No-arbitrage macroeconomic determinants of the yield curve Ruslan Bikbov, Mikhail Chernov To cite this version: Ruslan Bikbov, Mikhail Chernov. No-arbitrage macroeconomic determinants of the yield curve. Econometrics, 2010, 159 (1), pp.166. 10.1016/j.jeconom.2010.05.004. hal-00732517 HAL Id: hal-00732517 https://hal.science/hal-00732517 Submitted on 15 Sep 2012 HAL is a multi-disciplinary open access L’archive ouverte pluridisciplinaire HAL, est archive for the deposit and dissemination of sci- destinée au dépôt et à la diffusion de documents entific research documents, whether they are pub- scientifiques de niveau recherche, publiés ou non, lished or not. The documents may come from émanant des établissements d’enseignement et de teaching and research institutions in France or recherche français ou étrangers, des laboratoires abroad, or from public or private research centers. publics ou privés. Accepted Manuscript No-arbitragemacroeconomicdeterminantsoftheyieldcurve RuslanBikbov,MikhailChernov PII: S0304-4076(10)00129-6 DOI: 10.1016/j.jeconom.2010.05.004 Reference: ECONOM3382 Toappearin: JournalofEconometrics Receiveddate: 29October2008 Reviseddate: 8October2009 Accepteddate: 24May2010 Pleasecitethisarticleas: Bikbov,R.,Chernov,M.,No-arbitragemacroeconomicdeterminants oftheyieldcurve. JournalofEconometrics(2010),doi:10.1016/j.jeconom.2010.05.004 This is a PDF file of an unedited manuscript that has been accepted for publication. As a servicetoourcustomersweareprovidingthisearlyversionofthemanuscript. Themanuscript willundergocopyediting,typesetting,andreviewoftheresultingproofbeforeitispublishedin its final form. Please note that during the production process errors may be discovered which couldaffectthecontent,andalllegaldisclaimersthatapplytothejournalpertain. ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT T No-Arbitrage Macroeconomic Determinants of P the Yield Curve I R C ∗ Ruslan Bikbova, Mikhail Chernovb, , S U aFederal Reserve Board, Washington, DC 20551, USA bLondon Business School, London School of Economics, and CEPR, London, N NW1 4SA, UK A M Abstract D No-arbitrage macro-finance models use variance decompositions to gauge the ex- tent of association between the macro variables and yields. We show that results E generated by this approach are sensitive to the order of variables in the recursive identificationscheme.Inafour-factormodel,onemayobtain18differentsetsofan- T swers out of 24 possible. We propose an alternative measure that is based on levels ofmacrovariablesasopposPedtoshocks.Weaccountforthecorrelationbetweenthe macro and latent factors via projection of the latter onto the former. As a result, E the association between macro variables and yields can be computed uniquely via an R2. Macro variables explain 80% of the variation in the short rate and 50% of C the slope, and 54% to 68% of the term premia. JEL Classification: C13; C22; G12 C Keywords: macro-finance models; term structure; variance decomposition; Kalman filter A ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT T 1 Introduction P The important work of Ang and Piazzesi (2003) extends the traditional no-arbitrage term I structure modelsbymodellingjointlythedynamics ofyields andnonfinancialvariables. The R nonfinancial variables chosen by researchers are typically macro variables, so we refer to the models as no-arbitrage macro-finance models. One of the most important issues that the C setting allows researchers to address is whether yields are associated with macro variables. This issue could be broken down further. First, is the associaStion between yields and macro variables determined by the monetary policy? There is a strong intuition from the Taylor U rule literature that suggests that such macro variables as inflation and real activity should matter for the interest rate, which is the monetary policy instrument.1 Second, is the as- N sociation between yields and macro variables determined by the yield risk premia? It could be that macro variables affect the yields exclusively through the spot interest rate. Finally, A regardless of the channel, how large is this association quantitatively? A precise answer to these questions will provide a quantitative bMenchmark for equilibrium models. If structural implications of these models are to be taken seriously, they should be able to generate, at the very least, the same common variation in yields and macro variables as the benchmark. D ⋆ We are grateful to the Editor, Ron Gallant, the Associate Editor and the Referee for invaluable comments that helped us to imprEove the paper. We thank Andrew Ang, Geert Bekaert, Alan Bester, Jean Boivin, Larry Christiano, Pierre Collin-Dufresne, Greg Duffee, Silverio Foresi, Mike Gallmeyer, Rene Garcia, Marc Giannoni, Francisco Gomes, Mike Johannes, Lars Lochstoer, Stijn T VanNieuwerburgh,TarunRamadorai,AndreaRoncoroni,TanoSantos,SureshSundaresan,Andrea TambalottiandparticipantsofworkshopsatColumbia,BankofCanada,theFederalReserveBank ofAtlanta, andAFAinBoPston,CIREQ-CIRANOFinancialEconometricsConferenceinMontreal, the CEPRmeetings at Gerzensee, Econometric World Congressin London,EFA in Moscow, NYU SternFive-Star Conference, andseminarsat Chicago GSB,Duke, theEuropeanCentralBank, the E FederalReserveBoard,theFederalReserveBankofNewYork,GoldmanSachsAssetManagement, ImperialCollege,JPMorgan,LBS,LSE,NYU,PrincetonandRice.Chernovacknowledgessupport of the JP Morgan Chase Academic Outreach program. C ∗ Correspondingauthor.LondonBusinessSchool, SussexPlace, London,NW1 4SA, UnitedKing- dom. Tel.: +44 20 7000 8258 Email addresses: [email protected](RuslanBikbov),[email protected](Mikhail Cher- C nov). 1 However, thedegreeofassociation isnotobvious. Infact, interest raterulesand,therefore,their ingredienAts, do not matter at all in the absence of frictions, such as price stickiness (e.g., Bils and Klenow, 2004 and Woodford, 2003). 1 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT T The answers to these questions that are found in the literature are mixed. On the one hand, as is well-known from the term-structure studies using financial variables only, such P as Litterman and Scheinkman (1991) or Dai and Singleton (2000), two or three factors are sufficient forcapturing 95%-98%ofthevariationin theyield curve. ThisIconclusion suggests R a small role for macro variables in a empirically realistic term structure model. On the other hand, because the macro-finance models can be cast in a vector autoregression (VAR) C framework, it is natural to quantify the common variation in yields and macro variables via variance decomposition. Studies that follow this route attribute a large fraction (40% to S 80%) of the unconditional variance in yields to the joint contribution of real activity and inflation, which suggests that macro determinants are veUry important.2 Thereasonthatthetwostrandsoftheterm-structureliteratureproduceseeminglyconflicting N resultsisthattheVARliteratureusesshocks tomacrovariablestoexplainvariationinyields, while the work based only on financial data focuAses on the levels of variables to explain the same variation. It should be possible to reconcile the two approaches because levels are M aggregates of shocks. In this paper, we propose a general procedure that allows us to obtain a correct measurement of the association between yields and macro variables. A simple example illustrates how sucDh a reconciliation can be achieved. Consider the Ang andPiazzesi (2003)model, where macro variablesareindependent from thelatent variables. E The infinite horizon variance decompositions from the VAR representation of the model characterize how much of the unconditional yield variance can be attributed to shocks in T each of the macro variables. Our main interest is in disentangling the contribution of the macro and latent variablPes, rather than in disentangling every single variable. Therefore, we can exploit theindependence ofthe two types ofvariables(macro andlatent) anddetermine E the proportion of the yield variance that can be explained by macro variables simply by computing the corresponding R2. C The two approaches will yield the same result under two important conditions. First, the C shocks have to be identified correctly. Researchers often employ the recursive identification 2 For exAample, Ang et al. (2004), Ang and Piazzesi (2003), Dai and Philippon(2004), Rudebusch and Wu (2005), among others. 2 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT T scheme in the context of reduced-form VARs, such as macro-finance models. There is no guarantee that a particular order of variables will produce the correct identification; hence, P it is possible for there to be multiple sets of measures. Second, the VAR has to provide a good fit to the data, in that the variance of yields in the data and in tIhe model should be R similar. This is because the computation of variance decomposition does not involve actual data. In contrast, an R2 measures how much of the actual variance is explained by a model. C The coefficient of determination, R2, appears to be a more robust measure because it relies S on observed macro variables as opposed to unobserved shocks and, therefore, is not subject toassumptionsaboutidentification.WeemphasizethatR2 willnotonlybeauniquemeasure U ofassociationbetween macrovariablesandyields; itwillalsobeacorrectmeasure.However, this measure cannot be implemented if macro and laNtent variables are correlated with each other. This would be the case if, forexample, there is feedback from the financial sector into A the real economy. M We resolve this problem by exploiting the special nature of latent variables. Latent variables do not have any macro interpretation. As Dai and Singleton (2000) point out, these factors can be re-parameterized, or rotated, in a number of different ways without changing the D value of yields. Thus, latent factors serve no purpose other than to fit the data well. These observations lead us to propose a novel procedure that allows to express the traditional E latent factors via macro variables and new “residual” latent variables that are conditionally orthogonal to the macro oneTs. As a result, we disentangle the contribution of the macro and the new latent variables to the variation of yields. Now we can implement the R2 that we P advocated above. E Thekeytoourprocedureisaconditionalmodel-basedprojectionofthelatentvariablesonto themacroones.TCheprojectioneffectivelybreaksthelatentfactorsdowninto(i)acomponent thatconsistsofthecurrentandpastmacrovariables,and(ii)new“projectionresidual”latent C variables that are conditionally orthogonalto the entire history of macroeconomic variables. By construction, the variance of the new latent factors is minimized and the variance of the A macro component is maximized. The spot interest rate becomes a linear function of macro 3 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT T variables, their lags, and a set of new latent factors.3 P Theempiricalimplementationofourprocedureisbasedonafour-factorGaussianmodelwith twolatentfactorsandinflationandrealactivityactingasobservablefactors.Toestimatethe I model, we use a panel of eight yields ranging from three months to 1R0 years, with inflation andrealactivityobserved atamonthlyfrequencyfrom1970to2002.Weprovide diagnostics that indicate that the model fits the data reasonably well. C We document that the variance decomposition results are extremely sensitive to the order S of the model factors chosen for the recursive identification. For example, the fraction of the interest rate variance that is explained by the joint shockUs to inflation and real activity can vary between 36% and 77% depending on the assumed order of the factors. Similarly, the N fraction of the explained slope variance varies between 25% and 81%.4 In particular, the standardorderofthevariables,thatis,macrovariablesfollowedbylatentvariables,produces A 52%fortheshortinterestrateand37%fortheslope.Ourprocedureproducesauniquesetof explained variances precisely because it is bMased on observed macro variables. In particular, 80%ofthevariationintheinterestrateand52%ofthevariationintheslopecanbeexplained byinflationandrealactivity.Asimilarsetoffigures(76%and59%,respectively) isobtained via the variance decomposition if theDorder ofthe variables is real activity followed by latent variables, which are in turn followed by inflation. Clearly, there is no way of knowing this E “correct” order of shocks in the context of a reduced-from model. T The point that variance decomposition results are sensitive to the order of variables in the recursive identification scheme is not new in itself. Nevertheless, given the popularity of P the identification scheme in the macro-finance literature on the term structure, it is worth revisiting. The uncovEered magnitudes of disagreement between the variance decompositions based on different orders of variables seem to warrant a consideration of an alternative C approach. To be sure, our projection-based procedure is nota silver bullet. It cannot replace 3 Ourlagstructureisnotarbitrary:recursiveprojectionformulasimplyrelianceonalllagsandthe C loadings on these lags are optimal, due to the fact that they are selected to minimize the variance of the residuals. 4 We meAasure the slope of the yield curve as the difference between the 10-year and three-month yields. 4 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT T variance decompositions because it can only workin the presence oflatent variables and has no causal implications. We view our procedure as a useful complement to the toolkit of a P researcher studying VARs that are related to the yield curve. I We further illustrate the usefulness of our procedure by using it to adRdress the issues raised at the beginning of the introduction.5 First, we investigate how much of the short rate variation can be explained by the two macro variables, as opposeCd to by the latent factors. It seems natural to start with the null hypothesis that macro variables do not contribute to S explaining the short rate, given the excellent explanatory power of latent factor models that we discussed earlier. As we show, this hypothesis places restrictions on various parameters U that control the dynamics and cross-section ofthe yield curve. A number of previous studies have simplyimposed these restrictions, therebylimitingtheabilityofyields tovarywith the N macroeconomy. We test these restrictions in terms ofthe size ofR2 thatcan be explained by macro variables and confirm that macro variableAs are extremely important. Our projection- basedapproachcanexplain 80%oftheshortratevariation,usinginflation,realactivity, and M their lags exclusively as the basis. Second,we investigate whether macroeconomicvariablesareuseful forexplainingbondterm premia and not just short-term intereDst rates.6 Our approach enables us to determine that inflation and real activity risk premia are both significant factors, which jointly explain 54% E to 68% of the variation in the term premia, depending on a bond’s maturity. In the context of time-series analysis, the contribution of inflation is countercyclical. It is also the most T important contributor with respect to the magnitude and volatility of term premia. P Third, we focusonthe nature ofthe residual latent variables. In order togauge the relation- ship between additioEnal macro variables and our latent factors, we correlate them with two measures of liquidity (AAA credit spread and the growth rate of the money zero maturity C 5 More recent works by Chernovand Mueller (2008) andMueller (2008) provide furtherexamples of applications of our methodology. C 6 In fact, there is currently a debate in the literature over this point. Ang et al. (2004) and Ludvigson and Ng (2009) find that inflation and real activity measures play an important role in explaininAg bond risk premia. In contrast, Duffee (2007) concludes that macro variables make a minimal contribution to the term premia. 5 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT T (MZM), which is a measure of money supply) and a measure of the budget deficit (public government debt growth). The correlations are strong, but not overwhelming. We therefore P conclude that it is more appropriate to use latent variables to model shocks. The shock as- sociated with liquidity measures contributes to the variation in short Iinterest rate, almost R completelyaccountingforthepartleftunexplained bythemacrovariables.Weinterpretthis factorasanexogenous policyshock, that is, occasional reactionsofthe short interest rateto C information beyond that contained in real activity and inflation. The shocks correlated with the budget deficit make the largest contribution to that portion of the slope variation that S is left unexplained by macro variables. We interpret this factor as an exogenous non-policy shock. U Clearly, our paper is related to the growing literatuNre on macro-finance yield curve mod- elling.7 Our work, while having a different focus, is particularly close to the concurrent study by Ang et al. (2004) (ADP henceforth).AADP use a macro-finance model to show that one and the same interest rule can be interpreted in three distinct ways. Given that it M is based on additional assumptions such as the forecasting horizon and whether exogenous shocks depend on current or past innovations in the state variables, the interest rule can be seen as either simple, forward-looking, or backward-looking. Their approach applies to a D modelwithonlyonelatentfactor.Intheirempiricalwork,ADPusevariancedecompositions to gauge the degree of associatioEn between the macro variables and yields. Our projection- based approach implies a backward-looking interest rate rule and so appears to be similar T to their work. However, there are important differences in the focus and approach. First, our procedure applies regardless of the number of latent factors in the model. Second, we P do not focus on the interest rate rules per se, precisely because structural interpretation requiresadditionalasEsumptions. Third, regardlessoftheassumed interest raterule,variance decompositions will be the same and our focus is on providing a robust alternative to such C a computation. C 7 ThisliteratureincludesAngandPiazzesi(2003),Bekaertetal.(2010),DaiandPhilippon(2004), Duffee (2A006), Diebold et al. (2006), Gallmeyer et al. (2005), Ho¨rdahl et al. (2006), Law (2004), Rudebusch and Wu (2005), among others. 6 ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT T The remainder of this paper is organized into five sections and two appendixes. Section 2 summarizes the macro-finance framework. Section 3 motivates and describes the proposed P methodology. Section 4 discusses the estimation strategy. Section 5 presents our findings. The final section concludes. Technical details are presented in the appeIndices. R C S 2 The Model U N 2.1 State variables A FollowingAngandPiazzesi(2003)(APhencMeforth),weassumethatthestateoftheeconomy is captured by the vector z =(m′,x′)′. In particular, the vector of macroeconomic variables t t t m is equal to (g ,π )′, where g and π are monthly real activity and the inflation rate, t t t t t D respectively. The remaining factors x are latent. The latent factors may contain the lags t of m , other macro variables, or other unknown variables. Importantly, the vector z fully t t E reflects all available information at time t; so, for instance, one need not consider lags of x . t T We assume that the state vector z follows a VAR(1) process: t P z =µ+Φz +EΣǫ t t−1 t µm CΦmm Φmxmt−1 Σmm Σmxǫmt = + + , (1) µx Φxm Φxx x Σxm Σxx ǫx t−1 t C where ǫ ∼ N(0,I). We denote the vector of parameters that control the dynamics of state t A by Θ=(µ,Φ,Σ). The block representation will be useful for later discussions. 7
Description: