ebook img

MERGERS, STANDARD OF PROOF AND EXPERT - ACLE PDF

30 Pages·2006·0.18 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview MERGERS, STANDARD OF PROOF AND EXPERT - ACLE

JournalofCompetitionLawandEconomics2(1),71–100 doi:10.1093/joclec/nhi027 AdvanceAccesspublicationdateFebruary2,2006 MERGERS, STANDARD OF PROOF AND EXPERT ECONOMIC EVIDENCE Yves Botteman(cid:1) ABSTRACT D There is an increasing use of complex econometric modelling in EC merger o w controlproceedings.Thequestioniswhethereconometricsaresubjecttoastan- nlo dard of evidence similar to that applicable to facts and theories that the ad e CwhoemthmeirsstihoenretsrhadoiutilodnbaellysoumseesmaanrgdinaorfticduislacrteestioinnleifttstomtehrgeeCrodmemcisisiosinosnoinr d from the treatment and handling of econometric evidence. In the former case, EC h ttp coofuecrtosnwomoueltdriecxeevritdaenncien.teInnstihveelraetvteierwcaosfe,thEeCCcoomurmtsiswsoiounld’saudsoepatnadraarthtiecrudlaetfieorn- ://jcle entialapproach.WhiletheissuehasnotyetbeendealtwithbeforeECcourts,this .o x articlesubmitsthattheCommissionshoulduseeconometricswithcautionand, ford hence,should meetarelativelyhigh evidentiary threshold beforeadmittingthe jo u results of econometric models into evidence. Several guiding principles of evi- rn a dence are suggested, which are not intended to negate the Commission’s ls.o margin of discretion, but would, nevertheless, ensure that econometrics be rg subjecttoafairlyhighstandardofproof. at U/ n iv e rs ite I. INTRODUCTION it v a n It is now standard practice for economic experts from the European A m Commission (DGCOMP), the notifying parties and third parties to partici- ste pateactivelyinshapingthewaymergersshouldbeassessed.Asrecenthorizon- rda m tal noncoordinated effects merger cases illustrate,1 economics has taken an o n increasingly greater role in the assessment of mergers under the EC merger N o control system.2 Economists sponsor seminars, workshops and conferences ve m to raise awareness among antitrust lawyers and the business community be r 2 2 (cid:1) SeniorAssociate,Linklaters,Brussels.Email:[email protected] , 20 1 liketothankBernardvandeWalledeGhelckeandDavidBaileyfortheirvaluablecomments.All 3 errorsandomissionsare,ofcourse,hisown.TheauthoractedforPeopleSoftintheECaspects oftheOracle/PeopleSoftmerger.ThisarticlewascompletedinlateJune2005andisbasedonEC caselawavailableatthattime. 1 SeeCaseCOMP/M.3083—GE/Instrumentarium,Commissiondecisionof2September2003; CaseCOMP/M.3216—Oracle/PeopleSoft,Commissiondecisionof26October2004. 2 SeepublicationsponsoredbytheCommission,“TechnicalReport—EffectsofMergersInvolving DifferentiatedProducts,”COMP/B-1/2003/07,7October2004,http://europa.eu.int/comm/ competition/mergers/others/effects_mergers_involving_differentiated_products.pdf(visitedon 5July2005). #TheAuthor(2006).PublishedbyOxfordUniversityPress.Allrightsreserved. ForPermissions,pleaseemail:[email protected] 72 JournalofCompetitionLawandEconomics aboutthevariouseconomictoolsavailable,including regressionanalysesand bidandmergersimulationmodels.3Thoseinstrumentshavenotyetbeenfully tested in actual cases and their use is sometimes subject to cautions and controversy.4 It is nevertheless appropriate to identify what role economic models can play in the discharge by DGCOMPof its burden to prove that a merger will significantly impede competition in a substantial part of the CommonMarket.5 Inanattempttocontributetoandcomplementthedebateonthisissue,this article starts with an overview of the various methodological and evidentiary stepsthatDGCOMPhastogothroughincarryingoutmergerreviewsgenerally. D Thecollectionofrelevantevidenceisatthecoreofitstasks,butasthisintroduc- o w toryoverviewshows,thestandardofproofapplyingtomergercasesisill-defined nlo a despite efforts made by the CFI in the Airtours, Schneider/Legrand, and Tetra de d Laval/Sideltrilogy.Adiscussionthenfollowsonthestandard(s)ofreviewthat fro m Community courts have applied in the past, with a particular focus on the h long-awaited ruling from the Court of Justice in the Commission’s appeal of ttp theTetraLaval/Sideljudgment.6Practicalimplicationsaredrawnfromthosedis- ://jc le cussionsbeforeweenterintothedebateastowhatrolesandcontributionsecon- .o x omic models can have in the evidentiary threshold that must be met before ford DGCOMP can satisfy itself that its opinion regarding the compatibility of a jou rn mergerissupportedbya“cogentandconsistent”bodyofevidence. a ls This contribution identifies a paradox. While the review exerted by the .o rg Community judicature might admittedly be less intensive when the a/ Commissioncarriesouteconomicassessmentsonthebasisofthefactualevi- t Un iv dence contained in the file, the proposition whereby the Commission should e rs clear a transaction whenever it is confronted by “grey area” cases7 may be ite it v a n 3 IBCconferencesheldinLondonon11–12March2004andinBrusselson27–28January2005 A m entitled“TheUseofEconomicsinCompetitionLaw”. s 4 RBBBrief12,“Theemperor’snewclothes?Theroleofmergersimulationmodels,”January terd a 2004;BenDubow,DavidElliott&EricMorrison,“Unilateraleffectsandmergersimulation m models,”25(2)ECLR114(2004);GregoryWerden,LukeFroeb&DavidT.Scheffman,“A on Daubert discipline for merger simulation,” Draft of 16 February 2004 (on file with the N o author);David Scheffman&Mary Coleman, “Quantitativeanalysesof potentialcompetitive ve m effectsfromamerger,”9June2003;MarcIvaldi&FrankVerboven,“Quantifyingtheeffects b e fromhorizontalmergersineuropeancompetitionpolicy”,Int’lJ.ofIndus.Org.(vol23,n.9, r 2 December2005,pp.669–691);andRoyJ.Epstein&DanielL.Rubinfeld,“Mergersimulation, 2, 2 asimplifiedapproachwithnewapplications,”69AntitrustL.J.883(2004). 0 1 5 Thisquestioniscloselyassociatedwiththeyetunresolvedissueofthestandardofproofappli- 3 cable to merger cases. For a detailed discussion of that issue, see, inter alia, David Bailey, “Standard of proof in EC merger proceedings: a common law perspective,” 40 CMLR 845 (2003); Bo Vesterdorf, “Standard of proof in merger cases: reflections in the light of recent caselawofthecommunitycourts,”BIICL—ThirdAnnualMergerConference,6December 2004; Mario Siragusa, Judicial Review of Competition Decisions Under EC Law, UK CompetitionCommissionPapers,2004. 6 ECJ,CaseC-12/03P,Commissionv.TetraLaval,notyetreported. 7 Thestandardofproofisprobablyhigherthanamere50/50probabilitythattheeconomicharm willmaterializeasaresultofthemerger. StandardofProofandEconomicEvidence 73 inoperative in practice. More specifically, how should the Court review a decision where DGCOMP has selected an econometric model that is not entirelyconsistentwithmainstreameconomics?SupposeDGCOMPpreferred to stand by a minority view that showed with a relatively high level of prob- ability that prices would go up by a significant margin while other economic models/assumptionswouldleadtheCommissiontoalessclear-cutresult. Ourbasicpropositionisthateconometricscanusefullycontributetotheevi- dentiary burden that the Commission has to discharge, but econometrics should not be treated differently from the other factual elements of a merger investigation, at least from the perspective of the evidentiary threshold that D hastobesatisfied.Likewise,themerefactthatCommunitycourtshaveconsist- o w ently held that the Commission enjoys a certain “margin of discretion” nlo a when handling economic evidence should not constitute a barrier against a de d thorough review of the Commission’s approach and reasoning in its use of fro m econometric evidence. While undeniably the “margin of discretion” concept h is intended to highlight the limits of the Court’s judicial review, it should ttp onlybeconstruedasbarringtheCourtfromcarryingoutitsownmergerassess- ://jc le ment. In this regard, the Commission is in charge of the anticompetitive .o x scenario. The Court’s role is merely to verify that the competitive scenario ford is reasonable andthat the factual evidencethat isusedby theCommission is jou solid, consistent and adequately supports the points made. Econometrics rna ls shouldmakenoexception.However,econometricevidenceentailssomething .o rg morecomplexthancrudefacts.Econometricmodellingisindeedintendedto a/ explainwitharelativelyhighdegreeofconfidence(andprobability)whatcon- t Un iv sequencesamergerwillbringtothemarketplace.Inviewofitscomplexityand e rs purpose, theCourtsmaynothaveall theexpertise themselvesto“re-do”the ite analysis of the Commission in order to verify whether it is valid and solidly it v a n grounded onthefactsofthecase andconformswith mainstreameconomics. A m Theymayneedtoseekassistancefromanexpertorinvolvethepartiesinelu- s te cidatinghowthemodelswereconstructed,whattheyintendedtodemonstrate rd a m andwhytheyareconsistentwithmainstreameconomics.Undeniably,thecom- o n plexityofeconometricsmayhavetheconsequencethatCourtsmaynotbekeen N o todelvetoomuchintotheir intricaciesand,for thesakeofjudicialeconomy, ve m ratherprefer tocarryoutarelatively“light”reviewofeconometricevidence. be r 2 2 , 2 0 1 II. THECOMMISSION’SSTANDARDOFPROOFINMERGERS 3 This section provides an overview of the Commission’s standard of proof in merger reviews. It articulates the basic principles of evidence applicable to mergers and concludes that the Commission’s evidentiary burden in merger cases is setat afairly high threshold.8 8 NotethatthissectiondoesnotdiscusswhatstandardofprooftheCommissionhastomeetto satisfyitselfthatamergerdoesnotraisesignificantconcernsandshouldbeallowedtoproceed. 74 JournalofCompetitionLawandEconomics A. The Standard of ProofGenerally The standard of proof is commonly understood as the necessary evidentiary threshold that an authority or a court must meet before it can reach a certain opinion or determination in a particular case.9 Depending on the typeofmatterathand,civilorcriminal,thestandardwillbemoreorlessinten- sive. At one end, the burden is set at a relatively low threshold and is often defined under the “preponderance of the evidence” standard. This standard is usually employed in civil matters where the court will put all the facts and arguments that the parties have produced into the balance before reaching a conclusion.Attheotherendofthespectrum,thestandardissetataverystrin- D o gentthreshold,namelythe“beyondreasonabledoubt”standardusedincrim- w n inalmatters.Thislatterthresholddemandsfromthecourtthatitsconclusions loa d begroundedonverysolidevidenceandthatanypossibilitythattheaccusedis ed not guilty has been considered and rejected. Between the two extremes, the fro m standard of proof can moveacross the spectrum. h ttp MeIrngemr eRrgeegrulcaatisoens,10thheasConmotmsispseiocinfieids ctohnefreovnitdeedntwiairtyh tthhreesfhaoctldthtahtatthiet ://jcle .o must meet to prohibit a merger from going ahead. As the following sec- xfo tions illustrate, the European Courts have given some guidance on the rd jo relevantstandardtobeappliedbutseemtohavedonesoinarelativelyincon- urn a sistent manner. Indeed, the CFI uses alternatively the phrases “in all likeli- ls .o hood,” “very plausible,” “very probable”. True, each phrase suggests that rg a/ the standard is more than a mere preponderance of the evidence test. t U Beyondsemantics,though,theissuewouldseemtorelatetothelevelofprob- niv e ability that the Commission has to reach before a merger can be held to be rs anticompetitive.11 iteit v a n A m s te rd a m Onthispoint,seetheCommission’sdecisionintheSEB/Moulinexmergerandthesubsequent on rulingoftheCFIinCaseT-114/02,Babylissv.Commission,[2003]ECRII-1279. N o 9 See on this point David Bailey, “Standard of proof in EC merger proceedings”, 40 CMLR ve m 2003, 845 at p. 848. The standard of proof is to be distinguished from the neighbouring b e conceptofburdenofproof.Whiletheformerrelatestotheevidentiarythresholdthathasto r 2 bemetbeforeadecisioncanberenderedinacase,thelatterdealsprimarilywithprocedural 2, 2 rules that determine who has to discharge the evidentiary threshold. In this article, the 0 1 burdenofproofisnotdiscussedinanydetailsinceArticle2oftheMergerRegulationmakes 3 clear that it is for the Commission to meet a certain evidentiary threshold before it is allowedtoblockamerger. 10 CouncilRegulationNo.139/2004of20January2004onthecontrolofconcentrationsbetween undertakings,OJ2004L24/1(hereinafterthe“MergerRegulation”). 11 Certain commentators have suggested that the probability that a merger is anticompetitive shouldbesomewherearound70%.Itshouldbenotedthatthedeterminationofthestandard of proofisto someextentcloselyconnectedwiththe“falsepositives” and“falsenegatives” probleminantitrustdecision-making.See,e.g.,KenHeyer,“Aworldofuncertainty:economics andtheglobalizationofantitrust”,72AntitrustL.J.375(2005). StandardofProofandEconomicEvidence 75 B. TheCommission’s Four Stepsof Analysis TheMergerRegulationdisposesthattheCommissionhasthedutytomakean appraisal as to whether a concentration significantly impedes competition in the relevant market. The Merger Regulation is, however, silent as to the evi- dentiary threshold that the Commission has to reach before declaring a con- centration to be incompatible with the Common Market. One may identify several steps before such a determination can be reached. In particular, the Commission has to gather all relevant facts, develop the basic theoryof anti- competitive harm, specify the applicable test(s) and select the appropriate econometric tools that would support its opinion. These four steps do not D o take place all at once or within a specified order. Rather, the facts will w n determine the theories and tests to be used and vice versa. In this sense, the loa d process is relatively dynamic and evolving. Some or all the above steps may ed be considered with varying degrees of depth and detail in the course of the fro m first phase of the investigation, depending on the issuesat hand. h ttp dutWytitohcroengdaurdcttao“tthheofraocutgs,hitanisdwpiadienlsytarkeicnogg”n1i2zeindvtehsatitgtahtieoCn.oNmammiesslyiointmhaussta, ://jcle .o among others, collect all relevant qualitative and quantitative information xfo from the market in a comprehensive manner. The Merger Regulation has rd jo giventheCommissionwidediscretionarypowersastothetypeofinformation urn a that it may collect from the notifying parties, its competitors, suppliers, and ls .o customers. The CFI has also given a relatively wide margin of discretion as rg a/ to the scope and depth of information that the Commission may request t U pursuant to Article 11 of the Merger Regulation.13 niv e Aspartofthisinvestigatoryprocessandonthebasisofthedataprovidedby rs ite the parties in their Form CO and in response to the various information it v requests, the Commission will start developing the basic anticompetitive an A harmtheorybehindthetransaction.Itwilltypicallypayattentiontothepoten- m s tialanticompetitiveeffectsthattheconcentrationmaygenerateusingasabasic te rd framework the two theories laid out in the Horizontal Merger Guidelines,14 as am well as the conglomerate and/or vertical effects theories. In particular, the on N coordinated and unilateral effects theories under the Horizontal Merger o v e Guidelines will often be considered useful instruments to better identify and m b frame the issues. The Commission’s task will not only be to articulate the er 2 theory of anticompetitive harm, but to go a step further by laying out the 2, 2 0 1 3 12 See Opinion of Advocate-General Tizzano of 25 May 2004 in Case C-12/03, Commission v.TetraLaval,para74.Thissentencereferstothegeneralprincipleofgoodadministration underwhichtheCommissionmustoperateincarryingoutitsmergerinvestigationsandisa meanstoachievetheexpectedoutcome,i.e.thatthecasebesupportedbycogentandconsistent bodyofevidence. 13 Seeinparticular,CaseT-310/01,SchneiderElectricv.Commission,[2002]ECRII-4071,para 109. 14 Guidelines on the assessment of horizontal mergers under the Council Regulation on the controlofconcentrationsbetweenundertakings,OJ2004C31/5. 76 JournalofCompetitionLawandEconomics testandtheconditionsthatmustbesatisfiedbeforeits“gutfeeling”or intui- tivethinking rises tothe level of informed assessment. Oncethetestshavebeenproperlyspelledout,theCommissionwillhaveto useanumberofeconomictoolstoverifywhethereachpropositionofthetestis fulfilled. The tools range from very basic instruments, such as market-share information, diversion ratios,15 win/loss analyses, and critical loss analyses,16 to more sophisticated econometric instruments such as regressions,17 and bid and merger simulation models.18 The appropriateness of each of those instruments will have to be considered in light of the underlying theory of anticompetitiveharm.19 D o w n lo a C. The Standard of Evidence inMergerInvestigations d e d Thecaselawisalsounclearabouttheapplicablestandardofproofinmerger fro m investigations.20Fromtheoutset,threeconsiderationsshouldbehighlighted. h ttp Fwihriscth, ththeestacnasdeardisosftapnrdooinfgm. aFyovrariynsdtaenpceen,diantgtohnethenedstaogfepohfapsreocIe,ssthaet ://jcle .o Commission seems to enjoy relatively broad discretion to decide whether x fo there are sufficient elements in the file to warrant the initiation of an in- rd jo depth investigation. To the extent that an Article 6(1)(c) decision does not urn a affect the legal position of the undertakings concerned, the decision is not ls .o rg 15 Ibid,para29.DiversionratioscalculatetheamountoflostsalesbyproductAtoproductB at U/ whenthepriceofproductAincreasesbyacertainpercentage.Diversionratioscanbeestimated n usingown-priceandcross-priceelasticities.Ahighdiversionratiobetweentwoproductsindi- ive catesthattheproductsareclosesubstitutes.Alesssophisticatedalternativetodiversionratios rsite includescustomerswitchingstudiesorwin/lossanalyses. it v 16 Criticallossanalysiscalculatesthevolumelossesthatwouldbenecessarytomakeapost-merger a n priceriseunprofitableanddetermineswhethersuchalosswouldbelikelyinviewofthecharac- A m teristicsoftheindustry.Criticallossisconsideredasausefultooltodefinemarkets,butcan s te also,incertaincircumstances,beusedtoassesstheunilateraleffectsofamergerbyproviding rd a theminimumlostsalesnecessarytodefeatapriceincrease.Criticallossanalysishasbeenused m by the Commission in recent merger cases such as, Case COMP/M 3060—UCB/Solutia, on Commissiondecisionof31January2003,para42. N o 17 Regression analysis assesses the relationship between one variable called the explained, or ve m dependant,variableandoneormoreothervariablescalledexplanatoryvariables.Regression b e analyses are used as a quantitative technique to examine how the variable in question (e.g. r 2 price)isaffectedbyanumberofothervariables(e.g.reductioninthenumberofcompetitors 2, 2 or theincreasedlevelofconcentration).Asweshallseebelow,regressionmodelshavebeen 0 1 usedrecentlyinGE/InstrumentariumandOracle/PeopleSoft. 3 18 MergersimulationmodelshaverecentlyemergedinEUmergercasesasaquantitativetech- niqueusedtoestimatethepriceeffectsofamerger.See,e.g.,CaseCOMP/M.3191—Philip Morris/Papastratos,Commissiondecisionof2October2003,para32,whereamergersimu- lationwaspresentedbythemergingpartiestodemonstratethatthepriceimpactoftheconcen- trationwouldbeminimal. 19 Notethatthisarticleconcentratesontheuseofthemostcomplexeconometrictoolsinmerger investigations. 20 SeeAliNikpay&FredHouwen,Casecomment,“TourdeForceoralittlelocalturbulence?A hereticalviewontheAirtoursjudgment”,24(5)ECLR2003,196,at202. StandardofProofandEconomicEvidence 77 subjecttojudicialreviewbytheCommunityjudicature.Sincethestandardof proof is a concept closely related to the availability and intensity of judicial review,21 it is not surprising to see that Courts have likewise not defined any evidentiaryrequirement before acase can go into the second phase. The second consideration relates to the shifting in the burden of proof. While it is not the purpose of this article to cover this aspect in any great detail, it seems clear that the notifying parties playa key role in the adminis- tration of the evidence.22 Third, the standard of proof is admittedly much higher when the Commission reviews past and current market conditions than when it starts D to rely on those facts to predict the likely competitive effects of the merger o w in the short and mid-term.23 While factual evidence should be established nlo a with a relatively high level of accuracy, reliability, and consistency, the stan- de d dard of proof should not likewise require the Commission to prove the anti- fro m competitive effects with “absolute certainty”. That is, given the predictive h nature of merger control, the reviewing agency should not be required to ttp prove the anticompetitive effects of the merger using the standard of proof ://jc le applicable to criminal proceedings, that is, the “beyond reasonable doubt” .o x standard. Nevertheless, the CFI in Tetra Laval/Sidel held that, when the ford effects of the merger do not immediately affect the structure of the market, jou rn the Commission must be convinced that merger will “in all likelihood” allow a ls the parties to achieve a dominant position in the near future.24 That is, the .o rg further in time such effects are predicted to materialize, the higher the a/ burden the Commission must deliver. On appeal of the CFI’s judgment in t Un iv the Tetra Laval/Sidel case, Advocate General Tizzano suggested, however, e rs that giventhe prospectivenature of mergeranalysis, it is ite it v a n sufficient if on the basis of solid elements gathered in the course of a thorough and A painstakinginvestigation,andhavingregardtoitstechnicalknowledge,theCommission m s is persuaded that the notified concentration would very probably lead to the creation or te thestrengtheningofadominantposition.25(emphasisadded) rda m o n If the Commission is not able to reach such an opinion, it must clear the N o merger.TheCourtofJusticeseemstohaveadoptedasomewhatlessstringent ve m standardof proof: b e r 2 2 the quality of the evidence produced by the Commission in order to establish that it is , 2 0 necessarytoadoptadecisiondeclaringtheconcentrationincompatiblewiththecommon 13 market is particularly important, since that evidence must support the Commission’s 21 SeeSectionIIIbelow. 22 Thepartieshaveadutytoprovidecomplete,accurateandnon-misleadinginformation.See Article14oftheMergerRegulation. 23 AliNikpay&FredHouwen,seeabovenote21,at199. 24 CaseT-5/02,Tetrav.Commission,[2002]ECRII-4381,para148. 25 OpinionofAdvocate-GeneralTizzanoof25May2004inCaseC-12/03,Commissionv.Tetra Laval,para74. 78 JournalofCompetitionLawandEconomics conclusionthat,ifsuchadecisionwerenotadopted,theeconomicdevelopmentenvisaged byitwouldbeplausible.26(emphasisadded) The standard of proof applying to the Commission’s prospective analyses— that is, the projected anticompetitive effects flowing from the merger—raises a number of questions. While the ECJ’s “plausibility” test sounds sensible and approaches that applied in US courts,27 in practice its application is subjecttoanumberofhurdles.Inparticular,whatdoesa“plausible”standard mean? Does that mean that econometrics would be subject to less scrutiny, especially where such instruments are used to predict the likely effects of a D merger? o w LetustrytoarticulatetheaboveECJstandardinpracticalterms.Asafirst nlo a step, the Commission must get the facts right and describe the pre-existing d e d market conditions with accuracy. As the ECJ points out, the quality of fro the data is key to the reliability of the Commission’s prospective analyses. m h The task of the Commission is particularly demanding. For instance, in the ttp context of particularly complex merger cases such as the recent GE/ ://jc le InstrumentariumandOracle/PeopleSoftcases,thishasresultedinaveryburden- .o x some data gathering process.28 fo rd Once facts are established, the Commission has to assess the facts and jo u determine whethercertain conditions and requirements are met. Allrelevant rna ls factors must be taken into account and carefully reviewed before any con- .o rg clusion is drawn as to their significance and impact on market conditions. In a/ thisrespect,suchconclusionsmustsatisfytherequirementsof“logic,coherence t U n andappropriateness”.Inparticular,theCommissionmaynotusethesameset ive of facts to support twocontradictoryfindings.29 rsite Next, the Commission’s opinion entails a complex technical assessment, it v a n “based not on the application of precise scientific rules but on criteria and A m principles which are open to question, such as economic ones”.30 In this s te regard, one should pay particular attention to the selection, use, and cali- rd a m bration of economic theoriesand instruments. o n It is quite clear that the selection and use of economic theories should be N o supported by the facts. For instance, while a broad-brush review of the case ve m may suggest that a particular merger may be explained using a unilateral b e effects scenario, the Commission has to ensure that the facts and the r 2 2 , 2 0 1 26 ECJ,C-12/03P,Commissionv.TetraLaval,notyetreported,para44. 3 27 Inpreliminaryinjunctioncases,UScourtsapplythe“preponderanceoftheevidence”standard. 28 OnemayquestionwhetherthestricttimetablessetforthintheMergerRegulationconflictwith theevidentiaryrequirements.Itseemstousthat,inviewofthenecessitytobaseitsopinionon solidfactualgroundstheCommissionwillprobablycontinuetomakeextensiveuseofthe“stop theclock”provisionunderArticle11ECMR.Forinstance,intheOracle/PeopleSoftmerger, theclockwasstoppedtwiceandthereviewperiodwasextendedbyabout6months. 29 CaseT-342/99,Airtoursv.Commission,[2002]ECRII-2585,para142. 30 OpinionofAdvocate-GeneralTizzanoof25May2004inCaseC-12/03,Commissionv.Tetra Laval,para73. StandardofProofandEconomicEvidence 79 conclusions drawn therefrom support the unilateral effects theory. In this respect, there is much less guidance as to the evidentiary value to be given to econometric instruments. There is equally little guidance on the level of confidence or probability that the Commission must arrive at in relation to the results generated by the operation of those econometric models. The ECJ only indicates that the economic effects predicted by the econo- metric theories and models should be “plausible”. While the selection of a particular econometric tool should logically be made in accordance with a relatively well established set of guidelines, the way a particular instrument should be used—the parameters and variables to be included in the model D and the admissible assumptions that the Commission may draw—and the o w data upon which it should rely are subject to debate, even among nlo a economists.31 de d For instance,inthecontext of adifferentiatedproductmerger raisinguni- fro m lateraleffectconcerns,theCommissionmustascertaintheextenttowhichthe h elimination of competition that existed between the merging parties prior to ttp the merger will be of such magnitude as to allow the merged entity to find it ://jc le profitable unilaterally to raise its prices post merger. Resolving that question .o x calls for an evaluation of the relevanttest to be applied using the principle of ford logic, coherence, and appropriateness as well as the selection, use, and cali- jou rn brationofeconometrictoolsthatmaybeparticularlysuitabletoestablishcon- a ls vincingly each branch of the test. In the hypothetical situation at hand, the .o rg Commission’s first task will be to demonstrate the closeness of competition a/ between the merging parties.32 Suitable econometric tools include win/loss t Un iv data, provided that the underlying information is sufficiently precise and e rs reliable to indicate against whom each of the merging parties competed. In ite this respect, the way the win/loss sample has been prepared (what products it v a n are covered and which geographies) and presented is an important aspect. A m Anothersetofinstrumentsthatmightbeconsideredincludesregressionana- s te lyses with a view to evaluating the extent to which the presence of one party rd a m significantly impacts the pricing behaviour of the other party. Both instru- o n mentsrequirenotonlythatthefact-findingprocesshasbeencarriedoutpro- N o perly, but also that the econometric tools are calibrated to the particular ve m circumstancesofthecase.Thislatterpartissubjecttosomeformofarbitrage be and it is unclear, under the ECJ’s proposed standard, what justification the r 22 Commission has to provide in support of the choice of one particular cali- , 20 1 bration or the selection of acertainvariableagainst another. 3 31 See,e.g.,GregoryJ.WerdenandLukeM.Froeb,“Unilateralcompetitiveeffectsofhorizontal mergers”, inAdvancesintheEconomicsofCompetitionLaw(MITPress),draftof14January 2005(onfilewiththeauthor). 32 Theotherlimbsofthetestincludeevaluatingtheextenttowhichthenon-mergingpartiescould beconsidereddistantsubstitutesforthemergingfirmsandtheirabilitytorepositiontheiroffer- inginresponsetoapriceincreasebythemergedentity. 80 JournalofCompetitionLawandEconomics Toexplorethisissue further,it is appropriate toreview howthe European judicaturehasarticulatedthescopeofitsjudicialpowersinexercisingitsover- sightof the Commission’sworkin past mergercases. III. STANDARD(S)OFREVIEWINMERGERCASES Fromaconstitutionallawpointofview,judicialreviewcanbedescribedasan institutional concept defining the scope of intervention of the judiciary in relation to acts and decisions adopted by the administrative bodies of the European Union. There is the idea that Courts may not be invested with D thepowertoreviewanadministrativedecisiondenovobutshouldnevertheless ow n inquireastothelegalityofthedecisionagainstasetofprinciples,forexample, lo a theprincipleofgoodandsoundadministration.Thiswouldsuggestthatthere de d is a certain level of deference that Courts should maintain and keep in mind fro m when reviewingthe legalityof administrative decisions. h ttp ://jc A. The Scope of Judicial Review inMergerCases le.o x fo InaccordancewithArticle230oftheECTreaty,Commissiondecisionsmay rd jo beannulledonthegrounds“oflackofcompetence,infringementofanessen- u rn tialproceduralrequirement,infringementofthisTreatyorofanyofitsruleof als .o law relating to its application, or misuse of powers”. The Courts’review will rg consist of verifying whether: (i) the Commission carried out its duties under at U/ the ECMR by conducting a “thorough and painstaking” investigation; n iv (ii)therelevantproceduralruleshavebeencompliedwith;(iii)thestatement ers of the reasons for the decision is adequate;33 (iv) the facts upon which the ite Commission’s assessment is based are correct; and (v) whether there has it va n been any manifest error of appraisal or misuse of powers.34 Grounds based A m on legal and factual infringements are captured by the “manifest error of ste rd appraisal” standard. In RJB Mining, the CFI explained how this concept a m shouldbe understood: o n N as regards the evaluation of the situation resulting from economic facts or circumstances ov e underlying the contested decision, it is settled case law that the Court, in conducting its m b review,mustconfineitselftoascertainingwhethertheCommissionmisuseditspowersor e manifestlyfailedtoobservetheprovisionsoftheECSCTreatyoranyruleoflawrelating r 22 , 2 0 1 33 ThiswouldincludewhetherthereasoningoftheCommissionsatisfies“requirementsoflogic, 3 coherence and appropriateness”. See ECJ, Joined Cases C-68/94 and C-30/95 France and Othersv.Commission,[1998]ECRI-1375(“KaliandSalz”),para229–241. 34 See,e.g.,ECJ,Case42/84,RemiaandOthersv.Commission,[1985]ECR2545,para34,and Joined Cases142/84and156/84;BATandReynoldsv. Commission, [1987]ECR 4487,para 62; Case C-7/95, John Deere v. Commission, [1998] ECR I-3111, para 34: “[The Court]’s reviewofcomplexeconomicappraisalsmadebytheCommissionisnecessarilylimitedtover- ifyingwhethertherelevantrulesonprocedureandonthestatementofreasonshavebeencom- plied with, whether the facts have been accurately stated and whether there has been any manifesterrorofappraisaloramisuseofpowers”.

Description:
Feb 2, 2006 Case COMP/M. 3216—Oracle/PeopleSoft, Commission decision of 26 merger will significantly impede competition in a substantial part of the.
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.