Lecture Notes in Economies and Mathematical Systems 435 Founding Editors: M. Beckmann H. P. Künzi Editorial Board: H. Albach, M. Beckmann, G. Feichtinger, W. Güth, W. Hildenbrand, W. KrelIe, H. P. Künzi, K. Ritter, U. Schittko, P. Schönfeld, R. Selten Managing Editors: Prof. Dr. G. Fandei Fachbereich Wirtschaftswissenschaften Fernuniversität Hagen Feithstr. 140/AVZ 11, D-58097 Hagen, Germany Prof. Dr. W. Trockel Institut für Mathematische Wirtschaftsforschung (IMW) Universität Bielefeld Universitätsstr. 25, D-33615 Bielefeld, Germany Springer Berlin Heidelberg NewYork Barcelona Budapest HongKong London Milan Paris Santa Clara Singapore Tokyo Lin ehen Interest Rate Dynamies, Derivatives Pricing, and Risk Management Springer Author School of Accountancy and Economics Nanyang Technological University Nanyang Avenue Singapore 639798 Cataloging-in-Publication Data applied for Die Deutsche Bibliothek - CIP-Einheitsaufnahme ehen, Lin: Interest rate dynamics, derivatives pricing, and risk management / Lin Chen_ - Berlin ; Heidelberg ; New York ; London ; Paris ; Tokyo ; Hong Kong ; Barcelona ; Budapest : Springer, 1996 (Lecture notes in economics and mathematical systems ; 435) NE:GT ISBN-13: 978-3-540-60814-1 e-ISBN-13: 978-3-642-46825-4 001: 10.1007/978-3-642-46825-4 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved, whether the whole or part of the material is concemed, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, re-use of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other way, and storage in data banks. Duplication of this publication or parts thereof is permitted only under the provisions ofthe German Copyright Law of September 9, 1965, in its current version, and permission for use must always be obtained from Springer-Verlag. Violations are liable for prosecution under the German Copyright Law. © Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg 1996 'JYpesetting: Camera ready by author SPIN: 10568953 42/3111-54321-Printed on acid-free paper Preface There are two types of tenn structure models in the literature: the equilibrium models and the no-arbitrage models. And there are, correspondingly, two types of interest rate derivatives pricing fonnulas based on each type of model of the tenn structure. The no-arbitrage models are characterized by the work of Ho and Lee (1986), Heath, Jarrow, and Morton (1992), Hull and White (1990 and 1993), and Black, Dennan and Toy (1990). Ho and Lee (1986) invent the no-arbitrage approach to the tenn structure modeling in the sense that the model tenn structure can fit the initial (observed) tenn structure of interest rates. There are a number of disadvantages with their model. First, the model describes the whole volatility structure by a sin gle parameter, implying a number of unrealistic features. Furthennore, the model does not incorporate mean reversion. Black-Dennan-Toy (1990) develop a model along tbe lines of Ho and Lee. They eliminate some of the problems of Ho and Lee (1986) but create a new one: for a certain specification of the volatility function, the short rate can be mean-fteeting rather than mean-reverting. Heath, Jarrow and Morton (1992) (HJM) construct a family of continuous models of the term struc ture consistent with the initial tenn structure data. Unfortunately, the interest rate models that result from the HJM approach is usually non-Markov (the distribution of interest rates in the next period depends not only on the current rate but also on the rates in the earlier periods). There are only a small number of known forward rate volatility functions that give rise to Markov models. Moreover, except for a few simple cases, it is difficult to obtain closed fonn solutions for the values of bond and interest rate derivatives. The approach of Hull and White (1990 and 1993) to the no-arbitrage model is to extend the equilibrium models by letting parameters be time-varying. These generalized tenn structure models have more ftexibility to fit a given yield curve and the tenn structure of volatility. However, except for the extended Vasicek model, their approach provides no closed fonn solution and has to rely on numerical methods. Generally speaking, the main problem with the no-arbitrage approach to the tenn structure models is that at any date a function for the tenn structure of interest rates needs to be estimated and there is no guarantee that the estimated function will be consistent with the previously estimated function. Not surprisingly, despite the no-arbitrage approach' s ability to fit the initial tenn structure, its empirical per fonnance is quite disappointing. For example, Flesaker (1993) tests HJM's model using a Generalized Method of Moments with three years of daily data for Eurodol lar futures and futures options and shows that HJM' s approach is incompatible with the data for most sub-periods. Furthennore, Backus, Foresi and Zin (1994) discover vi Preface that the pricing of derivatives based on no-arbitrage tenn structure models can actu ally lead to systematic arbitrage opportunities as a result of its mispricing of some assets. They demonstrate that the Black-Dennan-Toy model is likely to overprice call options on long bonds when interest rates exhibit mean reversion and that this mispricing can be exploited even when no other traders offer the mispriced assets. They conclude that the time-dependent parameters cannot substitute for sound fun damentals. The equilibrium models of the tenn structure of interest rates, such as Varsicek (1977) and Cox-lngersoIl-Ross (1985) (CIR), have the important advantage that all interest rate derivatives are valued on a common basis. Nevertheless, these model tenn structures do not correctly price actual bonds. One primary reason is that there are too few model parameters to be adjusted. The other problem with their mod els is that they have not incorporated sufficient empirical realism. Their models either allow negative interest rates (Varsicek (1977», assume a constant volatility of interest rates (Varsicek (1977», or assume perfect correlation between volatil ity and the short rate (CIR 1985). Although one-factor models offer tractability, there is compelling reason to believe that a single state variable, such as the short rate, is not sufficient to capture reasonably weIl the direction of future yield curve changes. Stambaugh (1988) and Pearson and Sun (1993), among others, have docu mented more econometric evidence in favor of multi-factor models of interest rates. Brennan and Schwartz (1979) and Schaefer and Schwartz (1984) have developed two-factor tenn structure models by taking both the short rate and the long rate as factors. Longstaff and Schwartz (1992) have recently developed another two-factor model of interest rates. The choice of the model' s two factors, the short rate and the volatility of the short rate, allow interest rate derivatives prices to reftect the current levels of the short rate and volatility. However, as pointed out by some authors, the joint process of the two factors was chosen for its analytical tractability rather than its empirical realism. Also. it is argued that the interest rate \'olatility in their model is not really stochastic, as it is related to the short rate in a way similar to how the volatility is related to the short rate in CIR' s model. It is generally believed that equilibrium derivatives pricing fonnulas will be use ful for practical purposes only until substantial improvements have been made. This paper attempts to make such an improvement by bringing more empirical realism to the equilibrium models of derivatives valuation while maintaining the model' s tractability. Although our model, along with other equilibrium models, has the merit that all interest rate derivatives are valued within a unified and consistent framework, it has the disadvantage that it may not fit perfectly a given initial tenn structure. However, this problem is less severe in our model; there are ten adjustable parame ters which can be estimated to give the correct (i.e. market-priced) valuations for a Preface vii handful of actively traded bonds by calibrating the model. Then the model can price other less actively traded bonds relative to these benchmark bonds. The appealing attributes of the model presented are not only its ability to fit data better but also its ability to explicitly relate the dynamics of the short mean and volatility to the movements of the term structure and the values of interest rate derivatives. It is this very property that makes the model useful in dealing with the practical day-to-day problems of pricing derivatives and managing risks of fixed income securities. An other major desirable feature of our method is that. with the Green' s function. our approach has turned the valuation of derivative securities into a numerical integra tion. This feature has certain advantages over the currently available methods of derivatives valuation which normally deal with the solving of the valuation partial differential equation directly. Given the general issues of sensitivity and stability of numerical solutions to partial differential equation. our approach of valuing deriva tives by evaluating integrals instead of solving partial differential equation is more reliable and efficient. Acknowledgments This book is based on my dissertation submitted to Harvard University. I would like to thank the following individuals whose helps had made possible my graduate studies at Harvard and Stanford: Li Guo-G!1ang, Li Yu-Chang, Chen Yi-Sheng, John Y. Campbell, Jarnes Coleman, Sanjiv R. Das, Joseph Kalt, Glenn Loury, Robert C. Merton, F. M. Scherer, Jarnes H. Stock, Daniel W. Stroock, Nancy B. Tuma, and Louisa van Baalen. I would also like to thank Christian Gilles, Gary Anderson, Mark Fisher, Parnela Gerbino, Noah Williarns and many other supportive colleagues at the Federal Reserve Board for hel ps. LinChen Washington, D.C. USA November 1,1995 Contents 1 A Three-Factor Model of the Term Structure of Interest Rates 1 1.1 Introduction . 1 1.2 TheModel .. 4 1.3 Benchmark Case 7 1.4 Green' s Function 10 1.5 Derivatives Pricing 14 1.6 The Term Structure of Interest Rates 21 1.7 Expected Future Short Rate. 29 1.8 Forward Rates . . . . . . . . 35 2 Pricing Interest Rate Derivatives 39 2.1 Introduction . . . . . . . 39 2.2 Bond Options . . . . . . 40 2.3 Caps, Floors, and Collars 43 2.4 Futures Price and Forward Price 45 2.5 Swaps ......... . 50 2.6 Quality Delivery Options 52 2.7 Futures Options .. 55 2.8 American Options . 58 3 Pricing Exotic Options 63 3.1 Introduction.... 63 3.2 Green' s Function in the Presence of Boundaries 63 3.3 Derivatives with Payoffs at Random Times. 65 3.4 Barrier Options . . 66 3.5 Lookback Options. 67 3.6 Yield Options . . . 68 4 Fitting to a Given Term Structure 73 4.1 Introduction.......... 73 4.2 Merging to the Heath-Jarrow-Morton Framework 73 4.3 Whole-Yield Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 75 xii Contents 5 A Discrete-Time Version of the Model 77 5.1 Introduction ........... . 77 5.2 Construction ofthe Four-Dimensional Lattice 78 5.3 Applications ................. . 89 6 Estimation of the Model 95 6.1 Introduction . . . . . 95 6.2 KaIman Filter . . . . 95 6.3 Maximum Likelihood . 99 6.4 Method ofMoments 101 6.5 Simulated Moments . . 102 7 Managing Interest Rate Risk 105 7.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . 105 7.2 Generalized Duration and Convexity 107 7.3 Hedging Ratios . . . . . . . 110 7.4 Hedging: General Approach 112 7.5 Hedging Yield Curve Risk 113 8 Extensions of the Model 119 8.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119 8.2 Extension I: Jumping Mean and Diffusing Volatility . 120 8.3 Extension 11: Jumping Mean and Jumping Volatility . 122 9 Concluding Remarks 125 A Proof of Lemma 1 127 B Proof of Proposition 2 131 C Proof of Lemma 2 135 D Proof of Proposition 8 137 EIntegral Equation for Derivative Prices 141 Bibliography 143
Description: