ebook img

Imperfect Commitment, Altruism, and the Family - Andrew D. Foster PDF

57 Pages·2000·0.22 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Imperfect Commitment, Altruism, and the Family - Andrew D. Foster

Forthcoming:ReviewofEconomicsandStatistics ImperfectCommitment,AltruismandtheFamily:EvidencefromTransfer BehaviorinLow-IncomeRuralAreas AndrewD.Foster BrownUniversity MarkR.Rosenzweig UniversityofPennsylvania July2000 TheresearchforthispapersupportedinpartbygrantsNIHHD30907,NIHHD28687,andNSFSBR93- 0405 I.Introduction Altruismormutual“caring”amongfamilymembershasbeenhypothesizedtoplayanimportant roleinfacilitatingrisksharing,particularlyinenvironmentswithlessdevelopedmarkets(Becker,1991). Indeed,recentstudieshaveprovidedevidencethatfamily-basedincometransfersdocontributeto consumptionsmoothing(Rosenzweig,1988;RosenzweigandStark,1989;RosenzweigandWolpin, 1994).However,thereisalsoevidencesuggestingthatwithinfamiliesidiosyncraticriskisnotfully insured(Altonjietal.,1992),andthatthetransferofresourcesamongfamilymembersinresponseto incomefluctuationsdoesnotconformfullytosimplemodelsofaltruism(Cox,1987;Altonjietal., 1997). Aproblemwithexistingempiricalstudiesofaltruismisthattheydonotmodelexplicitlythe well-knownconstraintsoninsurancearrangementsthataltruismmaynotfullyovercome,suchasbarriers toinformationthatgiverisetomoralhazardandthecommitmentproblemsthatarisewhenindividuals cannotenterintobindingcontracts.Theimplicationsderivedfromtheassumptionofaltruisminsuch modelsthusmaybemisleading.Moreover,if,forexample,costlystateverificationistheprincipal probleminattainingperfectinsurance,itmaybethatthefamilyisprominentinrisksharingnotbecause ofaltruismbutbecauseoffamilialinformationadvantages. Recentworkonself-enforcingcontracts(CoateandRavallion(1993),ThomasandWorrall (1995))hasprovidedinsightintothestructureofconstrained-efficientinsurancecontractsinthepresence ofimperfectcommitment.However,thisworkdoesnotexploretheinteractionsbetweencommitment problemsandaltruismindeterminingrisk-sharingarrangementsandfailstoexplainthepervasivefact thattransfers,inbothhighandlow-incomecountries,frequentlyoccurbetweenfamilymembers.Ina worldinwhichcontractsareeitherself-enforcingorenforceablebyathirdparty,therewouldseemtobe noparticularreasonforthistobethecase:itseemslikelythathouseholdsotherthanthosetowhichone isrelatedwouldingeneralbeabletoprovideonewithmorecompleterisksharingthanwouldthoseto 1 whichoneisconnectedthroughfamilytiesif,forexample,theincomesofnon-kinarelesscorrelated thanthoseofkin.Inaworldinwhichcontractsarenotenforceable,however,altruismmayplayan importantrole.Totheextentthathouseholdsenteringintoarisksharingarrangementcareabouteach others’welfarewewouldexpectthattheywillgainmorefrominsurancethantheywouldotherwiseand thusthatthescopeofrisk-sharingcontractswillbegreater. Inthispaper,weexamineempiricallywhetherriskpoolingismoreadvantageousamong altruisticcomparedtoselfishagentsinaframeworkwhereindividualscannotmakebinding commitments. Weincorporatealtruismintotherecentmodelofrisksharingunderimperfect commitmentofThomasandWorrall(1995)toestablishtestsoftherolesofbothaltruismand commitmentproblemsindeterminingtheextentofinsuranceandtheintertemporalmovementsin interhouseholdtransfers.1 Weshowthatitispossibletoimplementthetestsintermsofdirectly measurablevariables,onlysomeofwhichhavebeenusedinpriorstudiesassessingalternativeincome smoothingmechanisms.Inparticularweshowthathowmuchpasttransfersaffectcurrenttransfers-the “transferasseteffect”-andhowmuchofacontemporaneousincomeshockissharedbytransferpartners -the“incomeshockeffect”-differinspecificwaysbybothwhetherthetransferpartnersarealtruistic andbypartnerincomecovariancesinthepresenceofcommitmentproblems.Thetestsarecarriedout usingthreepaneldatasetsfromtwocountriesofruralSouthAsiathatprovidedetailedinformationon 1ThomasandWorrall(1995)useanapproachdevelopedinthecontextofimplicitlaborcontracts (ThomasandWorrall(1988))toexaminethequestionofwhetheroptimalimplementablerisksharing contractsarenon-stationary.ThisquestionwasraisedbyCoateandRavallion(1993)who,buildingon workbyFoster(1988)andKimball(1988),examinedoptimalstationaryrisk-sharingcontracts.Ligon, WorrallandThomas(forthcoming)provideanempiricaltestofthismodelusingoneofthethreedata setsemployedinthispaper.Whiletheirresultssupporttheimperfectcommitmentmodelrelativeto perfectinsuranceandautarchy,theirapproach(inparticularthefactthatexplicitinformationontransfers bypartnersarenotused)doesnotpermitanassessmentoftheroleofaltruismasacommitmentdevice.It shouldalsobenotedthattheLigon,WorrallandThomas(forthcoming)approachfocusesonintra-village risksharing,andthusdoesnotpermitanassessmentof inter-villagerisksharingarrangements,which playanimportantroleasshownbelow. 2 transfersandenablethemeasurementofincomeshocks.2 InsectionIIwecharacterizetheoptimalimplementablerisksharingcontractunderimperfect commitmentandillustrateusingmodelsimulationhowthedegreeofaltruismamongtransferpartners andthemagnitudeoftheirincomecorrelationinfluencethiscontract.Themodelsimulationsshowthat althoughsufficientlyaltruisticfamilieswithlessthanperfectlycorrelatedincomeswilloptimallyengage inriskpoolingarrangements,non-altruisticindividualswillnotengageinriskpoolingwhenincome correlationsaresufficientlypositive.Wealsoshowthatiftransfersplayaninsurancerolebutdonot achievefullinsurancethentransferswillrespondtobothcontemporaryincomeshocksandtothehistory ofprevioustransfers,withthelatterarisingasaresultoftheinabilityofhouseholdstocommittomake first-beststate-contingenttransfers.Moreover,thehistorydependenceoftransfersandtheirdegreeof responsivenesstoincomeshocksdependonthedegreeofaltruism.Inparticular,wedemonstratethati) theexistenceofbindingimperfectcommitmentconstraintsimpliesthathouseholdsthathavemadenet transfersinpreviousperiodsarelesslikelytoprovidesubsequenttransfers,giventhecurrentstateofthe world,thanarehouseholdsthathavebeennetrecipientsoftransfers,butii)contemporaneoustransfers arelessresponsivetotransfersinthepastandmoreresponsivetocurrentincomeshocks,forgiven partnerincomecorrelations,whenpartnersarealtruisticallylinkedcomparedtowhentheyarenot. InsectionIII,weshowthatestimatesoflinearapproximationstothetransferfunctionsimplied bythemodelarecapableofidentifyingtherolesofimperfectcommitment,altruismandincome covariancesindeterminingtransferbehavior.Wealsousethesimulationstoinvestigatetherobustnessof theresultstolackofsymmetryamongtransferpartnersandtoassumptionsabouttherelationships betweenkinship,incomecorrelationandinformation.Thedatafromthreeruralpanelsurveysthatare 2Wolpin(1984),Paxson(1992),Behrman,Foster,andRosenzweig,(1997),Udry(1994,1996), Rose(forthcoming)usevariousmeasuresofincomeshockstotestforconsumptionsmoothingbehavior andtoassesstheimportanceofparticularsmoothingmechanisms,includingfinancialsavings,asset divestiture,andlaborsupply. 3 usedtoestimatethesefunctions,specificaspectsoftheempiricalimplementationandtheempirical resultsarepresentedinSectionIV. Theestimatesprovidestrongsupportforthenotionthatimperfect commitmentsubstantiallyconstrainsinformaltransferarrangements,whetherkin-basedornot,butalso provideevidencethataltruismplaysanimportantroleinamelioratingcommitmentconstraintsandthus inincreasingthegainsfromincomepooling. II.TheoryandSimulations Tocapturethebasicelementsofinterhouseholdinteractionsandyetkeepthemodelstructureas simpleaspossibleweassumethattherearetwohouseholdsi=1,2.Ineveryperiodteachhouseholdi receivesanincomey(s)wheresisthestateofnatureinperiodt.3Incomecannotbestoredorsaved i t acrossperiods.Weallowforaltruismbetweenthehouseholdsbyassumingthathouseholdsingle-period utilityisseparableinownandotherhouseholdconsumption.Inparticular,theutilityfunctionsfor households1and2areassumedtobe: γ u(c1)+ v(c2) (1) γ v(c2)+ u(c1), (2) γ whereu()andv()areincreasingandconcaveand <1reflectsthedegreeofaltruism.Householdsare δ infinitelylived,discountthefuturewithdiscountfactor ,andareexpectedutilitymaximizers.4 3Becauseincomeisexogenousinthemodel,weareassumingawayproblemsofmoralhazard. Hoff(1997)formulatesamodelwhichshowshowmoralhazardlimitstheextentofinsuranceandmakes insurancearrangementsvulnerabletowealthshocks.Inthatmodel,however,itisassumedthatcontracts areenforceableandtheshareofincomethatispooledisendogenouslychosenbythemedianvoter,but respondstoshockswithalag. Hoffpresentsevidencethatthereisconcernaboutmoralhazardinsome low-incomecountrycontexts.However,incorporatingmoralhazardconsiderationsintoamodelinwhich contractsmustbeself-enforcingandthereisnonstationarity,ashere,wouldaddconsiderablecomplexity. Moreover,theempiricalassessmentoftheadditionalroleofmoralhazardwouldrequiredataonthe behaviorofalltransferpartnersthatarenotavailable. 4AsnotedbyCoateandRavallion(1993)andThomasandWorrall(1995)theassumptionthat householdsareinfinitelylivedisnotasstringentasitwouldseem:themodelincorporatesthepossibility thattheplayersbelievethatanyinsurancearrangementwill,forreasonsexogenoustothehistoryof statesandtransfers,failwithsomepositiveprobability(e.g.,asaresultofthedeathofoneparticipant), ineachperiod.Inthiscase,thefailureprobabilityisabsorbedintothediscountfactor. 4 Becauseofriskaversionwhentheincomesofthetwohouseholdsarenotperfectlycorrelatedthe householdscan,inprinciple,benefitthroughsharingofresources.Itisassumed,however,thatcontracts arenotlegallyenforceable.Asaconsequence,enforcementofanycontractmustrelysolelyonthe potentialconsequencesforthetwopartiesofviolatingthecontract.Inparticular,itisassumedthatif eitherofthehouseholdsdoesnotmeetthetermsofthecontractthenthehouseholdsreverttoasequence ofstaticNashequilibria(SSNE),whichcanbeoftwotypes:forsufficientlylowlevelsofaltruismthe householdsoperateinautarchy,asinstandardmodelsofimperfectcommitment,butathigherlevels somelimitedrisk-sharingstillobtains.Thislatterpossibilitymeansthatwhilealtruismmayincreasethe willingnessofanindividualtomakeatransfertoapartnerwhenhisincomeisrelativelyhigh,itmayalso decreasetheabilitytopenalizedeviantbehaviorbyreducingthecredibilityofthethreatofautarchy.5 Thetaskistospecifythesetofcontractsthatcanbesupported.Ingeneral,arisk-sharingcontract τ inthecontextofthismodelcanbecharacterizedasatransferfunction (h)thatdictatesthe(possibly t negative)transferfromhousehold1tohousehold2thatshouldoccurifthecontractisinforceinperiodt afterhistoryh ,wherethelatterisdefinedasthesequenceofstatesuptoandincludingthestaterealized t inperiodt:h ={s ,s ,...,s}.ThetransferfunctionforthestaticNashequilibriumgivenstatesisdenoted6 t 1 2 t ) & ) % 'γ ) ) γ t s.t. u (y (s) t)/v (y (s) t) if u (y (s))/v (y (s))< τ ' ) 1 & ) 2 % ' γ ) 1 ) 2 γ N(s) t s.t. u (y (s) t)/v (y (s) t) 1/ if u (y (s))/v (y (s))>1/ (3) 1 2 1 2 0 otherwise 5Ontheotherhand,ifinformationamongfamilymembersisgenerallysuperiortothatamong non-kin,thethreatofrelegationtothelimitedrisk-sharingstatemaybemorecredible,asthefamily memberwhosetransferarrangementisdiscontinuedwillfinditmoredifficulttofindanotheraltruistic partner.WeconsiderinsectionIIItheempiricalimplicationsofthispotentialinformationaladvantage forfamiliesinenforcingpunishments. 6Notethatinline1ofequation1thetransferispositive,andinline2itisnegative.Intuitively, thebetter-offhouseholdwillmakeatransfertotheworse-offhouseholdinthestaticNashequilibrium whenhecaressufficientlyaboutthathouseholdthatheisbetteroffdoingsothanhewouldbeby acceptingtheautarchicallocation. 5 DefineU(h)astheexpecteddiscountedutilitygainfromtherisk-sharingcontractrelativetotheSSNE t afterhistoryh sothat: t ' &τ & &τ %γ %τ &γ %τ U(h) u(y (s) (h)) u(y (s) N(s)) v(y (s) (h)) v(y (s) N(s)) t 1 t t t 1 t t 2 t t t 2 t t % j4 δ& &τ & &τ %γ %τ &γ %τ (4) E j t(u(y (s) (h)) u(y (s) N(s)) v(y (s) (h)) v(y (s) N(s))) '% 1 j t j 1 j t 2 j t j 2 j t j t 1 andletV(h)denotetheanalogousexpressionforhousehold2.Theassumptionthatthecontractis t enforcedthroughreversiontotheSSNEimpliesthatagivencontractcanbeimplementedonlyifthe $ expecteddiscountedutilitygainfromthecontractrelativetotheSSNEisnon-negative,U(h) 0and t $ V(h) 0, foreachhistoryh.Werefertotheseconstraintssubsequentlyastheimplementability t t constraints.7 Thesetofimplementablecontractscanbecharacterizedbyahistory-dependentconvexfunction W(U)thatdescribesthemaximal(overallimplementablecontracts)expecteddiscountedutilitygainthat s canaccruetohousehold2instatesifhousehold1receivesautilityofU.8 Further,theoptimalcontract canbecharacterizedintermsoftheevolutionoftheratioof marginalutility ) %τ %γ ) &τ λ 'v (y (s) (h)) u (y (s) (h))'& ) (h) ) 2 t &τt t %γ ) 1 t %τt t W (U(h)) (5) t s t t u (y (s) (h)) v (y (s) (h)) t 1 t t t 2 t t t λ overtime,where- istheslopeoftheParetofrontier.Inparticularforeachstatesthereisahistory λ λ independentinterval[ L, U]correspondingtothesetofimplementablepointsontheParetoefficient s s λ frontierinstatessuchthatthe (h)evolveaccordingto: t γ 7Whenever >0,eventheone-shotgame(definedin(3))cansupportsometransfers.The questionsishowmuchbettercantheplayersdounderatime-linkedcontract.Theimplementability constraintissimplythestatementthatthelattercontractmustprovideutilitynolessthanundertheone- shotgame. 8ThomasanγdWorrall(1995).AlthoughtheproofbyThomasandWorrall(1995)referstothe non-altruisticcase( =0)theextensiontothealtruisticcaseisstraightforward. 6 λ λ λ L if (h)< L λ ' λ s λ t0 λs λ (h% ) (h) if (h) [ L, U] (6) t 1 λt λ t λs s U if (h)> U s t s Theoptimalcontractmaythusbecharacterizedasfollows.Uponenteringthecontract,thetwo householdschooseadesireddistributionofexpectedutilitygainsgiventhecurrentstate(i.e.,apointon λ W(U)).ThenegativeoftheslopeontheParetofrontieratthispoint, (h )=-W ’(U))correspondstoa s 0 s0 ratioofmarginalutilitiesthatthehouseholdswillattempttoimplementsubsequently.Insubsequent periods,theleveloftransferisspecifiedsothat,giventheincomesofthetwohouseholds,theratioof λ single-periodmarginalutilitiesequalsthisprespecified aslongasthedistributionthatresultssatisfies theimplementabilityconstraintsgiventhecurrentstateandassumingthatthecontinuationpayoffs(i.e., whattheplayersexpecttoreceiveifthecontractismaintained)aredeterminedbythepointonthe λ frontierW(U)thatcorrespondstothe fromtheimmediatelyprecedingperiod.Ifoneofthe s implementabilityconstraintsisbinding(i.e,theoneforthehouseholdrequiredtomakeapositive transfer),however,boththecurrentallocationofresourcesandthecontinuationpayoffsareadjusted together,withtheadjustmentbeingassmallaspossibleinordertojustrelaxtheimplementability λ constraint.Theresulting andthusthenewratioofsingle-periodmarginalutilitiesisthenmaintained untilasubsequentimplementabilityconstraintbinds. Therelationbetweenthiscontractandthefirst-bestcontractisstraightforward.Asiswellknown (see,e.g.,Townsend1994),thefirstbestrisk-sharingcontractinvolvesequatingthemarginalutilitiesat allpointsintimeandinallstatesoftheworld.Thus,forexample,inthecaseofiso-elasticutility functions,thefirst-bestcontractwillinvolvesimplypoolingincomeineveryperiodandthendividingit accordingtosomefixeddistributionrule.Givenimperfectcommitmentandsufficientimpatience, however,inastateoftheworldinwhichonehouseholddoesparticularlywellthebetter-offhousehold 7 wouldhaveanincentivetorenegeonthisfirst-bestcontractbywithholdinghistransferandacceptingthe SSNEtransfersinthefuture.Theoptimalimplementablecontractspecifiedhereremovesthisincentive byallowingthedistributionruletobeshiftedinfavorofthebetter-offhousehold.Changesinthe distributionofresources,andthusthelossrelativetothefirst-bestarrangement,arekepttoaminimum byallowingbothcurrentandfuturedistributiontobeaffectedbytheimplementabilityconstraintswhen theybind.9 Itisnotpossibleexceptincaseswithverylimitedstatespacestoderiveanalyticalsolutionsfor decisionrulesfromthemodel.Wethusexplorethequalitativeimplicationsofcombinationsofdifferent degreesofaltruism,imperfectcommitmentandincomecovariancesusingsimulations.Weshowthat becauseofthenonstationaritycharacteroftheoptimalimplementableinsurancecontractforgiven currentincomes,ahouseholdthathasrecentlyreceivedtransfersislesslikelytoreceivesubsequent transfersthanahouseholdthathasrecentlyprovidedtransfers.Thus,exceptinthecasethatfullrisk- sharingisimplementable(inwhichcasetheimplementabilityconstraintsareneverbinding),transfers shouldbehavelikecreditinthesensethattheresultsofpastbehaviors(i.e.,outstandingdebt) importantlyaffectcurrentbehaviors(currentborrowing). Wealsoshowthataltruisminfluencesthe extentof commitmentproblemsasmanifestedinoptimalimplementableinsurancecontracts.However, whileweshowthataltruismmayfacilitaterisksharing,itisstillnecessarytoexplainwhytherearerisk- sharingarrangementsamongnon-kin,eveninlow-incomeenvironmentsthatlackformalrisk-sharing institutions.Animportantreasonisincomecovariance.Wethusalsoconsidertheimplicationsof 9Thefactthatboththecurrentandsubsequentallocationsoftransfersareaffectedwhenan implementabilityconstraintbindsimpliesthattheoptimalimplementablecontractdevisedbyThomas andWorrall(1995)isanimprovementupontheoptimalstationarycontractconsideredbyCoateand Ravallion(1993).Inthelattercaseonlycurrentallocationsofresourcesarealteredtomeetthe implementabilityconstraintresultinginlessperfectrisksharing.Thedifferencecanbesubstantial:ina numericalsimulationThomasandWorrall(1995)foundthatforsufficientlylowdiscountfactorsthatthe optimalstationarycontractresultedinnorisksharing,whereastheoptimalnon-stationarycontractcould achievemostofthegainfromfullinsurance. 8 covarianceinincomesforthenatureofrisk-sharingarrangements.Anadditionalimplicationisthat incomecovariancesamongnon-kincontractinghouseholdsareendogenouslydeterminedandpossibly relatedtowhetherfamily-basedrisk-sharingarrangementsarefeasible. Tocarryoutthesimulationsweassumethatu()andv()arelogrithmicandthusthattheperiod γ γ specific-utilityforhouseholds1and2areln(c )+ ln(c )andln(c )+ ln(c ),respectively.Incomesfor 1 2 2 1 eachhouseholdtakeononeoftwovalues,2or4,eachwithprobability½,withvaryingdegreesof correlation.Tocapturethesedifferencesincorrelationweletthestatestakeon4values,1,2,3,and4 withy (s)equalto2ifs=1ors=3and4otherwise.Similarly,welety (s)equal2ifs=1ors=2and4 1 2 otherwise.Then,thecaseofindependencecorrespondstoeachstateoccurringwithprobability1/4,the caseofapositivecorrelationof0.5canberepresentedbyassumingstates1and4occurwithprobability 3/8andstates2and3withprobability1/8,andthecaseofanegativecorrelationof-0.5canbe representedbyassumingstates1and4occurwithprobability1/8andstates2and3withprobability3/8. γ Inthesimulationsthatarepresentedbelowthediscountfactorissetto0.7510andthedegreeofaltruism isallowedtovaryfrom0to0.6.Wefocusonsymmetricoptimalimplementablecontracts,i.e.,thosefor whichthehouseholdsagreetohaveequalexpectedutilitygainsfromthecontractatthestart.We examinebelowhowtheresultsarealteredwhenthepartnersareengagedinanon-symmetric relationship. Thesolutionstothisproblemmaybecharacterizedasfollows.11Startingfromperiod0, 10Thediscountfactorischδosensothatthekeyfeaturesofthecontractmaybeillustrated.For moreusualdiscountfactors(e.g., =0.9)theoptimalimplementablecontractachievesclosetothefirst bestcontractevenintheabsenceofaltruism.Ourresults,presentedbelow,provideevidenceconsistent withthepropertiesofoursimulatedmodelforthelowdiscountfactorusedhere.Whilethisisconsistent withthenotionthatruralhouseholdsareimpatientor,asnoted,thattheyfaceasignificantexogenous riskofhavingtheagreementterminated,itmayalsobeattributedtoothersimplificationsofthemodel. Forexample,wemaketheextremeassumptionthatadevianthouseholdmustsubsequentlyconsumeat SSNElevels.Werelaxthisassumptionbyallowingforapositiveprobabilityofnonenforcementbelow. 11Solutionsforthevalueandtransferfunctionsforeachsetofparameterswerefoundbyreducing theproblem,throughappropriatesubstitution,tooneofsolvingtwonon-linearequationsintwo 9

Description:
achieve full insurance then transfers will respond to both contemporary income Hoff presents evidence that there is concern about moral hazard in some.
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.