ebook img

Models of Economic Dynamics: Proceedings of a Workshop held at the IMA, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, USA, October 24–28, 1983 PDF

219 Pages·1986·5.456 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Models of Economic Dynamics: Proceedings of a Workshop held at the IMA, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, USA, October 24–28, 1983

Lecture Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems Managing Editors: M. Beckmann and W. Krelle Subseries: Institute for Mathematics and its Applications, Minneapolis Advisers: H. Weinberger and G.R. Sell 264 Models of Economic Dynamics Proceedings of a Workshop held at the IMA, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, USA October 24-28, 1983 Edited by Hugo F. Sonnenschein Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg New York Tokyo Editorial Board H. Albach M. Beckmann (Managing Editor) P. Ohrymes G. Fandel J. Green W Hildenbrand W Krelle (Managing Editor) H.P. KQnzi G.L. Nemhauser K. Ritter R. Sato U. Schittko P. SchOnfeld R. Selten Managing Editors Prof. Dr. M. Beckmann Brown University Providence, RI 02912, USA Prof. Dr. W. Krelle Institut fOr Gesellschafts-und Wirtschaftswissenschaften der Universitat Bonn Adenauerallee 24-42, 0-5300 Bonn, FRG Editor Prof. Hugo F. Sonnenschein Department of Economics, Princeton University Princeton, NJ 08544, USA ISBN 978-3-540-16098-4 ISBN 978-3-642-51645-0 (eBook) DOI 10.10071978-3-642-51645-0 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically those of translation, reprinting, re-use of illustrations, broadcasting, reproduction by photocopying machine or similar means, and storage in data banks. Under § 54 of the German Copyright Law where copies are made for other than private use, a fee is payable to 'Verwertungsgesellschaft Wort", Munich. © by Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1986 214213140-543210 INSTITUTE FOR MATHEMATICS AND ITS APPLICATIONS PUBLICATIONS CORRENT VOLUMES: The MatheMatics and Physics of Disordered Media Editors: Barry Hughes and Barry Ninham (Springer-Verlag, Lecture Notes in Mathematics, Volume 1035) Orienting Polymers Editor: J.L. Ericksen (Springer-Verlag, Lecture Notes in Mathematics, Volume 1063) New Perspecti,es in Thermodynamics Editor: James Serrin (Springer-Verlag, in press) Models of Economic Dynamics Editor: Hugo Sonnenschein (Springer-Verlag, Lecture Notes in Economics, this volume) FORTHCOMING VOLUMES: Homogenization and Effective Moduli of Materials and Media Liquid Crystals and Liquid Crystal Polymers Amorphous Polymers and Non-Newtonian Fluids Oscillation Theory, Computation, and Methods of Compensated Compactness Metastability and Incompletely Posed Problems Dynamical Problems in Continuum Physics * * * * * * * * * * The INSTITUTE FOR MATHEMATICS AND ITS APPLICATIONS was established by a grant from the National Science Foundation to the University of Minnesota in 1982. The IMA seeks to encourage the development and study of fresh mathematical concepts and questions of concern to the other sciences by bringing together mathematicians and scientists from diverse fields in an atmosphere that will stimulate discussion and collaboration. Hans Weinberger, Director George R. Sell, Associate Director * * * * * * * * * * YEARLY PROGRAMS 1982-1983 STATISTICAL AND CONTINUUM APPROACHES TO PHASE TRANSITION 1983-1984 MATHEMATICAL MODELS FOR THE ECONOMICS OF DECENTRALIZED RESOURCE ALLOCATION 1984-1985 CONTINUUM PHYSICS AND PARTIAL DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS 1985-1986 STOCHASTIC DIFFERENTIAL EQUATIONS AND THEIR APPLICATIONS 1986-1987 SCIENTIFIC COMPUTATION 1987-1988 APPLIED COMBINATORICS PREFACE During the week of October 24-28, 1983, a group of mathematicians and eco nomists met at the Institute for Mathematics and it Applications at the University of Minnesota. The workshop dealt with economic models in which time plays an essential role, and both the description of adjustment to a static equilibrium and the description of equilibrium paths were considered. From a mathematical point of view, discrete dynamical systems and the dynamics of ordi nary and partial differential equations played a major role. The conference consisted of lectures by economists and by mathematicians which treated some of the principal ideas of economic dynamics. Donald Saari pro vided some discrete dynamical systems background for a paper by Jean-Michel Grandmont on business cycles; the Grandmont paper was a major focus of the Workshop. Daniel Goroff, Jose Scheinkman, Christopher Sims. Neil Wallace. and Michael Woodford discussed the Grandmont paper after its presentation. The ideas of tatonnement were introduced by Leonid Hurwicz and extended by Andreu MasColell and H. Jerome Keisler. Four papers on economic dynamics follow (W.A. Brock, Truman Bewley. W.A. Brock and M. Rothschild and Yieh-Hei Wan). The remaining papers are devoted to issues of quantity and/or price adjustment (William Novshek and Hugo Sonnenschein. Phillipe Artzner. Carl Simon and Hugo Sonnenschein). equilibrium with a continuum of commodities (Larry Jones), and the adjustment of expectations (Lawrence Blume and James Jordan). A distinctive feature of the Workshop was the substantial interaction between mathematicians and economists. many of whom had not been previously exposed to the ideas that were presented. This volume is intended to introduce a wider audience to the contents of these lectures and to stimulate further dialogue between econo mists and mathematicians. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS The organizers of the Workshop thank Debbie Bradley and Kaye Smith for their careful typing of this volume. TABLE OF CONTENTS Dynamical Systems and Mathematical Economics 1 Donald G. Saari On Endogenous Competitive Business Cycles 25 Jean-Michel Grandmont COlll11entaries on the Grandmont Paper "Endogenous Competitive Business Cycles" 35 Daniel Goroff •••• 35 Jose A. Scheinkman 36 Christopher Sims 37 Neil Wa 11 ace 40 Michael Woodford 41 On the Stability of the Tatonnement Approach to Competitive Equilibrium 45 Leon i d Hu rwi cz Notes on Price and Quantity Tatonnement Dynamics •• 49 Andreu Mas-Colell A Price Adjustment Model with Infinitesimal Traders 69 H. Jerome Keisler A Revised Version of Samuelson's Correspondence Principle: Applications of Recent Results on the Asymptotic Stability of Optimal Control to the Problem of Comparing Long-Run Equilibrium 86 W.A. Brock Dynamic Implications of the Form of the Budget Constraint 117 Truman F. Bewley Comparative Statics for Multidimensional Optimal Stopping Problems 124 W.A. Brock and M. Rothschild The Cournot Problem with Bounded Memory Strategies •••• 139 Yieh-Hei Wan Quantity Adjustment in an Arrow-Debreu-McKenzie Type Model 148 William Novshek and Hugo Sonnenschein Convergence of Myopic Firms to Long-Run Equilibrium via the Method of Characteristics ••••••••••••••••••••••••• 157 Philippe Artzner, Carl P. Simon, and Hugo Sonnenschein Special Problems Arising in the Study of Economies with Infinitely Many Convnodi t ; es •••••• • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • 184 Larry E. Jones Introduction to Expectations Equilibrium. • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • • •• 206 Lawrence Blume and James Jordan DYNAMICAL SYSTEMS AND MATHEMATICAL ECONOMICS Donald G. Saari Department of Mathematics Northwestern University Evanston, Illinois 60201 1. INTRODUCTION The modern mathematical economics literature is permeated with dynamics. This starts with a simple tatonnement story of how prices adjust according to supply and demand, and it continues with the more sophisticated price adjustment models which involve speculation, etc. Dynamics arise from the Euler, or the Bellman equations, to define the optimal paths in growth models, as well as in other optimization problems. Arguments based upon dynamics are advanced to justify various forms of equilibria; here we find issues such as the accessihility of pareto points or the comparison of different bargaining solution concepts. In recent years, as manifested by several of the papers presented at this conference, dynamics has been used to explain non-stationary behavior such as business cycles. It became clear in the 1970's that mathematical economics is blessed with almost an overly rich supply of dynamical systems. This is the period when the work initiated by H. Sonnenschein and advanced by Mantel, Debreu, and ~as Colell culminated in the conclusion that just about any differential equation, or vector field on the price simplex, can be viewed as being the aggregate excess demand function for some economy. (A good reference would be the expository paper hy Shafer and Sonnenschein (1].) Other topics from mathematical economics also admit a wealth of dynamical systems with the accompanying varying behavior of the solu- tions. For example, in optimal growth models or overlapping generations models, a large class of systems can be generated by altering the production sets, the uti lity functions, and the discount rates. In what follow, I will indicate how these simple changes can lead to all sorts of unexpected orbit behavior. Because the modelling admits an abundance of dynamical systems, mathematical economics can benefit from most advances in Dynamical Systems. Consequently, it is fortunate for economics that during this same period of the late 60's and the 2 70's, mathematicians made significant advances in the geometric study of these systems. Part of the earlier intuition concerning solutions resulted from the behavior of dynamical systems in the plane. Here, under some general conditions (known as the Poincare - Bendixson Theorem), it is known that all bounded solu tions asymptotically approach either a fixed point or a periodic orbit. But it has been known for some time that the solution behavior isn't as nicely described in a higher dimensional space. Important progress has been made'on the difficult problem of describing the "general" or "generic" behavior of solutions: an earlier exposition of this is in [2J while a more recent one is [3J. We now know that the flexibility acquired by increasing the dimension of the phase space from two to three admits orbits which only a decade ago would have been viewed as being pathological. For example, it is natural to think of a periodic orbit as being a distortion of a simple loop. However, in a three dimen sional space, there are periodic orbits for differential equations which define almost any conceivable knot one can tie. That is, tie a piece of string into a complicated knot. Once this is done, attach the loose ends of the string together. It turns out that there are differential equations where a periodic orbit ties this knot! (An excellent, recent paper by Franks and Williams [4J shows that an infinite number of different knots occur in a system which satisfy a certain "topological entropy" condition.) Furthermore, we are learning that the limiting sets of orbits can assume complicated and strange structures: such sets are descri bed by the now standard term "strange attractors". Although this orbit behavior may seem to be bizarre, it can occur in models from economics! For example, as soon as four commodities are admitted into an economy, the tatonnement story is modelled by a dynamic ina three dimensional price simplex. The Sonnenschein result asserts that the defining system can be quite arbitrary, so all of the above orbit behavior is admitted. Thus, the story of the auctioneer admits some knotty consequences. It is natural to question whether this unusual orbit behavior can be dismissed on the grounds that it only occurs either in isolated, or in complicated examples. This is not the case. For example, in the 60's Lorenz introduced the 3 following differential equation as a model for turbulence. x' a o x y' b -1 o y z' o o -c z Here, a, b, and c are positive constants where the original values are a=10, b=28, and c=8/3. The linear part of this equation can be studied with a standard eigenvalue analysis. Because the equation is only a quadratic system, it might appear that the full system shouldn't be unduly difficult to analyze. The fact is, in spite of the efforts of several very good mathematicians, this equation is yet to be completely understood. It is known that this quadratic equation, admits solutions such as the knotty periodic orbits described above, and that there are other, more complicated trajectories. (A recent book by Guckenheimer and Holmes [5] discusses this system in great detail.) The important point, which is why this example is introduced here, is that although ~ nonlinear system Y2.. elementary ~ form, 2! can admit ~ very complicated orbit structure! (For an example of a simple, nonlinear, second order scalar equation with a periodic forcing function which has complicated solutions, I refer you to Mark levi's seminal work on the van der Pol equation [6].) When the modelling of an economic setting involves discrete units of time, the analysis yields an iterative, discrete dynamic. (Indeed, often the intended mOdel is a discrete one, but a continuous model is used to approximate and to simplify the analysis; e.g., a differential equation is the limiting case of the desired iterative system.) Since discrete, iterative dynamics playa vital role in economics, it is important to determine whether their orbit structures can be as complicated as above. They can, and these complexities already appear in one dimensional systems! In this paper, I will provide an elementary introduction to selective aspects of this area. The explanation of the causes for "chaos" in discrete dynamics are easier if only because they occur for one-dimensional systems. This permits the 4 ideas to be described in terms of graphs of functions. For this reason, this is the topic I'll emphasize. But, because Dynamical Systems is such an exciting and rapidly growing field of mathematics, any introduction cannot be complete. So, my approach is to present those ideas which I suspect are of immediate interest and applications to mathematical economics. My emphasis will be to indicate why cer tain types of orbit behavior occur, and to describe the identifying features of the defining system. These properties will be illustrated by suggesting how this relates to models in economics such as cycles in growth problems and price dyna mics. (The details for some of these models will be given elsewhere.) A selection of the appropriate references for the mathematics will be cited for the reader interested in more detailed information. 2. DISCRETE DYNAMICS AND THE TATONNEMENT PROCEDURE In this section, I will discuss a simple dynamical system represented by a mapping G from an interval I back into itself. To be specific, suppose the graph of G is given in Figure 1 where the iterative dynamic is given by (2.1) / Figure 1 / 5 Geometrically, this can be described in the following way. The value of xN+l = G(XN) ,which is found from the graph of Gover xN' provides the next value for x. To determine the location of xN+1 on the x-axis, move horizon tally from the graph of G until you reach the diagonal y=x, then move ver- tically to the x-axis. The next iterate, xN+2' is given by the value on the graph of G over this point. An equivalent description of this iteration, which omits the vertical projection, is to move horizontally from the graph of G to the line y=x and then move vertically to the graph of G. The process is con tinued, and it is depicted by the directed lines in the figure. It is obvious from the above that the intersection of the graph of G with the diagonal y=x determines a fixed point p of the map; G(p)=p. By use of the mean value theorem, it is an elementary exercise to show that a fixed point is stable at x=p if IG'(p)1 < 1 and unstable if IG'(p)1 > 1. This is because IxN+1-pl = IG(xN) - G(p)1 = IG'(c)llxN-pl for some c between xN and p. Thus if IG'(p) I < I, then once an iterate xN is sufficiently close to p, all future iterates are closer. If IG'(p) I > I, then the future iterates are pushed away from p. These conditions are the basis for the usual analysis of fixed points in mathematical economics. This system admits much more interesting activity than that captured by an equilibrium analysis; for instance, it admits a highly random, orbit behavior in the three regions labelled A, B, and C. More specifically, select a region in which you wish the initial point to be, say region C. Next, specify the interval in which you wish the first iterate to land, say A. Continuing in this fashion, a sequence of intervals is specified, say (C,A,A,B, ••• ), where the (N+l)th term in the sequence identifies the interval in which you wish the Nth iterate to be. What I will show is that for any specified sequence, there exist points for which their trajectories have this future! In other words, for any random defined future, there are orbits of this deterministic system which will obey it. To show this, all of the points which satisfy a finite portion of this future will be found. Let C(C,A) be the set of points in interval C which are mapped to the closed interval A. The crucial factor in describing this set

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.