TechnicalPaperSeries CongressionalBudgetOf¿ce Washington,D.C. Measuring Time Preference and Parental Altruism ShinichiNishiyama CongressionalBudgetOf¿ce October2000 2000-7 Technical papers in this series are preliminary and are circulated to stimulate discussion and criticalcomment. ThesepapersarenotsubjecttoCBO¶sformalreviewandeditingprocesses. Theanalysis and conclusions expressed in them are thoseof theauthor and should not be in- terpreted as those of the Congressional Budget Of¿ce. Any reference to this paper in other publicationsshouldbeclearedwiththeauthor. Papersinthisseriescanbeobtainedbysending [email protected]. (cid:6) Measuring Time Preference and Parental Altruism Shinichi Nishiyama Congressional BudgetOf¿ce Washington,D.C.20515 e-mail: [email protected] October2000 Abstract This paper extends a heterogeneous agent overlapping generations model by im- plementing bequests† both altruistic and accidental † and measures the degrees of timepreferenceand parentalaltruismthrough the calibration of themodeltotheU.S. economy. Inthismodel,aparenthouseholdanditsadultchildhouseholdsbehavecon- sistentlyandstrategicallytodeterminetheiroptimalconsumption,workinghours,and savings. Basedontheobtainedparameters,thepaperalsoshowstheindividualeffects ofaltruisticandaccidentalbequestsonwealthaccumulationbyexaminingtheimpacts of a 100 percent estate tax and a perfect annuity market in the model. To match the economy¶scapital-outputratioandtherelativesizeofbequestsobservedintheUnited States, the parent household would have to discount its children¶s utility by about 30 percentrelativetoitsownutility,accordingtothemodel. Themodelsuggeststhatto- tal bequests contribute about 14 percent to wealth accumulation in a closed economy and 21 percentin asmall open economy. Also, theeffect of a perfect annuity market dependsonthedegreeofparentalaltruismintheeconomy. 1 Introduction Most existing macroeconomic models assume either that people care about their descen- dantsasmuchastheycareaboutthemselves(in¿nitehorizonmodels)orthattheydon¶tcare abouttheirdescendantsatall(life-cyclemodels). Butwheneconomistsevaluategovernment policiesthatinvolveincomeredistributionbetweengenerations,theeffectsofthesepolicies critically depend on the degree of the altruism between parents and children. If people are mostly altruistic, in¿nite horizon models are appropriate. But if they are mostly sel¿sh, overlappinggenerationsmodelsarebetter. Previousanalysesthatevaluatethedegreeofbequestmotivesusingpaneldata,however, show several different conclusions, and it is still inconclusive to what extent parents are W IwouldliketothankAndyAbel,BobDennis,DougHamilton,RichardRogerson,andseminarparticipants attheUniversityofPennsylvaniaandtheCongressionalBudgetOf¿ceforvaluablecommentsandsuggestions. I am especially indebted to Víctor Ríos-Rull for his guidance from the early stage of this paper. The views expressedhereindonotnecessarilyre(cid:192)ectthoseoftheCongressionalBudgetOf¿ce. 1 altruistic toward their children. For example, Hurd (1987) and Wilhelm (1996) show that parental altruism is insigni¿cant and that bequests are likely to be accidental. In contrast, Menchik and David (1983) and Bernheim (1991) show that the bequest motives of parents arestrong,althoughthesearenotnecessarilycausedbyaltruism. Infact,HurdandBernheim actuallyusedthesamedataset,theLongitudinalRetirementHouseholdSurvey,butreached opposingconclusionsusingdifferentapproaches. Previous studies also differ greatly with regard to estimating the importance of transfer wealthversuslife-cyclewealth. Ontheonehand,Modigliani(1988)andothersestimatethat theshareofbequeathedwealthamongtotalwealthisatmost20percent.1 Ontheotherhand, Kotlikoff and Summers (1981) show that transfer wealth (which includes inter vivos trans- fers) accounts for more than 80 percent of total wealth. The difference between those two conclusions is signi¿cant, although it is due in large part to different de¿nitions of transfer wealth. Thispaperconstructsameasureoftimepreference(howmuchpeoplediscounttheirown future utility) and a measure of parental altruism (how much they discount their children¶s utility), and it answers the same questions using an extended dynamic general equilibrium model. Morespeci¿cally,thepaperusesaheterogeneousagentoverlappinggenerationsmodel, extendedtoincludealtruisticandaccidentalbequests.2 Inthismodel,aparenthouseholdand itsadultchildhouseholdsplayaCournot-Nashgameanddecidetheiroptimalconsumption, workinghours,andsavingsineachperiod. ThemodeliscalibratedtotheU.S.economy. In that calibration, the two main parameters, time preference and parental altruism, are deter- mined simultaneously so that the steady-state equilibrium of the model replicates the U.S. economy in termsof the following two key statistics †the capital-output ratio and the rel- ative size of bequests. Finally, based on the parameters obtained, the paper calculates the individualcontributionofaltruisticandaccidentalbequeststowealthaccumulation. Forsimplicity,themodelabstractsfromintervivostransfersaswellaseducationspend- ingbyparents. So,inthismodel,intergenerationaltransfersoccuronlyatthetimeofdeathin theformofbequests.3 But,inthecalibration,bothbequestsandpartofintervivostransfers inthedataareregardedasbequestsinthemodel.4 Altruisminthismodelisone-sided, i.e., parents care about their children but children don¶t care about their parents. In the baseline economy,thereareassumedtobenoannuitymarketsotherthantheSocialSecuritypensions(cid:30) later, the model is extended to include a private annuity market to analyze the contribution ofprecautionarysavings. 1SeeModigliani(1988)forseveralestimatesofothers. 2Intentionalbequestsarenotnecessarilymotivatedbyparentalaltruismbutalsobyrisksharingandbygift exchange. Accordingtotheempiricalstudies,however,thoselasttwomotivesarenotverylarge. Forexample, Wilhelm(1996)showedthatparentstendtoleaveanequalamountofbequeststoeachoftheirchildreneven if the children¶s earnings are signi¿cantly different. Also, Behrman and Rosenzweig (1998) showed that the relationshipbetweentheamountofbequestsandthenumberofvisitsacrosschildrenisnotsigni¿cant. 3This assumption is partly justi¿ed because uncertainty about earnings and lifetime implies incentives for altruistic parents to defer transfers to their children. But, in the presence of borrowing constraints, there are incentivesforparentstomakeintervivostransfers. 4Inthecalibration,educationspendingpaidbyparentsandpartofintervivostransfersarenotregardedas bequestsinthismodel. Instead,Iassumetheparent-childworkingabilitycorrelation,partlyduetoschooling, usingaMarkovtransitionmatrix. 2 The ¿ndings in this paper are as follows. With a coef¿cient of relative risk aversion of 2.0, the annual time preference parameter turns out to be 0.934, and the degree of parental altruism is 0.51 for each child household and 0.69 in total.5 The last-mentioned number indicatesthataparenthouseholdcaresaboutitschildhouseholds31percentlessthanitcares aboutitself. Ifa100percentestatetaxwasintroducedtoeliminateparentalbequestmotives, national wealth would be reduced by 10 percent in a closed economy and by 15 percent in a small open economy. In addition, if a perfect annuity market was introduced to eliminate precautionary savings and accidental bequests, national wealth would be reduced, in total, by 14.3 percent and 20.5 percent in a closed and a small open economy, respectively. The effect of a perfect annuity market depends critically on whether parents are altruistic. With parental altruism, the introduction of the perfect annuity market would increase national savingsslightly. Theremainderofthepaperislaidoutasfollows. Theextendedoverlappinggenerations modelisdescribedinsection2. ThemodeliscalibratedtotheU.S.economy,andtwomain parameters are obtained in section 3. The contribution of bequests to wealth accumulation is analyzed in section 4, and section 5 concludes the paper. The algorithm to calculate the steady-state equilibria and an optimal annuity holding are explained in the appendix to this paper. 2 Model Thissectiondescribesafour-periodheterogeneousagentoverlappinggenerationsmodelwith altruistic and accidental bequests. The model considers both parental altruism and lifetime uncertainty,andhouseholdsinthiseconomyplayaCournot-Nashgametomakeanoptimal decisionabouttheirconsumption,workinghours,andsavings. 2.1 Economy Themodelisbasedonastandardgrowtheconomythatconsistsofalargenumberofhouse- holds, a perfectly competitive ¿rm, and a government. Each household is assumed to act as a single person. In the calibration of the model, a household is assumed to be a married couple, but all of their decisions are made jointly. Also, there is assumed to be no strategic interactionbetweensiblings. The Life Cycle of Households. The life of a household is shown in Figure 1. In each period, new households are born without any wealth. The life span of each household is eitherthree orfour periods. Oneperiod inthis modelcorrespondsto 15 yearsstartingfrom the actual age of 30. So, age 1 corresponds to 30-44 years old, age 2 corresponds to 45-59 yearsold,age3correspondsto60-74yearsold,andage4correspondsto75-89yearsold.6 A householddieseitherattheendofage3orattheendofage4. Themortalityrateisknown, 5Inthecalibration,Iassumethepopulationgrowthrateas1percentperyearand35percentpergeneration. So,eachparenthouseholdhas1.35childhouseholds. 6Becauseofthissetting,householdsinthismodelareassumedtoretireatthebeginningofage60,contrary tothefactthatmostpeopleretireateitherage62orage65intheUnitedStates. 3 Figure1: TheLifeCycleofaHousehold Age 1 Age 2 Age 3 Age 4 (30-44) (45-59) (60-74) (75-89) A household It becomes It dies with It dies with is ‘born.’ Its parent dies a ‘parent’ prob. 1-(cid:28). prob. 1. with prob. 1- (cid:28). (its children are ‘born’). Its parent dies with prob. 1. but for each household its own life span is uncertain. When a household reaches age 3, its childhouseholdsofage1are‡born,·andtheformerbecomesaparenthousehold. Labor Income and Capital Income. When a household is age 1 or 2, its working abil- ity (labor productivity) at each age is stochastically determined. It receives labor income (earnings) according to the market wage rate, its working hours, and its working ability. A household of age3 or4 is assumedtoberetired. Thougha household can work at home to producealimitedamountofconsumptiongoodsandservices,itsworkingabilityisassumed to be low and deterministic. There are only one kind of assets (which are supposed to be a mixture of bonds, stock, and real estate) a household can hold. It receives capital income accordingtoitswealthlevelandthemarketinterestrate. Thereisassumedtobeaborrowing constraint,andthewealthofeachhouseholdmustbenonnegative. Taxes and Social Security Bene¿ts. A household pays federal income tax according to its total income (the sum of labor income and capital income). A household that inherits any wealth from its parent also pays federal and state estate taxes. In addition, a household of age 1 or 2 pays payroll tax for Social Security and Medicare based on its labor income. A household of age 3 or 4 receives Social Security bene¿ts. The Social Security system is assumedtobeoneofde¿nedbene¿ttype. Everyhouseholdofage3or4iseligibleforSocial Securitybene¿tsand,forsimplicity,thesizeofthebene¿tisassumedtobethesameforall households. Dynasty and Altruism. Since each household lives either three or four periods, at any period of time there are two types of dynasties † the dynasties with both a parent house- hold and its child households (Type I), and the dynasties with age 2 households only (Type II). Figure 2 shows the two types of dynasties in this economy. Every parent household caresaboutitschildhouseholdsandisassumedtobeequallyaltruistic. (Sinceaparentalso 4 Figure2: TwoTypesofDynasties Type I (Age 4, 2) Type II (Age 2 Only) Generation 0: Type I (Age 3, 1) Generation 1: Type I (Age 4, 2) Generation 2: Type I (Age 3, 1) Generation 3: Time knows its children are altruistic toward its grandchildren, it actually cares about all its de- scendantsindirectly.) Thus,aparenthouseholdchoosesend-of-periodwealth,whichwillbe bequeathed to its child households if it dies. The wealth choice is made so as to maximize theweightedsumofitsownutilityanditschildren¶sutility. StrategyofaParentandaChild. Beginning-of-periodwealthofaparenthouseholdand its child households, the working ability of the child households, and the mortality of the parent household (at the end of age 3) are known to each other. A parent and its children choose, simultaneously, their own optimal consumption, working hours, and end-of-period wealth. Since a parent household is altruistic toward its child households, and the children knowtheir parents arealtruistic, the decisions of a parent and its childrenare dependent on eachother. Forexample,ifaparentknewitschildren¶swealthwasgoingtobehigherinthe next period, it would reduce the amount of bequest since the marginal value of the bequest would be smaller. Also, if a child knew the bequest of its parent was going to be higher, it wouldreduceitsownsavingsandconsumemore.7 2.2 TheHouseholds¶Problem 2.2.1 ThePreferenceofaHousehold ConsiderahouseholdthatliveseitherthreeorfourperiodsandcallitaGeneration0house- hold. Ifthishouseholdissel¿sh,thehousehold¶sproblemisshownas (cid:12) pd{ xf @ H (cid:15)(cid:16)3(cid:129)x ff>kf .(cid:24)(cid:15)(cid:12)x ff>kf iSf(cid:16)c(cid:5)f(cid:16)je(cid:16)’(cid:129) %[(cid:16)’(cid:129) (cid:19) (cid:16) (cid:16)(cid:20) (cid:19) e e(cid:20)& 7In this model, a parent household and its child households behave strategically. But, this model doesn¶t considerso-calledstrategicbequests(orgiftexchanges)inwhichthechildoffersservicetotheparentinexchange forfuturebequests. 5 subject to some budget constraint, where xf is the lifetime utility of Generation 0(cid:30) x+=>=, is an instantaneous utility function(cid:30) ff and kf are consumption and working hours, respec- (cid:16) (cid:16) tively, at age l(cid:30) (cid:15) is a time preference factor(cid:30) and (cid:24) is the survival rate at the end of age 3. Thishouseholdchoosesitsoptimalconsumptionandworkinghourstomaximizeitslifetime utilityxf. Suppose that Generation 0 considers not only the utility from its own consumption and leisure(say,k (cid:3)kf)butalsotheutilityofGeneration1,andthatGeneration1considers 4@ (cid:16) theutilityofGeneration2aswell,andsoon. ThenthetotalutilityofGeneration0(including theutilityfromitsdescendants)Xf isshownas Xf @ pd{ H xf.*X(cid:129) iSfc(cid:5)fje (cid:16) (cid:16) (cid:16)’(cid:129) k l @ pd{ H xf.* pd{ x(cid:129).* pd{ x2. === > iSfc(cid:5)fje 5 ;iS(cid:129)c(cid:5)(cid:129)je ;iS2c(cid:5)2je <<6 (cid:16) (cid:16) (cid:16)’(cid:129) ? (cid:16) (cid:16) (cid:16)’(cid:129) ? (cid:16) (cid:16) (cid:16)’(cid:129) @@ 7 8 where*denotesthediscountfactorb=ytheparenthouseho=ldontheutilityofit>s>childhouse- holds. Thispaperassumesthat* @ (cid:15)2(cid:20)q ? 4, whereqisthenumberofchild households per parent household and (cid:20) is the degree of parental altruism. Since the consumption and leisure of the child household occur two periods later, the utility is discounted by (cid:15)2. The parent cares about its children proportionally to the number q of its child households. The degreeofparentalaltruism(cid:20) shows howmuch the parent household cares about each of its adultchildhouseholdsrelativetohowmuchitcaresaboutitselfinthesameperiod. This paperdecomposes *and measuresthe degree oftime preference (cid:15) andthe degree ofparentalaltruism(cid:20)(perchild)or(cid:20)q(intotal)throughthecalibrationusingtheaggregate statisticsofnationalwealthandintergenerationaltransfers. 2.2.2 TheStateofaDynasty Since the utility maximization problem of a household is nested as shown above, in the followingsectionsthepreferenceofhouseholdsisdescribedbyvaluefunctions. ForTypeI dynasties, the state ofeach dynasty is shownby the ages of parentand child householdsi+6>4,>+7>5,j,thebeginning-of-periodwealthoftheparentd 5D@^3>d ‘ R 4@ andthatofitschildrend 5D>andthelaborproductivity(whichdetermineshourlywage)of & thechildrenh 5 H @ ^H >H ‘=Inthecalibration,h isamemberofih(cid:129) >h2 >h(cid:12) j & 4(cid:16)? 4@ &c(cid:16) &c(cid:16) &c(cid:16) &c(cid:16) for age l @1 or 2, and it follows a Markov process. For Type II dynasties, the state of each dynasty is simply shown by the age i5j, the beginning-of-period wealth, and the working abilityoftheage2households+d>h,. Fornotationalsimplicity,letv andv denotethestatesofaTypeIdynastyandaType U UU IIdynasty,respectively,where v @+d >d >h , and v @+d>h,= U R & & UU ThenthevaluefunctionofaTypeIhouseholdofagelisdenotedasy +v ,,andthevalue Uc(cid:16) U functionofaTypeIIhouseholdofage2isdenotedasy +v ,. UUc2 UU 6 2.2.3 TypeIHouseholds AnAge3ParentandItsAge1Children. Thevaluefunctionofanage3parenthousehold isshownas y +v >(cid:11) , @ pd{ ix+f >k ,.(cid:20)qx+f >k , Uc(cid:12) U (cid:129) SRc(cid:5)Rc@(cid:30)R R R & & .(cid:15)H (cid:24)y +v(cid:30),.+4(cid:3)(cid:24),(cid:20)qy +v(cid:30) ,mh (1) Uce U UUc2 UU & subjectto (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) 4 (cid:30) d @ izh k .+4.u,d .wu (cid:3)(cid:31) +ud ,(cid:3)f j> (2) R 4.(cid:25) R R R 77 8 R R wherev isthestateofthisdynasty, U v @+d >3>h ,> U R & (cid:11) istheparent¶sconjectureofitsage1childhouseholds¶decision, (cid:129) (cid:11) +v ,@+f >k >d(cid:30),> (cid:129) U & & & andthelawofmotionofthestateofthisdynastyis v(cid:30) @ d(cid:30)>d(cid:30)>h(cid:30) > U R & & (cid:19) (cid:20) v(cid:30) @ d(cid:30) .d(cid:30)@q(cid:3)(cid:31) d(cid:30)@q >h(cid:30) = (3) UU & R . R (cid:19) (cid:19) (cid:20) (cid:20) The parent household chooses its optimal consumption f , working hours (housework R (cid:30) only) k , and end-of-period wealth level (normalized by the economic growth) d , taking R R the decision of its child households (cid:11) as given. It discounts the utility of each of q child (cid:129) households by (cid:20). At the end of age 3, the parent household dies with probability +4(cid:3)(cid:24),. Thevalueofthishouseholdatthebeginningofthenextperiodistheweightedaverageofits ownfuturevaluey (whenthishouseholdisalive)anditsqchildren¶sfuturevalueqy Uce UUc2 discountedby(cid:20)(whenthishouseholdisdeceased). ThetermH^. mh ‘denotesaconditional & expectationgiventhatthecurrentworkingabilityofanage1childhouseholdish ,i.e., & H y +v(cid:30),mh @ y +v(cid:30),(cid:28) +h(cid:30) mh ,gh(cid:30)> Uce U & Uce U (cid:129)c2 & & & ]. (cid:5) (cid:6) (cid:30) (cid:30) where (cid:28) +h mh , is a conditional probability of the working ability being h in the next (cid:129)c2 & & & period. The equation (2) is a budget constraint of this parent household, where (cid:25) is the growthrateoftheeconomy,zisthewageperef¿ciencyunitoflabor,u istherateofreturn oncapital,wu denotesSocialSecuritybene¿ts,and(cid:31) +=>=,isafederalincometaxfunction. 77 8 (cid:30) Whentheparenthouseholddies,itsend-of-periodwealthd issplitequallyandbequeathed R to each of q child households. In the law of motion (3), (cid:31) +=, denotes an estate tax (both . federalandlocal)function. Similarly,thevaluefunctionofanage1childhouseholdisshownas y +v >(cid:11) , @ pd{ x+f >k ,.(cid:15)H (cid:24)y +v(cid:30),.+4(cid:3)(cid:24),y +v(cid:30) ,mh (4) Uc(cid:129) U (cid:12) S&c(cid:5)&c@(cid:30)& & & Uc2 U UUc2 UU & (cid:11) (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) 7 subjectto 4 (cid:30) d @ izh k .+4.u,d (cid:3)(cid:31) +zh k >ud ,(cid:3)(cid:31) +zh k ,(cid:3)f j> (5) & 4.(cid:25) & & & 8 & & & 7 & & & where(cid:11) isthechild¶sconjectureofitsage3parenthousehold¶sdecision, (cid:12) (cid:11) +v ,@+f >k >d(cid:30),> (cid:12) U R R R andthelawofmotionofthestateis(3). Thechildhouseholdchoosesitsoptimalconsumptionf ,workinghoursk ,andend-of- & & period wealth level d(cid:30)> taking the decision of its parent household (cid:11) as given. The value & (cid:12) ofthechildhouseholdatthebeginningofthenextperiodistheweightedaverageofitsown future value when its parent is alive, y , and its future value when its parent is deceased, Uc2 y . The equation (5) is a budget constraint of this child household, and (cid:31) +=, is a Social UUc2 7 SecurityandMedicaretax(payrolltax)function. AnAge4ParentandItsAge2Children. Anage4parenthouseholdisassumedtodieat theendofthisperiod,andeachofitschildhouseholdsbecomesaparentatthebeginningof thenextperiod=So,thevaluefunctionofanage4parenthouseholdisshownas y +v >(cid:11) , @ pd{ x+f >k ,.(cid:20)qx+f >k ,.(cid:15)(cid:20)qH y +v(cid:30),mh (6) Uce U 2 SRc(cid:5)Rc@(cid:30)R R R & & Uc(cid:12) U & (cid:11) (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) subjectto(2),wherethelawofmotionofthestateis v(cid:30) @+d(cid:30) .d(cid:30)@q(cid:3)(cid:31) +d(cid:30)@q,>3>h(cid:30),= (7) U & R . R & Theparenthouseholdconsidersitschildren¶svalueatthebeginningofthenextperiodqy Uc(cid:12) discountedby(cid:20)=Similarly,thevaluefunctionofanage2childhouseholdisshownas y +v >(cid:11) , @ pd{ x+f >k ,.(cid:15)H y +v(cid:30),mh (8) Uc2 U e S&c(cid:5)&c@(cid:30)& & & Uc(cid:12) U & (cid:11) (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) subjectto(5),wherethelawofmotionofthestateis(7). The Strategy of a Parent and Its Children. Let g and g be the set of decisions of a R & parenthouseholdandeachofitschildhouseholds,respectively,i.e., g @+f >k >d(cid:30),> g @+f >k >d(cid:30),= R R R R & & & & The best response functions of an age 3 parent and an age 1 child are derived from the valuefunctions(1)and(4)asfollows: U +g >v , @ duj pd{ ix+f >k ,.(cid:20)qx+f >k , (cid:12) & U R R & & SRc(cid:5)Rc@(cid:30)R .(cid:15)H (cid:24)y +v(cid:30),.+4(cid:3)(cid:24),(cid:20)qy +v(cid:30) ,mh Uce U UUc2 UU & subjectto(2),and (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) U +g >v ,@duj pd{ x+f >k ,.(cid:15)H (cid:24)y +v(cid:30),.+4(cid:3)(cid:24),y +v(cid:30) ,mh (cid:129) R U S&c(cid:5)&c@(cid:30)& & & Uc2 U UUc2 UU & (cid:11) (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) 8 subjectto(5),wherethelawofmotionofthestateis(3). Similarly, the best response functions of an age 4 parent and an age 2 child are derived fromthevaluefunctions(6)and(8)asfollows: U +g >v ,@duj pd{ x+f >k ,.(cid:20)qx+f >k ,.(cid:15)(cid:20)qH y +v(cid:30),mh e & U SRc(cid:5)Rc@(cid:30)R R R & & Uc(cid:12) U & (cid:11) (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) subjectto(2),and U +g >v ,@duj pd{ x+f >k ,.(cid:15)H y +v(cid:30),mh 2 R U S&c(cid:5)&c@(cid:30)& & & Uc(cid:12) U & (cid:11) (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) subjectto(5),wherethelawofmotionofthestateis(7). Solvingthesebestresponsefunctions,Nashequilibriumdecisionrulesareobtainedas g +v , @ f +v ,>k +v ,>d(cid:30) +v , Uc(cid:16) U Uc(cid:16) U Uc(cid:16) U Uc(cid:16) U (cid:19) (cid:20) forl5 i4>5>6>7j. Theconsistencyconditionis(cid:11) +v ,@g +v ,forallv 5D2(cid:5)H and (cid:16) U Uc(cid:16) U U l 5i4>5>6>7j= 2.2.4 TypeIIHouseholds Thevaluefunctionofanage2householdissimply y +v , @pd{ x+f>k,.(cid:15)H y +v(cid:30),mh (9) UUc2 UU Sc(cid:5)c@(cid:30) Uc(cid:12) U (cid:11) (cid:5) (cid:6)(cid:12) subjectto 4 (cid:30) d @ izhk.+4.u,d(cid:3)(cid:31) +zhk>ud,(cid:3)(cid:31) +zhk,(cid:3)fj> (10) 8 7 4.(cid:25) wherethelawofmotionofthestateis v(cid:30)@+d(cid:30)>3>h(cid:30),= U & The household chooses its optimal consumption f, working hours k, and end-of-period wealthleveld(cid:30). Thehousehold¶sdecisionrulesareobtainedas g +v , @ f +v ,>k +v ,>d(cid:30) +v , = UUc2 UU UUc2 UU UUc2 UU UUc2 UU (cid:19) (cid:20) 2.3 TheMeasureofHouseholds Let{ +v ,denotethemeasureofTypeIhouseholdsofagel 5 i4>5>6>7j,andlet{ +v , Uc(cid:16) U UUc2 UU denote that of Type II households of age 2= Also, let [ +v , and [ +v , be the corre- Uc(cid:16) U UUc2 UU spondingcumulativemeasures. 9
Description: