MAKING A LIVING IN THE MIDDLE AGES Christopher Dyer is director of the Centre for english local history in the University of leicester. among his recent publications are An Age of Transition?: Economy and Society in England in the Later Middle Ages (2005), and The Self- Contained Village, edited with harold Fox and nigel goose (2007). he has been president of the society for medieval archaeology and of the British agricultural history society. he was awarded the CBe in 2008. THE NEW ECONOMIC HISTORY OF BRITAIN Making a Living in the Middle Ages THE PEOPLE OF BRITAIN 850–1520 CHRISTOPHER DYER YALE UNIVERSITY PRESS NEW HAVEN AND LONDON The New Economic History of Britain General Editor: David Cannadine Copyright © 2002 by Christopher Dyer First printed in paperback (US) 2005 First printed in paperback (UK) 2009 The right of Christopher Dyer to be identified as the author of this work has been asserted by him in accordance with the Copyright, Designs and Patents Act 1988. All rights reserved. This book may not be reproduced in whole or in part, in any form (beyond that copying permitted by Sections 107 and 108 of the U.S. Copyright Law and except by reviewers for the public press) without written permission from the publishers. For information about this and other Yale University Press publications, please contact: U.S. Office: Contents Preface INTRODUCTION Approaching the economic history of medieval Britain PART ONE Origins of the medieval economy, c.850–c.1100 1 Living on the land, c.850–c.1050 i. Farming ii. Expansion iii. Estates and lords iv. Peasants 2 Crisis and new directions, c.850–c.1050 i. The Viking invasions ii. The growth of the state iii. The origins of towns 3 Conquest, c.1050–c.1100 i. Old aristocracy ii. New aristocracy iii. England in 1086 PART TWO Expansion and crisis, c.1100–c.1350 4 Lords, c.1100–c.1315 i. Aristocracy and property ii. Managing the estate iii. Lords and peasants iv. Lords and towns v. Knights and gentry vi. Aristocratic achievement? 5 Peasants, c.1100–c.1315 i. Families and population ii. Peasants and their holdings iii. Peasants and the market iv. Peasants and lords v. Individuals and communities 6 Towns and commerce, c.1100–c.1315 i. Urban expansion ii. The urban environment iii. Urban occupations iv. Techniques of trade and manufacture v. Urban government vi. Towns in a feudal economy 7 Crisis, c.1290–c.1350 i. Great Famine and Black Death ii. Contraction and change iii. Historical debate iv. Crisis in Scotland v. Explanations PART THREE Making a new world, c.1350–c.1520 8 The Black Death and its aftermath, c.1348–c.1520 i. Plague and population, c.1348–c.1520 ii. Low population, c.1348–c.1400 iii. Revolts iv. The economy, c.1348–c.1400 9 Towns, trade and industry, c.1350–c.1520 i. Urban fortunes ii. Urban economies iii. Consumers iv. Old and new 10 The countryside, c.1350–c.1520 i. Landlords ii. Gentry iii. Farmers iv. Peasants Conclusion Further reading Index Illustrations Maps 1. A woodland village and its fields: Great Hampden, Buckinghamshire 2. Distribution of nucleated villages 3. A champion village and its fields: Crimscote, Warwickshire 4. A great estate: Meddyfnych, Carmarthenshire 5. Town plans of a) Winchester and b) Northampton 6. Boroughs in Domesday Book (1086) 7. Distribution of population according to Domesday Book (1086) 8. Examples of estates in the twelfth and thirteenth centuries 9. Scottish burghs in existence by 1300 10. Debts owed to Londoners, c.1400 11. Changes in the distribution of lay wealth, 1334 and 1515 Figures 1. Grain prices in England, 1160–1520 2. English population, 850–1550 3. Wage rates in England, 1210–1520 4. English exports of wool and cloth, 1279–1544 Preface This book surveys the society and economy of medieval Britain. It covers the seven centuries from the Vikings to the Reformation, and it aims to deal with Britain, that is England, Scotland and Wales. I have approached the subject by seeking to understand the perspective of those who lived at the time. Changes in the society and economy came about because men and women, as individuals or in groups, made decisions and acted accordingly. We can therefore appreciate why they behaved and acted as they did if we can reconstruct their thinking in the light of their circumstances. Such an exercise requires some imagination, as one of the purposes of this book is to explore the economic contribution of the working population, who are not very fully documented. This is difficult, but is intended to add to the interest of the book, and in the same spirit while scholarly debates and controversies are reflected in these pages, they will be presented without lengthy accounts of the views of contending schools of historians. The writing consciously avoids jargon and technicalities and the more specialized terms will be explained when they are first mentioned. A book dealing with a long period and many themes is inevitably the product of many years of research, reading, listening and conversation. I could not possibly name the dozens of people who have helped me in various ways, and I hope that they will understand and forgive the omission. The only exception must be Rodney Hilton, whose early tuition and later advice has been an influence and inspiration. To focus on those who helped specifically with the production of this book, David Cannadine suggested that I write it, and commented helpfully on a first draft. I was advised and encouraged by the editors for Penguin and Yale, Simon Winder and Robert Baldock. Chapters were read and improved by Dawn Hadley, Keith Stringer, Phillipp Schofield and two anonymous readers. The final version of the typescript was prepared by Sue Bowen and Nancy Moore. Jenny Dyer read drafts and helped in other ways. John and Geraldine Brown gave me hospitality when I worked in Edinburgh. Help with preparing illustrations came from Duncan Brown, Bob Croft, Geoff Egan and Andy Isham. Candida Brazil of Yale University Press gave care and encouragement. The University of Birmingham and the Arts and Humanities Research Board allowed me a generous period of study leave. Christopher Dyer Birmingham, April 2001 Note on the text. Places are identified here with reference to the counties before the reorganization of local government in the 1970s. Money, length, distance, area, volume and weight are given in measures prevailing before metrication. There were 240d (pence) in a pound (£1), and 12d (pence) made a shilling (1s). To gain a sense of the value of money, a cow could be bought for about 24d (2s) or 36d (3s) before 1200, and between 6s and 11s after that date. A foot is equivalent to 0.3 metre, a yard to 0.9 metre, and a mile to 1.6 kilometres. An acre is 0.4 hectare. Grain was measured in bushels (36 litres) and wine in gallons (4.5 litres). Wool and tin were weighed in pounds (0.45 kilogramme). Introduction Approaching the economic history of medieval Britain We should explore the economic history of medieval Britain for many reasons. It is the only branch of history which gives pride of place to the whole population, and through the study of the economy we can understand the everyday lives of working people. The economy was important. All other human endeavours depended on the production of food and other goods, which means that any investigation of non-material things must take into account the material base. Economic history is a unifying subject, not taking us into an obscure byway of the past, but acting as a crossroads from which we gain access to the history of the environment, culture, politics and thought. Economic historians are concerned with two types of change. One focuses on the ups and downs of economic life, both the short-term fluctuations in prices and trade, and the long-run movements of growth and decline. The other is concerned with the structural changes, such as the emergence of towns, or the shifts in the distribution of land and the control of farming between social groups. Both are necessary for understanding the course of history. Why go back to such a remote period? The past has always attracted our curiosity, and there is no reason to think that the period before 1520 offers us any less interest than the twentieth century or any other period in between. Medieval people were as lively, active and complicated as at any other time, and they are as worthy of our attention as those of later centuries. They pose at least as many dilemmas and puzzles of interpretation. Indeed there is a particular fascination in revealing the thoughts and actions of people living in an age unlike our own, when most people worked on the land, and were dominated by an aristocracy and an all-embracing church. The past fascinates us because it was different, and the middle ages were very different. Lastly, but not least, later periods cannot be fully understood if we do not appreciate their predecessors. We owe the majority of our villages and towns, boundaries, roads and institutions to the middle ages. The words that we use to describe economic life, such as farmer, wages, fees, capital and interest were all used (often with distinct