ebook img

Pandemic Economics PDF

210 Pages·2021·6.293 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Pandemic Economics

Pandemic Economics To Andrew Cuomo who made me plan ahead of the curve M Pandemic Economics Peter A.G. van Bergeijk Professor of International Economics and Macroeconomics, International Institute a/Social Studies at Erasmus University Rotterdam, The Hague, the Netherlands IE"E"" I" Edward Elgar PUBLISHING Cheltenham, UK· Northampton, MA, USA Peter A.G. van Bergeijk 2021 © Cover image: Peeter Burgeik All rights reserved. No part ofthis publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic, mechanical or photocopying, recording, or otherwise without the prior permission of the publisher. Published by Edward Elgar Publishing Limited The Lypiatts 15 Lansdown Road Cheltenham Glos GL50 2JA UK Edward Elgar Publishing, Inc. William Pratt House 9 Dewey Court Northampton Massachusetts 01060 USA A catalogue record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Control Nmnber: 2020952724 This book is available electronically in the Elgaronline Economics subject collection http://dx.doi.orglI0.4337/9781800379978 ISBN 978 I 80037996 I (cased) ISBN 978 I 80037 997 8 (eBook) Contents Preface vii Acknowledgements ix 1. Introduction PART I THE PAST 2. Prepared, but not Equipped IS 3. The Outbreak of Pandonomics 43 Appendix A3.1 Overview of Forecasts for Global Growth in 2020 64 PART II THE PRESENT 4. Flying Blind 69 5. Reliable Tools 95 PART III THE FUTURE 6. Many Futures 121 7. Five Ps for the Next Pandemic 147 References 169 Index 193 v Preface Tuesday March 10, 2020 was my last 'normal day' in The Hague. I remember teaching my 'Global Economy' course on a pressure-cooking Tuesday in which I had stuffed as many individual meetings as possible. On Wednesday I finished field research with the last interviews in Rotterdam. Erasmus University came to a standstill on Thursday, when lectures and meetings with students were forbidden. Staff and students adapted to the new situation overnight and during the next week classes were already over the internet. Research also picked up quickly and within a few weeks we Ie-started capacity building projects, were writing and peer-reviewing and organized virtual research seminars. So academic work continued in a new format but with similar, if not more, intensity as before the outbreak. In these weeks the idea for this book emerged as an afterthought in an email exchange with Caroline Kracunas at Edward Elgar on April I, 2020. I started writing April 10. Writing was not 'normal'. Over the past decade I have written nine books while commuting and on international trips. I learned to appreciate airports, train stations and hotel rooms as places to write. Planes and trains and their delays became opportunities. It turns out that the lock-do\Vll also has its merits: this book was written at home. To most people it would seem to be very unwise to write a book on one of the largest economic crises since the Second World War while we are still amid the storm. It is indeed difficult and exhaustive to analyse a moving target. There is an information overkill and new and challenging perspectives are developed on a daily if not hourly basis. For a pure scientist it would probably make a lot of sense to wait until all the data are in so that theories and hypotheses can be tested. It is, however, necessary to write this book, because humanity for the first time in history has been able to deeply hurt the economy by its o\Vll response to a pandemic. These costs have stimulated a debate between those that give priority to the economy and those that give priority to health. This antithesis at the same time is both correct and, to a large extent, false, depending on the epidemiologic features and pathogenicity of a new virus. It is correct because health protection obviously comes at an economic cost. It is wrong because a high-mortality-high-contagion pandemic would mean economic disaster and the economy, indeed, could only survive if health was protected vigorously. vii viii Pandemic Economics The COVID-19 pandemic as such is, of course, serious, but certainly not without historical precedent and not exceptionally severe in terms of mortality. It appears that, unlike other pandemics such as the Spanish Flu and HIV IA IDS, the death toll is not among children and young adults. The response to the pandemic, however, has been exceptionally costly for the world economy and has hurt the poor and those that had just escaped from poverty in the past decade. Since pandemics occur with a frequency of roughly seven to eight events per century, it is vital to look beyond the apex of the COVID-19 pandemic and the trough of the ensuing recession, and to investigate how prevention and mitigation can become more cost effective. The only way to beat the future contagious diseases -that will without any doubt emerge -is to plan in a rational way for the Big One. We have witnessed responses that were induced by neglect, ignorance and fear. This triumvirate has led to the worst possible outcome for the world, an outcome that is not sustainable if only because killing the economy is neither helpful for the necessary investments in health care systems (diagnosis and monitoring) nor for the Research and Development that is necessary for curing and preventing the next pandemic. So, our response to the next pandemic must be better, more efficient and especially more rational. I live in the Netherlands, four meters below sealevel, and when you think about this it is a much stranger and riskier way of living than the new normal of the COVID-19 world. The Netherlands has managed to protect its way of living by means of the Delta Works, a massive and long­ term engineering project that started in 1953 and is supported by law from the vagaries of short-termism of politics. If the water comes, the policy is that I should not flee. I must evacuate vertically as my attic is sufficiently high, and horizontal evacuation (to get out of the risk area) would be dangerous because of the congestion. The Delta Works and the Dutch vertical evacuation policy offer a real-world example of how we can use planning to construct rational protection at acceptable levels, and also against pandemics. The Dutch, incidentally, needed a disaster, the North Sea Flood of 1953, to start preparing. Most important perhaps, while they were willing to invest in protection against the sea, the Dutch did not act on warnings that the Dutch Intensive Care capacity was too low in the case of a pandemic (ANY, 2016). Nobody has the perfect recipe and neither do I, but I do hope that this book can be of help by offering building blocks and a framework to think about the challenges of pandemic economics. De Koog, August 1, 2020 Acknowledgements I am not an expert; nobody is yet an expert in the new field of pandemic economics. I may, however, have been a bit more mentally prepared than most economists. I had to think about pandemics while COVID-19 was still beyond the horizon, when I was a member of ANY Netherlands Network of Safety and Security Analysts. Most of that work by its nature has been in Dutch, but an English translation of the major all-hazard report in which severe pandemic scenarios also feature has appeared as ANY (2016). This book, as my other work on disasters, has benefitted from comments by people that I have worked with in ANV, in particular, Peter Scheepstal and Leendert Gooijer. My thinking, pre COVID-19, had also been stimulated because I work at a development studies institute. The major recent almost-pandemics (or 'international epidemics', in WHO speak) have been in Africa, namely Ebola and HIV/AIDS. Development economists cannot avoid the impact of contagious diseases on the economy: one of my students had been in lockdO\vn quite recently during the outbreak ofEbola. As always, I learned a lot from the institute community, also -during the outbreak -about the daily experiences oflockdowns in Barcelona, Tel-Aviv and Dar-es-Salaam. The economics of natural disasters was not a new topic either. I have worked on natural disasters for quite some time and produced one of the first meta­ analyses on the economic impact of natural disasters in developing countries (Lazzaroni and van Bergeijk 2014). The key finding of the meta is that disasters are not by definition bad for the economy and may actually stimulate productivity. Later work on trade and disasters (Li and van Bergeijk 2019) revealed that the trade impact of disasters is not as negative as is often assumed and may sometimes stimulate trade. I do, of course, not claim that these findings on natural disasters such as floods, earthquakes and droughts are valid for the COVID-19 pandemic, because such a generalization would be both 'out of sample' and an example of the Fallacy of Hasty Generalization. Still I have benefitted from this research experience because it has forced me to keep an open eye for unexpected and counterintuitive developments during the pandemic. ix

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.