ebook img

OECD economic outlook. 2. PDF

97 Pages·1967·15.037 MB·English
by  OECD
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview OECD economic outlook. 2.

ORGAN E C 0 N 0 W 0 t V B I 0 P W t N t ORGANISATION DE COOPERATION H DE ECONOMIQUES DECEMBER 1967 OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK - DECEMBER 1967 Corrigendum English version only Chart C on page 13 and Chart F on page 26 should be replaced by the attached revised versions. Page 19: United Kingdom. The second sentence starting at the bottom of the left-hand column should read: "The decline in private productive investment in 1967 now looks like being only about 5 per cent and the latest survey suggested that there might be some recovery in 1968. " CHARTC PRODUCTIVE INVESTMENT IN SELECTED O.E.C.D. COUNTRIES, 1960-70 Projections,estimates,andforecasts (Indexnumbers,1960 =100) 200 180 160 140 100 Japan United Kingdom 240 / /\0% " 240 / 220 - 220 20D - - 200 3fc% ISO - - 180 160 - / / - 140 France // - 120 / / - - / / / / /^ZW " - - 1/ - inn l/\ i i i i i i i 1 1 '60 *B1 '62 '63 '64 '65 '66 '67 '68 '69 70 - - ,x Trendprojectedfor1960-70 Productive investments is composée " " of enterprise investment, including Actual1960-66 governmententerprises and excluding residentialconstruction /// -Forecasts1967-68 Thetrendline forproductive invest¬ mentisan averageoftheactual rate s'X ofchangefrom1960to1965,andthe projections made by governments or theO.EC.D.Secretariatforihe1965-70 periodin"EconomicGrowth. 1960-70, /-I i i i i i i i 1 1 A mid-decade review ofprospects". '60 '61 '62 '63 '64 '65 '66 '67 '68 '69 7D DOMESTIC DEMAND AND TRADE BALANCES United States E.E.C. 2000 Japan Percent United Kingdom 6 - /- *\! V illion - lowpressure \ 1400 - - / 1000 - K N^^ 1965 1966 1967 1968' _ - < 1. Domesticdemand (deviationfromtrend) _ 2.O.E.C.D.demand(deviationfromtrend) wm^a^ÊM^ 3.Relativepressureofdemand(1 2) JL_ i i I -«^"b^m 4.Tradebalance (Smillion,seasonallyadjusted) '* Adjusted for removal or import surcharge 196S 1966 1967 1968 * 19672ndhalfand1968:forecasts ARCHIVES' \ :P"Rt retol: OECD ECONOMIC OUTLOOK 2 DECEMBER 1967 ORGANISATION FOR ECONOMIC CO-OPERATION AND DEVELOPMENT CONTENTS Economic Prospects after the Devaluation of Sterling (General Summary) (cid:9) 3 GENERAL TRENDS IN OECD COUNTRIES Demand and Output (cid:9) 7 Trade Balances (cid:9) 24 Current Invisibles (cid:9) 29 The Current Situation (cid:9) 7 Effects ofthe Suez Canal Closure (cid:9) 29 The Outlook for 1968 (cid:9) 8 The Outlook for Individual Countries (cid:9) 9 Monetary Developments (cid:9) 30 United Kingdom (cid:9) 31 Expansion Versus Price Stability (cid:9) 12 United States (cid:9) 33 United States (cid:9) 14 Japan (cid:9) 35 Canada (cid:9) 16 Canada (cid:9) 36 Italy (cid:9) 36 Japan (cid:9) 17 France (cid:9) 36 Italy (cid:9) 18 France (cid:9) 18 Germany (cid:9) 37 Smaller Industrialised Countries (cid:9) 38 Germany (cid:9) 18 United Kingdom (cid:9) 19 International Capital Movements (cid:9) 39 Banking Funds (cid:9) 39 Trade and Current Invisibles (cid:9) 20 Total Capital Flows (cid:9) 41 OECD Imports (cid:9) 20 Balance of Payments Equilibrium (cid:9) 43 Trade with non-OECD Countries (cid:9) 22 Total OECD Exports (cid:9) 24 The Outlook for 1968 (cid:9) 45 DEVELOPMENTS IN MAJOR COUNTRIES France (cid:9) 47 United States (cid:9) 71 Germany (cid:9) 53 Canada (cid:9) 77 Italy (cid:9) 60 United Kingdom (cid:9) 65 Japan (cid:9) 82 Statistical Annex on New Foreign Bond Issues and New Issues on the Euro-Bond Market 86 Technical Notes (cid:9) 87 CONVENTIONAL SIGNS S US dollar Irrelevant c US cent Decimal point £ Pound sterling I, II Calendar half-years Data not available Q,q Calendar quarters 0 Nil or negligible Billion Thousandmillion ECONOMIC PROSPECTS AFTER THE DEVALUATION OF STERLING General Summary The slowing-down of the growth of activity evident at the beginning of 1967 has come to an end. In the twelve months ahead (second half of 1967 to second half of 1968) the combined GNP of OECD countries seems likely to grow by more than 4\ per cent, as against less than 3 per cent in the previous twelve months. As a result, the value of imports of OECD countries now seems likely to grow by 8 per cent over the same period (as against less than 4 per cent in the previous twelve months). The acceleration of output and trade seems more securely established in North America and Japan than in Europe. The devaluation of sterling on 18th November (14.3 per cent) was followed, among OECD countries, by Denmark (7.9 per cent), Ireland (14.3 per cent), Spain (16.7)*and Iceland (24.6). The United Kingdom accounts for 9 per cent of world imports; other devaluing OECD countries for 4 per cent (and other countries outside the OECD area, which also devalued in the latter part of November, account for a further 4 per cent). The effects which the devaluations and the internal measures taken by the devaluing countries may have on the course of demand in other countries, and on trade and payments patterns, are discussed below. THE DEVALUATION OF STERLING The United Kingdom took the decision to devalue after running deficits on current account during six of the last eight years to which, till recent years, was added a substantial outflow of long-term capital. The Government had sought, since 1964, to correct the imbalance by reducing demand pressures, by attempting to restrain prices and incomes more effectively than in competing countries, and by measures to improve productivity and the structure of the economy. It was realized that such policies would take time to become effective and that, in the interval, external assistance would be required. It became progressive¬ ly clear that the delay and sacrifice would be considerable. After the severe measures of 1966, the balance of payments was slow to respond. By the early summer it was apparent that the restraint of demand would push unemployment above the level regarded as tolerable. It is generally agreed that countries cannot be called on to sustain indefinite periods of stagnant demand in the interest of the balance of payments, and that beyond a point other methods of adjustment are called for.r What is important for the immediate future is that the United Kingdom authorities should ensure that a sufficient margin of unused resources exists to enable exports to expand significantly. While de¬ valuation has shifted the external constraint on expansion, the internal constraint remains; and it may be necessary to restrict expansion to a rate not very much in excess of the 3 per cent a year at which product¬ ive capacity is estimated to be growing. Devaluation has given United Kingdom manufacturers a net cost advantage of the order of 10 per cent. On any normal assumption about the response of trade to cost and price changes, the benefit to the trade account should be substantial, and could, over time, even exceed the Government's target of an improvement of £500 million or $1.2 bil¬ lion. (Excluding purchases of US military aircraft and the impact of the temporary adverse factors, the current account was probably in rough balance in 1967. The devaluation could by 1969therefore lead to a current account surplus of over $ 1 billion.) As the more detailed note on page 65 of this issue suggests, the situation contains dangers for the United Kingdom, as well as opportu¬ nities. The improvement in the current balance might well absorb 2 per cent of GDP over the next twelve months. Unless, therefore, domestic demand is severely restrained, overheating could develop, pushing up incomes and prices and soon cancelling out the competitive advantage obtained by devaluation. Since public expenditure and fixed investment both seem likely to rise, there will be very little room for any incrase of private consumption. It is widely agreed that the res¬ trictive measures taken in November along with devaluation (see page 66) will need to be followed, by the time of the budget, by substantial further measures of restraint if this purpose is to be achieved. The devaluations in Ireland, Denmark and Spain are also being accompanied by certain measures of internal restriction. 1. Thelatest internationalstatementon thesubject, afterobserving that: Countries in deficit should endeavour to keep the rise of incomes within, and if possiblebelow, therateofproductivityincrease. The appropriate means may differ from country to country. In some cases, it may be possible to achieve this by the combined use of incomes policies and steps to encourage the improvement of productivity. If these policies fail to produce the desired result in a reasonable period oftime, it may be appropriate to facilitate the operation of incomes policies by measures which, while preserving reasonable employment levels, are designed to reduce the pressure of demand. goes on to say: It is, however, generally agreed that countries cannot be called on deliberately to sustain prolonged periods of stagnant demand. There may at times be cases where the above policies appear unlikely to restore balance sufficiently quickly, and adjustment of the exchange rate seems appropriate. andadds: It should be stressed, however, that this is only likelytobesuccessfulifthenecessary conditions have been assured beforehand; these include a margin of spare capacity adequate to provide for an expansion of exports, and a readiness on the part of those responsible for price and income determination not to seek to evade their share of the immediate effects ofthe devaluation. See The Balance of Payments Adjustment Process, a report by Working Party No. 3 ofthe Economic Policy Committee ofOECD,paragraph 46, OECD, Paris, August 1966. EFFECTS ON OTHER COUNTRIES Successful devaluation in the United Kingdom and elsewhere will affect the demand situation and the current balance of payments of the countries which have not devalued. The depressive effect on demand of the British devaluation can be measured by the shift in real resources which occurs in the United Kingdom. As noted above, this could be of the order of 2 per cent of United Kingdom GDP over the next twelve months and, if the devaluation were fully successful, could rise to something like $2.5 billion by the middle of 1969. In quantitative terms, this is only a very small fraction of the combined GDP of other OECD countries, which amounted to $ 1,270 billion in 1966, and still small in relation to the annual increase to be expected. But the effects will be unevenly spread and will not be negligible for some countries. As a rough rule of thumb, the volume of exports of other countries exporting mainly manufactured goods might be reduced by 1-1\ per cent below the level which would otherwise have prevailed. The exact amount will vary from country to country according to the import¬ ance of its markets in the United Kingdom, and the extent to which, elsewhere, it competes in the same markets and same product lines as the United Kingdom. This could clearly have a considerable impact on overall demand in countries such as Norway and the Netherlands, where exports of goods and services account for 40-50 per cent of GDP, but will have virtually no impact on the United States, where the corresponding ratio is only 5J per cent. In a number of the smaller industrialised countries in Europe, particularly Norway, Swedan and the Netherlands, compensatory ex¬ pansionary action may, therefore, be called for, if a swing in the United Kingdom's balance of the order envisaged begins to appear. For Germany and France, the position is less clear-cut. Although in both countries there has been some pick-up in domestic demand in recent months, there are certain doubts whether faster expansion will be sustained through 1968. The direct effects of the devaluations should be small. But there might be an indirect adverse impact on business confidence from the unsettled state of international exchange and financial markets; and if this became apparent, present fiscal plans might need to be reassessed. BALANCE OF PAYMENTS EQUILIBRIUM The balance of payments pattern among OECD countries will clearly be substantially affected by the devaluations. But the current balances of the non-devaluing countries will be less affected than are their internal levels of demand, because the devaluations will improve their terms of trade. Thus the effect of the British devaluation the predominant element might be to worsen other countries' current balances by about $ 1%-Ii billion over the next eighteen months. A sum of this magnitude, spread between the other OECD indus¬ trialised countries, would not itself present serious problems. But the incidence is likely to be somewhat uneven; and, in addition, there may be a considerable impact on international capital movements. First, there should be a reflux of the massive outflow of highly volatile funds from London in the months preceding devaluation. Looking further ahead, there should be a progressive strengthening of confidence in sterling which, eventually, could have a pervasive effect on other types of capital movements, in particular direct investment. Taking current and capital transactions together, the devaluation could in time sub¬ stantially reduce other countries' overall surpluses; and could push some countries, at least temporarily, into deficit. If this happened, and if it led many governments to cut back domestic demand to protect their balance of payments, this might be a clear sign perhaps the first of a generalised shortage of world reserves. MONETARY CONSEQUENCES Before the devaluation, the monetary authorities in the United Kingdom were faced with relatively weak domestic demand, but had to resist the pull of rising interest rates in the United States because of the fragile balance of payments. The situation has now radically changed. Monetary restraint is needed to support fiscal policy in keeping the growth of domestic demand within the narrow limits required; and the maintenance of fairly high interest rates will help to build up confidence in the new exchange rate. The authorities will, no doubt, wish to " neutralise " so far as possible, the internal monetary effects of the substantial capital inflows which may now take place, so as to maintain a tight grip on domestic liquidity creation and prevent too rapid a decline of rates (p. 31 below). Thus the United Kingdom, like, the United States, is now a country where relatively high interest rates appear appropriate for both domestic and external reasons. The same considerations in reverse point to the need, in most other countries in Europe, to keep interest rates low, and, notably in the case of long-term rates, to continue efforts to bring them down further. Such an international pattern of interest rates would also seem appropriate from the point of view of maintaining confidence in the international monetary system. This, inevitably, was disturbed by the devaluation of sterling. But granted appropriate policies, a major element of international monetary instability should prove, as an result of the devaluation, to have been removed. The following sections are devoted to an assessment of the outlook for 1968 in the OECD area as a whole, taking into account as far as possible the consequences of the British and other devaluations. A discussion of the benefits obtained from the easing of demand pressures in 1967, and of the cost, will be found on p. 12. A review of the monetary developments which have led to a reversal of the earlier fall in the interest rates is on p. 30. More detailed surveys of develop¬ ments and prospects in the seven major countries are given in pp. 47-85. 2nd December 1967.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.