of natural biodiversity, a subject in which I have little particular strength, no such chapter was forthcoming. The issue of biodiversity is treated, but not as completely as I would like, in other chapters. Our reason for undertaking this analysis is scientific and not to suggest any particular pohcy. It is our strong belief that the policy by which any nation should be run is the business of that country alone. Thus, with one exception (in the last chapter), we make no explicit policy recommendations in this book, although we were strongly encouraged to write a shorter, policy-oriented book by one of our reviewers. Ours is a difficult tightwire to tread, for our analysis includes examination and critiques of past policy and in some cases possible future pohcies. But we do so only from the perspective of analyzing consequences and of trying to understand how the system has and might work. However, if leaders in the developing world find our analyses helpful in formulating their own policies, we are of course happy about that. We have undertaken similar analyses previously for the United States (Cleveland et al, 1984; Hall et al, 1986; Ko et al, 1998) and Argentina (Paruelo et al, 1987) without explicitly recommending any policy. The first section of the book gives the reader a nonquantitative introduction to the economic and environmental situation in the developing tropics in general and in Costa Rica in particular. The second section reviews conditions of sustainability, considers whether the discipline of economics is the most appropriate set of tools for examining the issues that surround sustainability, and puts forth the alternative biophysical approach. The third and fourth sections are mostly technical and give in-depth treatments of particular tech niques and resource bases. The final sections use the technical chapters and historical information to examine the potential for sustainability. As a synthe sis we include an empirically based computer model that includes its own decision-making framework, based on real data and a synthetic perspective. This model and others are contained on the enclosed CD, so that if the reader is unconvinced by our arguments or assumptions he or she can devise some other, we hope realistic, scenario and run a new set of assumptions. The CD also contains all of the databases that we use in the book as well as unique software to display them. We believe that this tool and the in-depth analyses that we have done for Costa Rica should be broadly applicable to most other developing nations.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.