ebook img

Macroeconomic Theory PDF

308 Pages·2012·1.726 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Macroeconomic Theory

Macroeconomic Theory Dirk Krueger1 Department of Economics University of Pennsylvania January 26, 2012 1I am grateful to my teachers in Minnesota, V.V Chari, Timothy Kehoe and Ed- ward Prescott, my ex-colleagues at Stanford, Robert Hall, Beatrix Paal and Tom Sargent, my colleagues at UPenn Hal Cole, Jeremy Greenwood, Randy Wright and Iourii Manovski and my co-authors Juan Carlos Conesa, Jesus Fernandez-Villaverde, Felix Kubler and Fabrizio Perri as well as Victor Rios-Rull for helping me to learn modern macroeconomic theory. These notes were tried out on numerous students at Stanford, UPenn, Frankfurt and Mannheim, whose many useful comments I appreci- ate. Kaiji Chen and Antonio Doblas-Madrid provided many important corrections to these notes. ii Contents 1 Overview and Summary 1 2 A Simple Dynamic Economy 5 2.1 General Principles for Specifying a Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 2.2 An Example Economy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 2.2.1 De(cid:133)nition of Competitive Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . 8 2.2.2 Solving for the Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 2.2.3 Pareto Optimality and the First Welfare Theorem . . . . 11 2.2.4 Negishi(cid:146)s (1960) Method to Compute Equilibria . . . . . . 14 2.2.5 Sequential Markets Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 18 2.3 Appendix: Some Facts about Utility Functions . . . . . . . . . . 24 2.3.1 Time Separability . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 2.3.2 Time Discounting . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 24 2.3.3 Standard Properties of the Period Utility Function . . . . 25 2.3.4 Constant Relative Risk Aversion (CRRA) Utility . . . . . 25 2.3.5 Homotheticity and Balanced Growth . . . . . . . . . . . . 28 3 The Neoclassical Growth Model in Discrete Time 31 3.1 Setup of the Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 31 3.2 Optimal Growth: Pareto Optimal Allocations . . . . . . . . . . . 32 3.2.1 Social Planner Problem in Sequential Formulation . . . . 33 3.2.2 Recursive Formulation of Social Planner Problem . . . . . 35 3.2.3 An Example . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 3.2.4 The Euler Equation Approach and Transversality Condi- tions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 3.2.5 Steady States and the Modi(cid:133)ed Golden Rule . . . . . . . 52 3.2.6 A Remark About Balanced Growth . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 3.3 Competitive Equilibrium Growth . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 55 3.3.1 De(cid:133)nition of Competitive Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . 56 3.3.2 Characterization of the Competitive Equilibrium and the Welfare Theorems . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 58 3.3.3 Sequential Markets Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 3.3.4 Recursive Competitive Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 3.4 Mapping the Model to Data: Calibration . . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 iii iv CONTENTS 4 Mathematical Preliminaries 71 4.1 Complete Metric Spaces . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 72 4.2 Convergence of Sequences . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 73 4.3 The Contraction Mapping Theorem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 77 4.4 The Theorem of the Maximum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 83 5 Dynamic Programming 85 5.1 The Principle of Optimality . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 85 5.2 Dynamic Programming with Bounded Returns . . . . . . . . . . 92 6 Models with Risk 95 6.1 Basic Representation of Risk . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 95 6.2 De(cid:133)nitions of Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 97 6.2.1 Arrow-Debreu Market Structure . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98 6.2.2 Pareto E¢ ciency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100 6.2.3 Sequential Markets Market Structure. . . . . . . . . . . . 101 6.2.4 Equivalence between Market Structures . . . . . . . . . . 102 6.2.5 Asset Pricing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 102 6.3 Markov Processes . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 104 6.4 Stochastic Neoclassical Growth Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106 7 The Two Welfare Theorems 109 7.1 What is an Economy? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109 7.2 Dual Spaces . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 112 7.3 De(cid:133)nition of Competitive Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 114 7.4 The Neoclassical Growth Model in Arrow-Debreu Language . . . 115 7.5 A Pure Exchange Economy in Arrow-Debreu Language . . . . . 117 7.6 The First Welfare Theorem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119 7.7 The Second Welfare Theorem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120 7.8 Type Identical Allocations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128 8 The Overlapping Generations Model 129 8.1 A Simple Pure Exchange Overlapping Generations Model . . . . 130 8.1.1 Basic Setup of the Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131 8.1.2 Analysis of the Model Using O⁄er Curves . . . . . . . . . 136 8.1.3 Ine¢ cient Equilibria . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 143 8.1.4 Positive Valuation of Outside Money . . . . . . . . . . . . 148 8.1.5 Productive Outside Assets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 150 8.1.6 Endogenous Cycles . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152 8.1.7 Social Security and Population Growth . . . . . . . . . . 154 8.2 The Ricardian Equivalence Hypothesis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160 8.2.1 In(cid:133)nite Lifetime Horizon and Borrowing Constraints . . . 161 8.2.2 Finite Horizon and Operative Bequest Motives . . . . . . 170 8.3 Overlapping Generations Models with Production. . . . . . . . . 175 8.3.1 Basic Setup of the Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 175 8.3.2 Competitive Equilibrium . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 176 CONTENTS v 8.3.3 Optimality of Allocations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 183 8.3.4 The Long-Run E⁄ects of Government Debt . . . . . . . . 187 9 Continuous Time Growth Theory 193 9.1 Stylized Growth and Development Facts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193 9.1.1 Kaldor(cid:146)s Growth Facts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194 9.1.2 Development Facts from the Summers-Heston Data Set . 194 9.2 The Solow Model and its Empirical Evaluation . . . . . . . . . . 199 9.2.1 The Model and its Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 202 9.2.2 Empirical Evaluation of the Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . 204 9.3 The Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 215 9.3.1 MathematicalPreliminaries: Pontryagin(cid:146)sMaximumPrin- ciple . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 215 9.3.2 Setup of the Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 215 9.3.3 Social Planners Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 217 9.3.4 Decentralization . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 226 9.4 Endogenous Growth Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 231 9.4.1 The Basic AK-Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 231 9.4.2 Models with Externalities . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 235 9.4.3 Models of Technological Progress Based on Monopolistic Competition: Variant of Romer (1990) . . . . . . . . . . . 248 10 Bewley Models 261 10.1 Some Stylized Facts about the Income and Wealth Distribution in the U.S.. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 262 10.1.1 Data Sources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 262 10.1.2 Main Stylized Facts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 263 10.2 The Classic Income Fluctuation Problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . 269 10.2.1 Deterministic Income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 270 10.2.2 Stochastic Income and Borrowing Limits. . . . . . . . . . 278 10.3 Aggregation: Distributions as State Variables . . . . . . . . . . . 282 10.3.1 Theory . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 282 10.3.2 Numerical Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 289 11 Fiscal Policy 293 11.1 Positive Fiscal Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 293 11.2 Normative Fiscal Policy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 293 11.2.1 Optimal Policy with Commitment . . . . . . . . . . . . . 293 11.2.2 TheTimeConsistencyProblemandOptimalFiscalPolicy without Commitment . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 293 12 Political Economy and Macroeconomics 295 13 References 297 vi CONTENTS Chapter 1 Overview and Summary After a quick warm-up for dynamic general equilibrium models in the (cid:133)rst part ofthecoursewewilldiscussthetwoworkhorsesofmodernmacroeconomics,the neoclassical growth model with in(cid:133)nitely lived consumers and the Overlapping Generations (OLG) model. This (cid:133)rst part will focus on techniques rather than issues; one (cid:133)rst has to learn a language before composing poems. I will (cid:133)rst present a simple dynamic pure exchange economy with two in- (cid:133)nitely lived consumers engaging in intertemporal trade. In this model the connectionbetweencompetitive equilibriaandParetooptimalequilibriacanbe easily demonstrated. Furthermore it will be demonstrated how this connec- tion can exploited to compute equilibria by solving a particular social planners problem, an approach developed (cid:133)rst by Negishi (1960) and discussed nicely by Kehoe (1989). This model with then enriched by production (and simpli(cid:133)ed by dropping one of the two agents), to give rise to the neoclassical growth model. This model will (cid:133)rst be presented in discrete time to discuss discrete-time dynamic programming techniques; both theoretical as well as computational in nature. The main reference will be Stokey et al., chapters 2-4. As a (cid:133)rst economic application the model will be enriched by technology shocks to develop the Real Business Cycle (RBC) theory of business cycles. Cooley and Prescott (1995) are a good reference for this application. In order to formulate the stochastic neoclassical growth model notation for dealing with uncertainty will be developed. This discussion will motivate the two welfare theorems, which will then be presented for quite general economies in which the commodity space may be in(cid:133)nite-dimensional. We will draw on Stokey et al., chapter 15(cid:146)s discussion of Debreu (1954). Thenexttwotopicsarelogicalextensionsoftheprecedingmaterial. Wewill (cid:133)rst discuss the OLG model, due to Samuelson (1958) and Diamond (1965). The(cid:133)rstmainfocusinthismodulewillbethetheoreticalresultsthatdistinguish theOLGmodelfromthestandardArrow-Debreumodelofgeneralequilibrium: in the OLG model equilibria may not be Pareto optimal, (cid:133)at money may have 1 2 CHAPTER 1. OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY positive value, for a given economy there may be a continuum of equilibria (and the core of the economy may be empty). All this could not happen in the standard Arrow-Debreu model. References that explain these di⁄erences in detail include Geanakoplos (1989) and Kehoe (1989). Our discussion of these issues will largely consist of examples. One reason to develop the OLG model was the uncomfortable assumption of in(cid:133)nitely lived agents in the standard neoclassical growth model. Barro (1974) demonstrated under which conditions (operativebequestmotives)anOLGeconomywillbeequivalenttoaneconomy with in(cid:133)nitely lived consumers. One main contribution of Barro was to provide a formal justi(cid:133)cation for the assumption of in(cid:133)nite lives. As we will see this methodological contribution has profound consequences for the macroeconomic e⁄ects of government debt, reviving the Ricardian Equivalence proposition. As a prelude we will brie(cid:135)y discuss Diamond(cid:146)s (1965) analysis of government debt in an OLG model. In the next module we will discuss the neoclassical growth model in con- tinuous time to develop continuous time optimization techniques. After having learned the technique we will review the main developments in growth the- ory and see how the various growth models fare when being contrasted with the main empirical (cid:133)ndings from the Summers-Heston panel data set. We will brie(cid:135)y discuss the Solow model and its empirical implications (using the arti- cle by Mankiw et al. (1992) and Romer, chapter 2), then continue with the Ramsey model (Intriligator, chapter 14 and 16, Blanchard and Fischer, chapter 2). In this model growth comes about by introducing exogenous technological progress. Wewillthenreviewthemaincontributionsofendogenousgrowththe- ory, (cid:133)rst by discussing the early models based on externalities (Romer (1986), Lucas (1988)), then models that explicitly try to model technological progress (Romer (1990). All the models discussed up to this point usually assumed that individuals are identical within each generation (or that markets are complete), so that without loss of generality we could assume a single representative consumer (within each generation). This obviously makes life easy, but abstracts from a lotofinterestingquestionsinvolvingdistributionalaspectsofgovernmentpolicy. In the next section we will discuss a model that is capable of addressing these issues. There is a continuum of individuals. Individuals are ex-ante identical (have the same stochastic income process), but receive di⁄erent income realiza- tionsexpost. Theseincomeshocksareassumedtobeuninsurable(wetherefore depart from the Arrow-Debreu world), but people are allowed to self-insure by borrowing and lending at a risk-free rate, subject to a borrowing limit. Deaton (1991) discusses the optimal consumption-saving decision of a single individual in this environment and Aiyagari (1994) incorporates Deaton(cid:146)s analysis into a full-blowndynamicgeneralequilibriummodel. Thestatevariableforthisecon- omy turns out to be a cross-sectional distribution of wealth across individuals. This feature makes the model interesting as distributional aspects of all kinds of government policies can be analyzed, but it also makes the state space very big. A cross-sectional distribution as state variable requires new concepts (de- veloped in measure theory) for de(cid:133)ning and new computational techniques for 3 computing equilibria. The early papers therefore restricted attention to steady state equilibria (in which the cross-sectional wealth distribution remained con- stant). Very recently techniques have been developed to handle economies with distributions as state variables that feature aggregate shocks, so that the cross- sectional wealth distribution itself varies over time. Krusell and Smith (1998) is the key reference. Applications of their techniques to interesting policy ques- tions could be very rewarding in the future. If time permits I will discuss such an application due to Heathcote (1999). For the next two topics we will likely not have time; and thus the corre- sponding lecture notes are work in progress. So far we have not considered how government policies a⁄ect equilibrium allocations and prices. In the next modules this question is taken up. First we discuss (cid:133)scal policy and we start with positive questions: how does the governments(cid:146)decision to (cid:133)nance a given streamofexpenditures(debtvs. taxes)a⁄ectmacroeconomicaggregates(Barro (1974),Ohanian(1997))?;howdoesgovernmentspendinga⁄ectoutput(Baxter andKing(1993))? Inthisdiscussiongovernmentpolicyistakenasexogenously given. The next question is of normative nature: how should a benevolent gov- ernment carry out (cid:133)scal policy? The answer to this question depends crucially on the assumption of whether the government can commit to its policy. A gov- ernmentthatcancommittoitsfuturepoliciessolvesaclassicalRamseyproblem (not to be confused with the Ramsey model); the main results on optimal (cid:133)scal policy are reviewed in Chari and Kehoe (1999). Kydland and Prescott (1977) pointed out the dilemma a government faces if it cannot commit to its policy -this is the famous time consistency problem. How a benevolent government that cannot commit should carry out (cid:133)scal policy is still very much an open question. Klein and Rios-Rull (1999) have made substantial progress in an- swering this question. Note that we throughout our discussion assume that the governmentactsinthebestinterestofitscitizens. Whathappensifpoliciesare instead chosen by votes of sel(cid:133)sh individuals is discussed in the last part of the course. As discussed before we assumed so far that government policies were either (cid:133)xedexogenouslyorsetbyabenevolentgovernment(thatcanorcan(cid:146)tcommit). Nowwerelaxthisassumptionanddiscusspolitical-economicequilibriainwhich peoplenotonlyactrationallywithrespecttotheireconomicdecisions, butalso rationally with respect to their voting decisions that determine macroeconomic policy. Obviouslywe(cid:133)rsthadtodiscussmodelswithheterogeneousagentssince with homogeneous agents there is no political con(cid:135)ict and hence no interesting di⁄erences between the Ramsey problem and a political-economic equilibrium. This area of research is not very far developed and we will only present two examples (Krusell et al. (1997), Alesina and Rodrik (1994)) that deal with the question of capital taxation in a dynamic general equilibrium model in which the capital tax rate is decided upon by repeated voting. 4 CHAPTER 1. OVERVIEW AND SUMMARY

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.