PAWN:S,HIP, S~LAVERY, AND ·C·OLO·N.IALISM IN AFRICA a.v EDITED PAUL E. .. LO·VE]OY Afri1ca Worlld Pr·ess, Inc. P.O.B~109l 'W • P.O.Bo•48 l'renlon, Nl 08607 A~mara, ERITREA 0 Africa World Pr,ess, Inc. P.O. Bo. '89> P.O. Bo<" 1 Trenton, NJ 08&07 . Asmara, ERITRIEA Copyrigh~©2003 Paul E. Lovejoy and Toyin Faiola First Printing 2003 All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means electronic, mechani cal, photocopying, recording or otherwise without the prior written permission of the publisher. Book design: Getahun Seyoum Alemayehu Cover design: Roger Dormann Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Pawnship, slavery, and colonialism in Afdca/ Paul E. Lovejoy and Toyin Faiola, eds .. Includes bibliographical references and index. ISBN 1-59221-039-2--ISBN 1-59221-040-6 (pbk.) ] . Peonage--Africa--History. 2. Slavery--Africa--History. 3. Africa--Colonization--History. I. Lovejoy, Paul E. H. Faiola, Toyin. HD4275.A3 P392003 306. 3'62'096--dc21 2002152038 ;-.·~~ '! ... . I ( . (. ..· :; ACKNOWLEDGMENTS T his volume includes the chapters origin. ally published in Toy in Faiola and Paul Lovejoy, eds., Pawnship in Africa: Debt Bondage in Historical Perspective (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, African Modernization and Development Series, Paul E. Lovejoy, Series Editor), which includes two chapters previously published, viz.: ''Pawns, Porters, and Petty Traders: Women in the Transition to Cash-Crop Agriculture in Colonial Ghana, ... by Beverly Grier, in Signs: Journal of Women in Culture and Society, 17, 2 ( 1992), 304-28 (reprinted with the pennission of the University of Chicago Press). The chapter by Martin A. Klein and Richard Roberts, "The Resurgence of Pawning in French West Africa during the Depression of the 1930s," is a revised version of an article originaUy published in Aji-ican Economic History, 16 (l987), 23-37 (reprinted with the permission of the editors). The following essays have been added to this expanded edition: E. A. Oroge, "lwofa: An Historical Survey of the Yoruba Institution of Indenture," published posthumously in African Economic History, 14 ( 1985), 75-106 (reprinted with pennission of the editors). Paul Lovejoy and David Richardson, "Pawns Will Live When Slaves Is Apt to Dyen: Credit, Risk and Trust at Old Calabar in the Era of the Slave Trade," first published in The American Historical Review, 104:2 (1999), 332-55, is reprinted here with the permission of the American Historical Society. Lovejoy and Richardson, 'The Busmess of Slaving: Pawnship in Western Africa, c. 1600-181 0," initiaHy pubhshed the Journal ofA frican History, 42:1 (200 1) , is reprinted with the permission of Cambridge University Press. Toyin Faiola, "Slavery and Pawnship in the Yoruba Economy of the Nineteenth Century," previously published in Slave1y and Abolition, 15, 2 (1994), 221- 45, is reprinted with the pennission of Frank Cass, Ltd. We gratefully acknowledge the support of the Social Sciences and Hwnanities Research Council of Canada,. and we would especially like to thank J.J. Shafer and Anita Thakurdeen for their editorial assistance. TABLE OF CONTENTS Acknowledgments ............................................................................. iii Table Of Contents ............................................................................... v 1. Pawn ship In Historical Perspective .............................................. 1 by Toyin Faiola and Paul E. Lovejoy 2. The Business Of Slaving: Pawnship In Western Africa, C. 1600-1810* .......................................................................... 27 by Paul E. Lovejoy and David Richardson 3. On Pawning And Enslavement For Debt In The Precolonial Slave Coast ................................................................................. 55 by Robin Law 4. "Pawns WiH Live When Slaves Is Apt To Dye": Credit, Risk And Trust At Old Calabar In The Era Of The Slave Trade* ........................................................................ 71 by Paul E. Lovejoy and David Richardson 5. Pawnship In Nembe, Niger Delta ................................................. 97 by Ebiegberi J. Alagoa and Atei M. Okorobia 6. Slavery And Pawnship In The Yoruba Economy Of The Nineteenth Century ............................................................ 10 9 by Toyin Faiola 7. Pawning In The Emirate Of Ilorin ............................................. 13 7 by Ann O'Hear 8. Pawnship In lgbo Society ......................................................... 165 by Felix Ekechi 9. Human Pawning In Asante, 1820-1950: Markets And Coercion, Gender And Cocoa ................................................... 187 by Gareth Austin 10. Pawnship ln Edo Society: From Benin Kingdom To Benin Province Under Colonial Rule .................................................. 225 by Uyilawa Usuanlele 11. Pawning And Slavery On The Kenya Coast: The Miji Kenda Case ................................................................ 239 by Fred Morton 12. Pawning, Politics And Matriliny Jn Northeastern Tanzania ....... 255 by James Giblin 13. Pawning In Coastal Northwest Sierra Leone, 1870-1910 ........... 267 by Allen M. Howard vi 14. Indirect Rule And The Brief Apogee OfPawnship In Nimba, Liberia, 1918-30 ........................................................... 283 by Martin Ford 15. Pawns, Porters, And Petty Traders: Women In The Transition To Cash-Crop Agriculture In Colonial Ghana ........................... 299 by Beverly Grier 16. lwofa: An Historical Survey Of The Yoruba Institution Of Indenture* ........................................................................... 325 by E. Adeniyi Oroge 17. Pawns And Politics: The Pawnship Debate In Western Nigeria. 357 by Judith Byfield 18. Pawnship In Colonial Southwestern Nigeria ............................. 387 by Toyin Faiola 19. The Resurgence Of Pawning In French West Africa During The Depression OfThe 1930s ............................................................... 409 by Martin Klein and Richard Roberts 20. "What Is And What Is Not The Law:" Imprisonrnen~ For Debt And The Institution Of Pawnship In The Gold Coast, .............. 42 7 by Kwabena Akurang-Pany Bibliograp,hy ................................................................................... 449 Notes On Contributors .................................................................... 467 Index .............................................................................................. 471 P AW NSHIP IN HISTORICAL PERSPE·CTIVE TOYIN FALOLA and PAUL E. LOVEJOY Studies in African labor and social history have emphasized,. with some justification, slavery, peasantries, and wage labor. Pawnship, a system in which individuals are held in debt bondage as collateral for' loans, has been largely' neglected, and until this volume, information on pawnship in Africa has been so scarce as to make generalization difficult 1 Yet pawns were more prevalent than hitherto recognized, and it is possible to suggest a broad historical framework to explain the political and economic conditions that accounted for the range of contexts in which pawnship was important. The institution is centuries old, at least along the Atlantic seaboard, where it appears to have developed in tandem with the growth of the trans-Atlantic slave trade, the expansion of slavery within Africa, and the greater commercialization of African economies. Because of its importance in the provision of credit, pawnship seems to have become more common in those states and societies that were most fully involved in external trade. Although at this stage of research, we cannot detennine the frequency of pawning in the distant past,. it flourished in the late nineteenth century when slavery was stiH widespread and when demand for primary products (palm oil and kemds, witd rubber, ivory, peanuts, 2 Faiola & LoveJo.F among others) had pulled African producers more fully into the international market than ever before. Under colonialism, pawnship continued to be a common mechanism for mobilizing labor and guaranteeing credit, although the demise of slavery and legal restrictions - - on various forms of servility, including pawnship, gradually altered the political and economic setting. Pawns held in debt bondage became less important in regulating the extension of credit as other forms of collateral became more common. The study of pawnship is related to questions of indebtedness, labor control, gender, and capital flows in societies that were only imperfectly connected to world markets. Hence there are a variety of themes that have to be considered in assessing the importance of this institution and how it changed over the past several centuries in the different parts of Africa that are examined in this volume. First, the prevalence of pawnship at any point in time appears to have had some correlation with poverty and the inability 2 of families and individuals to secure the necessities of life. Famine, disease, political insecurity, and econorruc miscakulation were frequent causes of poverty and the need to borrow. It should be noted, however, that poverty was not always the cause of indebtedness. Sometimes merchants borrowed to promote their trade. Their expectation was to repay the loan sooner or later out of profits. People also borrowed to meet funeral expenses, ritual obligations, and court fines. In these cases, however, failure to repay debts quickly was often a sign of deteriorating economic circumstances and hence was ultimately related to poverty. Second, pawnship involved the control over the labor of the individual held in pawn. As a mechanism for obtaining access to labor, pawnship has to be considered in the context of other mechanisms of labor supply, including slavery, communal activities, corvee, and wages. Pawnship was only one form of labor mobilization. Third, gender issues are paramount in understanding the context for pawnship because much of the labor that was mobilized through this institution was performed by women. 3 Furthennore, women and their children were often ilie ones to suffer the most from famine and political instability, and hence gender and indebtedness were often associated. Because of this vulnerability, women were exposed to sexual ,exploitation and other abuse that sometimes resulted in their reduction to slavery. Fourth, pawning was only one mechanism for obtaining credit, and hence an examination of its economic role must take into consideration other institutions and practices and how these changed in different historical contexts.4 As Gareth Austin has argued,. pawnship was characterized by "interlocking factor markets," in which the tenns of exchange in different markets (labor and credit) were contractually and 5 simultaneously tied together. Because of the primacy of women as a Pawnship in Historical Perspective 3 source of pawns, moreover, the flow of credit and the control of labor were closely linked with the institution of marriage. Until this volume, pawnship in Africa has usually been discussed in the context of slavery; pawns have been perceived as an important supplement to slaves during the precolonial period and as substitutes for slaves during the present century when slavery was declining into insignjficance. Indeed pawnship existed alongside slavery, experiencing levels of resurgence and intensity that initially depended upon the economic conditions of precapitalist social fonnations and then under colonialism on the imperfect penetration of capitalism. When slavery was dominant, pawnship fed individuals into servitude. After slavery subsided, pawnship briefly surfaced as an alternative to slavery, its appearance fluctuating with the vicissitudes of the market economy. Pawnsbip,: C.haracteristics of the Institution Pawnship, by definition, is a legal category of social and economic 6 dependency. The institution, in various fonns, was common in many preindustrial societies,. not on1y in Africa, but in southern and southeastern Asia and parts of Latin America as well, where it is usuaUy referred to as 7 deb~ bondage. The pawn was a person held as collateral fur a loan, and as in the case of trees and fanns that were pledged under a similar system of credit, the pawning of individuals constituted the transfe,r of productive assets for the duration of the debt as security, unlike a ~Ortgage, in which assets are transferred only in case of default. 8 The labor of the pawn constituted interest on the debt and covered the costs of subsistence, but did not contribute to the principal. The principal usually had a fixed value at the time of the contract and had to be paid off in full before the pawn was free from service.9 As Morton,s study of the Miji Kenda demonstrates, however, there could be disputes over the amount of the principal; if the loan had been originally calculated in tenns of a commodity whose value subsequently increased during the period of servitude, the creditor might insist that repayment be made on the basis of the inflated value, thereby adding an often substantial increment to the debt. H was also possible for the original debt to include a monemry component for interest, in which case the pawn did not usually live with the creditor. However the principal and interest were calculated, the pawn continued in bondage until the fuU debt had been repaid or otherwise cancelled. While 4 Faiola & Lovejoy ·, the period for repayment was usually indefimte before the twentieth century, colonial laws in some parts of Africa attempted to fix a terminal date for repaym.ent, thereby establishing the that the labor p~rinciple p~erfonned by the pawn itncluded both interest and capitaL The contmct that controUed the labor of the pawn represented an ]nv·estment that was realized thfough the laborRpower of the p~awn. That contract was property and henc·e was owned and could be transferred, 1 although as Byfield demonstrates in her study of Yoruba pawning in this volume, the p·ell1rission of the debtor was required before a pawn could be transferred. Pawns thems~elves were not property and were not owned,. although various authors sometimes refer to "masters" who "owned'' pawns, as if they were slaves (see below). In most instances, it would be 1 more ac·curate to refer to 11Creditors" who "'contro11ed11 pawns. This confusion over the loan and the labor of the p·awn highlights the interconnection between property and indebtedness,. on the one hand, and ' m various methods for controlling ]abor in economies whi·ch wage labor was marginal or nonexistent, on the other hand. A debt that resulted in pawning involved the imp~Hcit recognition by the debtor and the creditor that a specific amount of was owed,, and that the loan arose from ~cap~ital property rights enjoyed by the creditor. Food, money, shelter, ttade items or some c~ombination of these goods and s~ervices were extended to the debtor in Heu of fuU repayment. In short the transaction was based on the con1moditization of these goods and servic·es. Because interest continued in the fonn of labor unti1 the debt was repaid in full, pawnship had some similarities to slavery. In both cases, the creditor/master had :relatively full control over the output oftbe pawn/slave; the labor-power of the pawn/slave belonged to the cr,editor/master. Nonetheless,, there ]s an important distinction between pawnship and slav,ery., From a theoretical perspective, the pawning contract, not the pawn, was the p~rop~erty of the creditor, while under slavery,, the slav·e was the direct property of the master. Pawns, or more often their relatives who had placed them in pawn, had legal rec·our;se in the case of abuse or dispute on 1 the basis of the contract, and the contract could be tenninated on the repayment of the original debt. Slaves had no such legal recourse, although m they could achieve emancip.ation a vari.ety of ways if a master was so disposed. This proprietacy diffefence between the pawning contract and the sJave as property had important ramifications in different. historical contexts, ahhou,gh it should be recognized that the fine theoretical distinction that is drawn here often broke down in pract]c,e. Pawns could end up as slave:s, and slaves we11e pawned. som~etimes P'awns were gener:aJly drawn from within the society in which they were in bondage;. ,either pawns were freeborn members of society, or they , --------------....... - -----·--··- --------------- Pawnship in Historical Perspective 5 were slaves of long standing whom masters to redeem and to ~expected reincorporate into their households. In order for an individual to have use as collateral, it was essential that the debtor want to redeem the person. This commitment to paying off the debt was clearly established in the cas~e of self-pawning, whereby a person agre~ed to pledge him or herself as coUateral. Whether or not a person was always able to pay off the debt is another matter. The commitment to redemption was also operative in the case of close kin, where the debtors usually intended to pay off the debt. Chronic financial difficulties might prevent redemption, and therefore there was considerable risk that the transaction might involve the total alienation of the pawn. A domestic slave had value to his or her owner because slaves were an moreover over time, the relationship might well evolve inv~estment; so that the personal attachment might become almost as strong as that based on kinship. Nonetheless, the potential alienation for slaves was certainly more extreme than in instances of self-pawning or the pawning of close relatives. Pawns had to be individuals who, were recognized as constituent members of society, even if they were subordinates or peopl~e of low status. Unless they were fuU members,, they had little chance of being protected from sale into slav~ery or otherwise abused. Individuals had to have value deriving from their social relationship to the debtor in order for them to have value to the as collateral. Self-pawning intrinsicany ~cr,editor emphasiz,ed this value, even though those who pawned themselves were often in the worst position to honor a debt They were preoccupied with servioe to the creditor,. and were usually only able to cover the costs henc~e of subsistence and to pay the interest on the debt. Time had to be allowed for additional work if ther-e was any hope of the principal, or liecov~ering relatives had to be willing to repay the original debt. Those individuals who were the most effective pawns were close tdatives of the debtor, because the debtor was stiU free to conc,entrate on acquiring the resources to repay the debt. Sodal pressures and affection between debtor and pawn were effective instruments that promoted redemption. m This identification with the sodety which individuals experienced their subordination distinguished pawnship from slavery as an institution. Newly acquired slaves were foreigners or otherwise defmed as outsiders,. unlike individuals being reduced to the status of pawn. As already noted,. slaves could be pawned, but when masters arranged to slaves as us~e collateral, they were acting on the basis of their investment in slaves as prop~erty. UsuaUy, slaves could serve this function only if they were a~ccuUurated and therefore members of society as well, albeit of servile status. In a sense, pawned slaves were being treated like quasi-kin. Otherwise, a master would be more likely to sell the slave in order to p~ay a
Description: