ebook img

Institutional Imperatives of Poverty Reduction PDF

41 Pages·2009·0.21 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Institutional Imperatives of Poverty Reduction

INSTITUTIONAL IMPERATIVES OF POVERTY REDUCTION By Akmal Hussain Distinguished Professor, Beaconhouse National University Lahore Institute of Public Policy, Beaconhouse National University, Lahore ACKNOWLEDGMENTS The author wishes to thank Dr. Hafiz Pasha for his guidance and support in writing this paper. In particular his advice regarding the methodology for estimates in table 7 is appreciated, without implicating him. Also acknowledged is a debt of gratitude to Dr. Shahid J. Burki, Mr. Sartaj Aziz, Dr. Parvez Hassan and Dr. Aisha Pasha for valuable comments and suggestions on an earlier draft. Thanks are also due to Mr. Ahsan Shah for research assistance and to Mr. Muhammad Azeem for typing successive drafts. The responsibility however for the analysis, the views expressed and any errors that might remain rests with the author alone. 1 INSTITUTIONAL IMPERATIVES OF POVERTY REDUCTION By Akmal Hussain Ms. Bushra, a poor 30 year old woman, threw herself in front of a moving train in Lahore together with her two children, Saima, age 3 and Zubair, age 5. The mother is reported to have covered the eyes of her children before all three were crushed under the train. She left a suicide note written in the copy book of Zubair in the school satchel found near the site of the tragedy. In the suicide note Ms. Bushra stated poverty as the cause of her decision to commit suicide along with her children. [News Report in the daily Dawn, 13th April 2008]. He who is without empathy for the suffering of others, has no right to be called human. [Jalal-ud-Din Rumi, 1207-73] INTRODUCTION: POVERTY AND INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE The high food inflation in the last three years has pushed 11 million people into a state of hunger and poverty. Given the present trend, if no policy action is taken, an additional 22 million people will be impoverished over the next four years. (See Table 7). According to the World Food Programme Survey for the Vulnerability Analysis and Mapping Unit as many as 77 million people upto March 2008 are deemed “food insecure”1, where the food insecure population is defined as those consuming less than 2350 calories per person per day. The statistical evidence clearly shows Pakistan is in the grip of a poverty crisis. Ms. Bushra’s action stands as stark testimony of the human experience of poverty. It also poses a challenge to policy makers as much as to economists to undertake urgent policy action on the basis of a scientific analysis of the problem. 2 This paper is an attempt to provide such an analysis and the outline of possible public action to address the poverty crisis. The poor in Pakistan like all human beings have a creative potential. Yet by being denied the minimum of food and basic necessities, such as health, education and employment opportunities, they are rendered incapable of actualizing their human potential.2 In understanding this constraint to human development, the poor in Pakistan cannot simply be seen as individuals with certain adverse ‘resource endowments’, making choices in free markets. Poverty occurs when the individual in a fragmented community is locked into a nexus of power, which deprives the poor of their actual and potential income. The poor face markets, institutions and local power structures, which discriminate against access of the poor over resources, public services and governance decisions which affect their immediate existence. (A. Hussain, 2000)3. This paper provides evidence to show that the poor have unequal access over capital, land and labour markets. It is argued therefore that inequality and poverty are built into the structure of the growth process itself. It is now widely recognized that inequality adversely affects both the sustainability of growth as well as its capacity for poverty reduction (WB Report, 2006)4. The power structure, and the inequality it engenders, excludes a large proportion of the population (poor, women, the sick and the illiterate). Therefore there is a constriction of the human potential through which entrepreneurship, investment, innovation and productivity growth can occur to sustain GDP growth5. Until 2003, most studies on poverty in Pakistan had examined the problem simply in terms of measuring the number of people below certain poverty lines. However if poverty is to be overcome, it is important to understand the processes of poverty creation and to identify points of intervention in the process through which the poor can be enabled to overcome poverty on a sustainable basis. In this context some of the questions that arise are: How do distorted markets for inputs and outputs of goods and services result in the loss of the actual or potential income of the poor? How do local structures of power with respect to landlords, local administrative officials, and institutions for the provision of health, credit and dispute resolution, deprive the poor of their income, assets and the 3 fruits of their labour? These questions will be examined in section-I of this paper. Equally important for an understanding of the nature of poverty and the growth process is the question of how the institutional structures of governance and the incentive systems embodied in government policy constrain growth and poverty reduction. The argument in this paper is that poverty is rooted in the institutional structure of society and state in Pakistan. Therefore overcoming poverty will involve inducing changes in both the polity and the economy as part of an integrated process of institutional change (A. Hussain, 2008)6. As North has argued, the polity is the fundamental basis of economic performance7. This is because it is in the realm of the polity that the “rules of the game” and the associated incentive systems for the economy, are stipulated. In this paper however while acknowledging the primary role of the polity, we will focus on institutional changes in the economy as the basis of sustainable growth with equity. (North, Wallis and Weingast 2006)8. It is in moving towards a stable democratic constitutional order that Pakistan can create the institutional conditions for sustained and equitable growth: opportunities in the polity and economy for all citizens, merit based selection, competition, efficiency and innovation. Thus the path to democracy within a stable constitutional order is also the path to sustainable and equitable economic growth. In sections I and II of this paper we identify the structural factors that constrain growth and induce endemic poverty. These structural factors are located in the institutional framework that conditions both markets and governance. In section-III we briefly indicate some of the policies for institutional change in the medium term that can be undertaken to overcome the structural constraints to equitable growth. In section IV, an analysis of poverty trends during the Musharraf regime (1999-2008), is presented, together with new estimates of the impact of food inflation on poverty during the last three years to suggest that a poverty crisis is at hand. At the end of section-IV, short term policy actions for addressing the poverty crisis are outlined. 4 I. MARKETS, INSTITUTIONS AND POVERTY In this section we will examine the four features of the power structure that makes markets asymmetric to function adversely against the poor. I.1 Power, Tenancy and Tied Labour In landlord dominated areas, where landlords control the local state apparatus as well as the credit market the poor tenants are locked into a nexus of power and debt bondage with the landlord. Consequently the tenants are obliged to work part time on the landlord’s farm as labourers either at less than market wage or no wage at all. The NHDR survey data shows that 51 percent of the tenants get locked into debt dependence on the landlord, and out of these, 57 percent are obliged to work as labourers on the landlord’s farm without wages, while 14 percent work for a wage below the market rate (Hussain et.al., 2003)9. Thus the structure of power and dependence creates distortions in the labour and capital markets, which systematically deprive the poor of their actual and potential income. The consequent inefficiency in the allocation of labour and capital resources constrains agricultural growth, increases inequality and engenders persistent poverty. (See table 1). TABLE 1 LOAN DEPENDENCE ON THE LANDLORD AND LABOUR EXPLOITATION OF THE POOR PEASANTRY Extremely Poor Non-Poor Total Poor Loan from landlord (%) 50.8 29.4 11.7 34.4 Work for landlord against 14.0 24.3 5.1 16.9 wages (%) Daily wages (Rupees) 28.0 43.6 60.0 40.0 Work for landlord 57.4 38.5 25.4 43.5 without wages (%) SOURCE: NHDR/PIDE Survey 2001. 5 I.2 Power and the Double Squeeze on the Peasantry In landlord dominated areas the landlord’s power impacts the disposal of the produce by poor farm households which have direct consequences for their food consumption. As the following table 2 shows, under asymmetric tennurial arrangements, the extremely poor farmers are obliged to pay a larger proportion of their farm produce to the landlord as rent, compared to other categories of the peasantry. For example, the extremely poor have to pay 28.21% of their production value to the landlord, compared to 13.39% by the poor households and only 8.41% by the non-poor households. Consequently, the extremely poor households are forced to keep only 39.59% of their crop output for household consumption, compared to 48% by poor households and 54% by non-poor households. TABLE 2 DISPOSAL OF CROP HARVEST BY INCOME CLASS Total Paid in kind Paid as Paid to Given to Crop Sold Crop Kept Production to labour rent landlord Relatives (Value) for Own Value (Value)/Tota (Value) under share (Value)/ /Total Use/Total l Production /Total cropping Total Production Production Value* 100 Production agreement Production Value* 100 Value* 100 Value* 100 (Value)/ Value* 100 Total Production Value* 100 Extremely Poor 13864 1.45 1.10 28.21 0.09 29.57 39.59 Poor 22538 2.76 1.40 13.39 1.06 33.27 48.12 Non-Poor 37626 4.70 0.83 8.41 1.61 30.02 54.43 SOURCE: NHDR/PIDE Survey 2001. The evidence suggests that due to the relatively smaller crop share retained by the poor tenant households, they face a food deficit near the end of the year. As they run out of their household stock of food grain, they are obliged to purchase grain in the market at year end when market prices are relatively high. (Hussain, 1988)10. Such households are then faced with the necessity of borrowing for food consumption. This is also suggested 6 by the NHDR evidence, which shows that the extremely poor households borrow for food consumption (Hussain et.al., 2003)11. Poor farm households are thus placed under a double squeeze: First by the power of the landlord, who obliges them to give up a relatively larger proportion of their crop output as a crop share to the landlord. A second squeeze is placed by the seasonal variation in the market price of grain, which obliges the extremely poor households to purchase a relatively larger proportion of their food consumption requirements from the market near the end of the production cycle, when prices are high. (A. Hussain, 2004)12. I.3 Adverse Changes in Tenancy Arrangements and Poverty As the evidence suggests, since the majority of the rural poor are tenants, therefore any deterioration in tenancy arrangements would be expected to accentuate poverty. Due to weakening relative power position of poor tenants, tenancy arrangements have changed adversely against them. They now have to bear a higher proportion of input costs compared to the landlord on the tenant operated farms. The evidence shows that the contribution of tenants to input costs (for each of the major crops) such as tractor rental13, hired labour, seeds and fertilizers have increased during the period 1990-91 to 2000-01. TABLE 3 CONTRIBUTION OF TENANTS IN INPUTS PERCENTAGES 1990-91 2000-2001 Tractor Labour Seeds Fertilizer Tractor Labour Seeds Fertilizer Extremely Poor 36.3 13.8 24.8 26.0 43.5 28.5 31.0 31.8 Poor 29.5 18.8 22.8 24.5 41.3 30.5 34.5 34.0 Non-poor 39.8 25.8 28.8 27.3 44.5 32.8 38.8 34.5 Total 34.3 22.5 24.8 25.5 42.8 30.3 34.0 33.3 SOURCE: NHDR/PIDE Survey 2001. For Crop wise figures, see: Akmal Hussain et.al., UNDP- Pakistan National Human Development Report 2003, op.cit., page 64, table 16. The above evidence suggests that the adverse changes in tenancy arrangements with respect to input contributions of the tenant have become a significant structural factor in generating poverty. While the financial burden on the poor tenants has thus increased, 7 their lack of control over the timing water application, combined with adulterated inputs, keeps the yield per acre of the peasant at a low level, thereby further squeezing net incomes. I.4 Asymmetric Markets for Inputs and Outputs In the UNDP, Pakistan National Human Development Report 2003, it has been argued that local elite power structures in rural areas distort markets in favour of the rich and against the poor. The poor peasants face input and output markets where they have to pay a higher price for their inputs and get a lower price for their outputs compared to large farmers. The study showed that the poor peasants are losing as much as one third of their income due to asymmetric markets (Hussain et.al., 2003)14. II. GOVERNANCE, INSTITUTIONS AND GROWTH In this sub-section we will show how the institutional structure of governance constrains the provision of adequate health, education and security, which are major factors in perpetuating poverty. We will also show how the incentive system implied in rent based governance constrain sustained and equitable growth. II.1 Poverty and Illness The NHDR showed that due to inadequate diet and lack of access over safe drinking water and sanitation facilities, 65.1 percent of the extremely poor and 55.6 percent of the poor in the sample survey were suffering from ill health. The data also shows that the poor respondents reporting sickness at the time of the interview had on average suffered from their sickness for 95 days of the year15. (See table 4). The study showed that the prevalence of disease amongst those who are slightly above the poverty line is a major factor in pushing them into poverty. Those who are already poor get pushed into deeper poverty as a result of loss of income due to absence from work, and high medical costs resulting from illness. Thus the unequal access over public health facilities and the relatively high prevalence of disease amongst the poor becomes a structural factor that further accentuates both poverty and inequality. 8

Description:
water and sanitation facilities, 65.1 percent of the extremely poor and 55.6 percent of the poor in the sample . Lanka, India and Nepal. (Talat Anwar . This concept was first propounded by Professor. Rehman Improving the nutrition, preventive hygiene, provision of safe drinking water, improving th
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.