Lectu re Notes in Economics and Mathematical Systems Managing Editors: M. Beckmann and H. P. KUnzi Mathematical Economics 167 Malte Faber Introduction to Modern Austrian Capital Theory Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg New York 1979 Editorial Board H. Albach· A. V. Balakrishnan' M. Beckmann (Managing Editor) p. Dhrymes . J. Green' W. Hildenbrand' W. Krelle H. P. Kunzi (Managing Editor) . K. Ritter' R. Sato . H. Schelbert p. Schonfeld Managing Editors Prof. Dr. M. Beckmann Prof. Dr. H. P. Kunzi Brown University Universitat Zurich Providence, RI 02912/USA 8090 Zurich/Schweiz Author Prof. Dr. Malte Faber Alfred-Weber-Institut der Universitat Heidelberg Seminargebaude Grabengasse 14 6900 Heidelberg/FRG AMS Subject Classifications (1970): 90-02, 90A99 ISBN-13: 978-3-540-09121-9 e-ISBN-13: 978-3-642-48310-3 001: 10.1007/978-3-642-48310-3 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically those of translation, re printing, re-use of illustrations, broadcasting, reproduction by photocopying machine or similar means, and storage in data banks. Under § 54 of the German Copyright Law where copies are made for other tban private use, a fee is payable to the publisher, the amount of the fee to be determined by agreement with the publisher. © by Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1979 2142/3140-543210 To Peter Bernholz mentor and friend Preface During the fifties and the sixties the neoclassical concept of the production function was criticized in numerous papers. In particular, the aggregation of different capital goods into a single number was reprehended. A second essential disadvantage, namely the neglect of the time structure of the production process, found, however, rela tively little attention. While up to the thirties the Austrian capital theory which stressed the time aspect of production was an important school, it fell into oblivion after the great capital controversies of the thirties. It took over thirty years, i.e. till the beginning of the seventies be fore it came to a renaissance of the Austrian capital theory by var ious writers. We may roughly classify the different attempts of Hits rebirth in modern economics" into three groups: 1. The approach of ~ [1970, 1973, 1973a] has received most of the attention in the literature (Burmeister [1974], Faber [1975], Fehl [1975], ~[1975], Hagemann and ~ [1976]). It will be shown in Chapter 9 that ~ is only in so far a Neo-Austrian as he does explicitly take into consideration the vertical time structure of the production process. But he does not use the Austrian concepts of superiority of roundabout methods, of time preference and of the period of production. 2. The latter concept has been revived by the second group, to which Tintner [1970], von Weizs~cker [1971a, 1971b, 1974], ~ [1971, 1976 and ~ [1973, 1975, 1976] belong. The discussion of the thirties mentioned above, however, showed that the period of pro duction is a dubious tool for the analysis of problems of capital theory (see e.g. Morgenstern [1935]). 3. The authors forming the third group try to employ the concepts of superiority of roundabout methods and of time preference to prove that the rate of interest is positive. Jaksch [1975a, 1975b] shows in a linear multiperiod multisector model that investment implies a positive rate of interest under certain rather strong conditions. In contrast to ~, Bernholz [1971] started with a linear two-period two-sector model which has successively been extended by Bernholz and the present writer in a series of papers during the last seven years. In addition we have tried to relate our neo-Austrian approach to the Marxian labor theory of value, the von Neumann-model, neoclassical growth theory and Hicks' neo-Austrian theory of capital. VI Bernholz [1971] began with a rather intuitive concept of superiority of roundabout methods, which we grad~ally deve19ped into a rigorous form. Since we broke, in some respects, new ground, it is not surpris ing that some readers had difficulties to understand our papers. Of course, these were aggravated by the fact that we continuously changed our definitions and notations. The present author, therefore, thought it to be appropriate to unify our papers and to supplement several missing links in such a way that our approach is accessibl~ in the form of a text-book. A further reason for the publication of this volume was that some of the relevant material was only accessi~le to German speaking readers. After the introduction, von Bohm-Bawerk's theory of capital and interest is presented. For this purpose I use the interpretations by Wicksell [1893], Dorfman [1958/59, 1959] and ~ [1967]. To my mind, the further development of the traditional Austrian capital theory is best stated by a presentation of an article by von Stackelberg [1941/ 43], which at the same time may be considered a temporary termination of this school of thought. Von Stackelberg develops four models, in which not only the questions put forward by Wicksell and Akerman are examined, but the problem of recycling (Rtickversetzung) of goods is analyzed as well. Since von Stackelberg's important contribution is entirely unknown in the English literature (the same is almost true for the German one), I have presented it in detail. A critical assess ment of the traditional Austrian theory of capital and interest closes Chapter 2. The von Neumann-model is described in Chapter 3. Special emphasis is put on its assumptions and its economic interpretation. It will be shown that von Neumann's approach already indicated a way out of the dead-ends in which the Austrian capital and interest theory found itself at the end of the thirties. Having set the stage in Part I, it is demonstrated in Part II how the law of greater productivity of roundabout production can be introduced in a modified special case of the generalized von Neumann-model, namely a generalized Leontief technology. In Chapter 4 a two-period two-sector model is employed to introduce the ideas of our neo-Austrian approach: the model is extended to n periods in Chapter 5. It is generalized to a multi sector model in Chapter 6, however, with the restriction that there is an economic horizon of only two periods. (Work is in progress to generalize it: see ~ [1978]). While the production programs are not restricted to the class of proportional ones (steady states) in Chapter 4 to 6, they are restricted to stationary programs in Chapter 7, where I take up the famous controversy between von Bohm-Bawerk and VII schumpeter on the zero rate of interest in a stationary economy. Some relationships between other approaches to capital theory and ours are shown in Part III. The neoclassical steady state theory is dealt with in Chapter 8 and Hicks' approach in Chapter 9. Bernholz and myself [1971, 197~] have also related our approach to the labor theory of value. Since Bernholz [1972, Chapter 3, pp.85-95] has already treated this subject in a text-book and since there has been a voluminous literature on the labor theory of value\during the last decade, it did not seem to be necessary to deal with it once again. The absence of a discussion of the Cambria!e U.K. theory of capital explains itself quite different. I accept it to be a deficiency of this book and can only apologize for this with the proverb that "Rome was not built in a day." Perhaps I have also been influenced by a letter from Professor Joan Robinson in which she wrote to me: "I am afraid it is a hopeless task to reconcile the Sraffa system with BOhm-Bawerk because they take different views of the operation of the capitalist system." I, however, am not quite so pessimistic in that respect, since there seems to be a relationship between Sraffa's and our approach via the von Neumann-model' (see Burmeis'ter [1974] and Schefold [1978]). The manuscript for this book was used for a course at the Univer sity of Heidelberg in winter-semester 1977/78. Thus the problems at the end of each chapter have been tested. The students were in the 'Hauptstudium', i.e. senior undergraduate level and first year gradu ate students. Though mathematical requirements consist only of an elementary form of the Kuhn-Tucker conditions and ~'s rule, the reading of this book is in some passages demanding. This holds for Chapter 5, especially Section 5.3, and in particular for Chapter 6, the multisector model. Some students told me that it helped them to start Part II with Chapter 7. Throughout this volume I have tried to make the assumptions, defini tions and propositions of all models explicit to enable the reader to compare the models more easily. I also took pains to avoid phrases like "it is easily seen';" nas the reader finds after several transfor mations." Some readers, therefore, may find some derivations too lengthy. There are many persons to whom I am indebted. I hope that the ded ication of this book gives the reader an impression how much lowe to Peter Bernholz. As stated above, his 1971 paper gave rise to our VIII collaboration. A rendition of this article is presented in Chapter 4. A comparison of this chapter with the following three chapters of Part II shows how much it influenced our later research. It should, however, be mentioned that Peter Bernholz has actually continued his earlier research on Austrian capital theory in 1971, since he wrote his dissertation on the law of greater productivity of roundabout methods in 1955 and two papers on impatience to consume in 1964 and 1965. Besides Peter Bernholz I would like to thank also my co-authors Johann Irsigler, Winfried Reiss, and Gunther Stephan for letting me use material from previously published joint articles. Furthe~ I am grateful to Klaus Jaeger [1974], Hans Jurgen Jaksch [1975a] and 2£! Schweizer [1978], who took up in one form or the other papers by ~ holz and me. Their valuable criticisms and constructive suggestions helped and stimulated us in many respects. I am also grateful to my students, in particular to my English speaking ones, Grover Mc Arthur and Anthony Sagoe, who corrected my English; Gregory Capellari translated the second and third chapters into English. My assistants Friedrich Breyer, Alexander Gerybadze, Johann Irsig l!E, Gerhard Pross, Winfried Reiss supported me in various ways to prepare the manuscript. Johann Irsigler helped to formulate the prob lems at the end of each chapter. Friedrich Breyer and Johann Irsigler carefully read three versions of the manuscript, which led to a con siderable mathematical, economic and stylistic improvement. Joachim Weisbrod proofread the whole manuscript. Of course, I assume full responsibility for any remaining errors. Thanks are due to Wolfgang KBstlin, who enabled me in various ways to spend more time on capital theory than would have been possible without his help. I gratefully acknowledge the permission of the publishers of Kyklos, Zeitschrift fUr die gesamte Staatswissenschaft and Journal of Economic Theory for letting me use material previously published. Finally I thank Hanna Streubel for her accurate and most of all patient typing of various versions of the manuscript. Con ten t s PART I: AUSTRIAN CAPITAL THEORY AND THE VON NEUMANN-MODEL 1. Introduction 3 1.1 Problems 7 2. The Austrian Theory of Interest 10 2.1 von B5hm-Bawerk 10 2.2 von Stackelberg 20 2.3 An Assessment of Austrian Interest Theory 29 2.4 Problems 34 3. The von Neumann-Model and its Relations to Austrian Capital and Interest Theory 38 3.1 Introduction 38 3.2 The Meaning, Import and Historical Point of Departure of the Ideas of the von Neumann-Model 38 3.3 The von Neumann-Model 40 3.4 Criticism and Generalization of the von Neumann_ Model 51 3.5 Solutions to Problems of Austrian Capital Theory 53 3.6 The Interest Rate in the Stationary State 55 3.7 Problems 56 PART II: MODERN AUSTRIAN CAPITAL THEORY 4. A Two-Period Two-Sector Neo-Austrian Model 61 4.1 Outline of the Procedure 61 4.2 The Technology 61 4.3 The Transformation Curve 64 4.4 Condition for Roundaboutness 70 4.5 Condition for Superiority 71 4.6 Prices in a Planned Economy 73 4.7 The Rate of Interest in a Planned Economy 77 4.8 Decentralizing the Decisions 85 4.9 Problems 87 5. A Multiperiod Two-Sector Model 90 5.1 Extension of the Model 90 5.2 A Model with n-Period Horizon 90 5.3 A Model with Two Techniques Using a Capital Good 98 5.3.1 The Model 98 x 5.3.2 The Sign of the Rate of Interest 104 5.4 Problems 109 6. A Multisector Model 111 6.1 The Problem and the Main Results 111 6.2 The Model 113 6.3 Superiority, Roundaboutness and Positive Rate 117 of Interest 6.4 A Finite Economic Horizon with More than ~wo Periods 128 129 6.5 Problems 7. The Schumpeter-von Bohm-Bawerk Controversy on the Rate of Interest in the Stationary State 131 131 7.1 Introduction 7.2 The Origins of the Controversy 133 135 7.3 The Rate of Interest in a Stationary State 140 7.4 Schumpeter's Dynamic Theory of Interest 142 7.5 Problems PART III: RELATIONSHIP TO OTHER APPROACHES TO CAPITAL THEORY 8. A Comparison with Results of Neoclassical Capital and Growth Theory 145 8.1 Introduction 145 8.2 A Simple Growth Model 145 8.3 A Neoclassical Version for Steady States 150 8.3.1 Factor-Price Frontier for T~ and T~ 150 8.3.2 Factor-Price Frontier for Tl and T2 154 8.3.3 Consumption-Growth Frontier 155 8.3.4 The Relationship between the Interest Rate and the Growth Rate 157 8.4 Charcteristics of Optimal Steady State Programs 159 8.5 Problems 163 9. Hicks' Neo-Austrian Theory of Capital 164 9.1 Introduction 164 9.2 Hicks' Model 166 9.3 The Index of Improvement in Efficiency 168 9.4 Hicks' New Classification of Technological Change 169 9.5 Superiority and the Index of Efficiency 174 9.6 Concluding Remarks 178 9.7 Problems 179 References 181 Author Index 192 Subject Index 194 Part I: AUSTRIAN CAPITAL THEORY AND THE VON NEUMANN-MODEL