ebook img

Helping a Victim or Helping the Victim: Altruism and - CiteSeer PDF

12 Pages·2003·0.17 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Helping a Victim or Helping the Victim: Altruism and - CiteSeer

TheJournalofRiskandUncertainty,26:1;5–16,2003 (cid:1)c 2003KluwerAcademicPublishers.ManufacturedinTheNetherlands. Helping a Victim or Helping the Victim: Altruism and Identifiability DEBORAHA.SMALL∗ [email protected] GEORGELOEWENSTEIN DepartmentofSocialandDecisionSciences,CarnegieMellonUniversity,Pittsburgh,PA,15213,USA Abstract Althoughithasbeenclaimedthatpeoplecaremoreaboutidentifiablethanstatisticalvictims,demonstratingthis “identifiablevictimeffect”hasprovendifficultbecauseidentificationusuallyprovidesinformationaboutavictim, andpeoplemayrespondtotheinformationratherthantoidentificationperse.Weshowthataveryweakform ofidentifiability—determiningthevictimwithoutprovidinganypersonalizinginformation—increasescaring.In thefirst,laboratorystudy,subjectsweremorewillingtocompensateotherswholostmoneywhenthelosershad alreadybeendeterminedthanwhentheywereabouttobe.Inthesecond,fieldstudy,peoplecontributedmoretoa charitywhentheircontributionswouldbenefitafamilythathadalreadybeenselectedfromalistthanwhentold thatthefamilywouldbeselectedfromthesamelist. Keywords: valueoflife,identifiablevictims,dictatorgame JELClassification: C9,Z0 Peoplereactdifferentlytowardidentifiablevictimsthantostatisticalvictimswhohavenot yetbeenidentified.Specificvictimsofmisfortuneoftendrawextraordinaryattentionand resources. But, it is often difficult to draw attention to, or raise money for, interventions that would prevent people from becoming victims in the first place. For example, when JessicaMcClure(“BabyJessica”)wastrappedinawellinTexas,over$700,000wassent to her family for the rescue effort (Variety, 1989). If those donations had instead been spentonpreventativehealthcareforchildren,hundredsofchildren’slivescouldpotentially have been saved. As Schelling (1968) noted in a seminal article on what has come to be known as the identifiable victim effect, the death of a particular person invokes “anxiety andsentiment,guiltandawe,responsibilityandreligion,[but]...mostofthisawesomeness disappearswhenwedealwithstatisticaldeath.” Schelling’s comment points to an intuitively plausible psychological account of why identifiablymatters.Itsuggeststhatidentifiablevictimsstimulateamorepowerfulemotional responsethandostatisticalvictims.However,thelimitedamountofresearchthathassought tobetterunderstandtheidentifiablevictimeffecthasnotsupportedsuchanaccount. JenniandLoewenstein(1997)identifiedfourpotentialcausesoftheidentifiablevictimef- fectandconductedstudiestoteasethemapart.Mostobviously,identifiablevictimsaremore vivid than statistical victims (see Nisbett and Ross, 1980), especially when details about ∗Towhomcorrespondenceshouldbeaddressed. 6 SMALLANDLOEWENSTEIN them are communicated—e.g., pictures, family information, and so on. Second, identifi- ablevictimsarecertainvictims,whereasstatisticalvictimsare,bydefinition,probabilistic. Researchonriskydecisionmakingsuggeststhatpeopleareloss-averse—theydislikelosses muchmorethantheylikeequivalentvaluedgains(KahnemanandTversky,1979).Ifsaving astatisticallifeisseenasagain,butsavinganidentifiedvictimisseenasavoidingaloss,then thispredictsthatpeoplewillplacegreatervalueonidentifiedvictimsthanonstatisticalones. Third, evaluation of an identified victim is made ex post—i.e., after the event has occurred—whereas the evaluation of a statistical life is made ex ante. Ex post evalua- tionmakesblameandresponsibilitymuchmoresalient,andriskperceptioncandependon thesaliencyofblame(Douglas,1992).Attributionofblameislessclearintheexantecase sinceitisimpossibleforpeopletopredictandtakeonresponsibilityforallthetragedies thatmightoccur.ThisthirdcauseisclosesttotheonethatSchellingimplicitlyattributed theidentifiablevictimeffectto,andisclosetothecauseweexamineinthispaper. The fourth cause, and the one that has received the greatest empirical support, is the referencegroupeffect.Peoplefeelgreaterconcerntowardvictimsasthereferencegroup theyarepartofgrowssmaller(Slovic,Fischhoff,andLichtenstein,1980).Forexample,a diseasethatkills100peopleoutofagroupof100isseenasacalamity,butonethatkills 100peopleacrossthecountryisexperiencedasmuchlessdisturbing.Identifiablevictims representthemosthighlyconcentrateddistributionofrisk(ann ofn)becauseidentifiable victimsbecome,ineffect,theirownreferencegroup.Incontrast,astatisticallifehasamuch largerdenominator,becausetheriskistypicallyspreadacrossalargepopulation. JenniandLoewensteinfoundonlyweaksupportforthefirstthreeexplanations,butstrong support for the fourth explanation involving the proportion of the reference group saved. SimilarresultswereobtainedbyFeatherstonhaughetal.(1997)andBaron(1997)andall werereportedinthesameissueoftheJournalofRiskandUncertainty,whichwasdevoted totheproblemofvaluinghumanlife. Theideathattheidentifiablevictimeffectis“just”areferencegroupeffectissomewhat surprisingandseemstoconflictwithSchelling’scompellingintuitionthatthereissomething specialaboutidentifiedvictimsthatcausesustoreacttotheminamoreemotionalfashion. Evenifthereferencegroupeffectcanhelptoexplaintheidentifiablevictimeffect,itseems difficulttoacceptthatthisisthewholestory. Severalpsychologicaltheoriessuggestthatpeopleusedistinctprocessestomakejudg- ments of specific as opposed to general targets (Hamilton and Sherman, 1996; Sherman, Beike, and Ryalls, 1999). Dual-process models in social psychology suggest that peo- ple become more mentally, and emotionally, engaged when they process information aboutspecificindividualsthanwhentheyprocessinformationaboutabstracttargets.The central-peripheralmodel(PettyandCacioppo,1986)andtheHeuristic-Systematicmodel (Chaiken, 1980) both can be applied to the perception of and reactions to victims. These dual-process models suggest that specific instances are more involving to the perceiver. Specificcases,suchasidentifiablevictims,arethusmorelikelytoreceivegreatercognitive attention, and deeper consideration. Abstract cases, including statistical victims, are less emotionally involving, and judgments of them are more likely to be made on the basis of peripheral or heuristic cues. The differential functioning of separate processes helps explainwhyknowingthatthereisaparticularsomeoneinneedwhomyoucanhelpfeels HELPING AVICTIMORHELPINGTHEVICTIM 7 qualitativelydifferentfromknowingthatyoucouldhelponeofmanypossibleneedypeople. Thevictimismoreemotionallygrippingthana victimregardlessofthesizeoftherefer- encegroup.Basedonourdoubtsabouttheformer“referencegroupeffect”conclusion,we decidedtoconductamorefocusedtestoftheeffectofidentifiability. Testingforaneffectofidentifiabilityisdifficultbecauseitishardtomanipulateidenti- fiabilitywithoutalteringotherfactorsatthesametime.Perhapsthebiggestproblemisto identifyvictimsinanymeaningfulfashionwithoutrevealinginformationaboutthem—e.g., theirgenderorage.Assoonasonerevealsspecificcharacteristicsofthevictim—eveninfor- mationastrivialasaname—itispossiblethatpeoplefeelespeciallysympathetictopeople withthosecharacteristics.Onceidentifyinginformationisprovided,itispossiblethatthe specificcharacteristicratherthantheidentifiabilityofthevictimperseisresponsiblefor anydifferentialresponseoneobserves. Inthestudiespresentedhere,weavoidthisproblembymanipulatingaparticularlyweak form of identifiability, determination of the recipient of help, that avoids conveying any information about the victim. Statistical victims are indeterminate in the sense that the people who will become victims have not yet been determined. Identifiable victims, in contrast,aredetermined.Thevictims’identitieshavebeendetermined,whetherwelearn anythingabouttheiridentity.Wehypothesize,therefore,thatevenifwehavenoinformation aboutthepersons,determinedvictimswillbeperceivedasmoretangibleandhenceevoke greater sympathy. Indeterminate victims, in contrast, are more difficult to imagine and empathizewith,andhenceoneislesslikelytobehavetowardtheminanaltruisticfashion. 1. Labexperiment Ourfirststudyusesaspecializedversionofthe“dictatorgame”toprovideaquantitative measureofaltruism.Inthestandardversionofthegamean“allocator”ispresentedwith an endowment and then given the opportunity to split the endowment with an unknown “recipient.” Although economic models which assume selfishness predict that allocators will keep the entire endowment for themselves, in fact many allocators give a positive amount(seeCamererandThaler,1995,forareviewoffindings).Ofspecialrelevanceto the current study, Hoffman, McCabe, and Smith (1996) varied the design of the dictator gameinvariousways,includingpermittingcommunicationbetweentheallocatorandthe recipient.Theyfoundthatindividualswhocommunicatedwithone-anotherbecamemore other-regarding,andpositedthatithadthiseffectbecauseitreducedtheperceived“social distance”betweentheplayers. BohnetandFrey(1999)examinedoneaspectofsocialdistancethatisespeciallyclosely relatedtoidentifiability.Theyconductedaversionofthedictatorgameinwhichdifferent subjects played either (a) completely anonymously, (b) with silent identification, and (c) withface-to-facecommunication.Theyfoundthatrelaxinganonymitywhilestillforbidding dialoguewassufficienttoincreaseother-regardingbehavior.Notethatrelaxinganonymity issomewhatdifferentfrompureidentifiabilityaswehavedefinedit.First,inthecontext of their studies, it introduces the possibility that one will interact with the individual in the future, and that such interaction will be affected by the recipient’s knowledge of the dictator’sbehavior.Second,asdiscussedabove,itintroducesthepossibilitythatanyeffect 8 SMALLANDLOEWENSTEIN is due to the specific identities of the linked pairs as opposed to the mere fact that they are identified. Nevertheless, the results are certainly consistent with our prediction that determiningthepersontobehelpedincreasesgenerosity. In our first experiment, we modified the dictator game to produce a situation in which fortunatesubjectswhoretainedtheirendowmentcouldcontributeaportionofitto“victims” whohadlosttheirs.Themainmanipulationinthestudywaswhethertheidentityofvictims hadalreadybeen,orwasabouttobebuthadnotyetbeen,determined.Wehypothesized thatdeterminedvictimswouldreceivemoremoney. 1.1. Method Seventy-sixundergraduatestudentsatCarnegieMellonUniversityparticipatedinthestudy inexchangeforresearchparticipantcreditandwhateversumofmoneytheyearnedfrom thegame.Subjectswererecruitedingroupsoften,andwererandomlyassignedasablock tooneofthetwoconditions(determinedorundetermined).Theywereseatedincubicles facingawayfromoneanotherandwereinstructednottospeakorturnaroundandlookat oneanotherduringthecourseoftheexperiment.Theexperimenterinformedthesubjects thatalldecisionstheymadewouldbeanonymousandthat,atnopointduringorafterthe experiment,wouldanyonelearntheidentityofanyonetheywerepairedwith.Attheendof theexperiment,subjectsweretoldthattheywouldreceivetheirpaymentsfromtheoutcome oftheallocationsinsealedenvelopes,sothattheywouldonlylearntheoutcomeoftheir ownallocation,andnooneelse’s. At the beginning of an experimental session, each subject was given an envelope with $10.00intheformof40papertokensworth$0.25each.Subjectswereinformedthatthe tokenswereequivalenttorealmoneyandthatthosetheyretainedattheendofthegame could be exchanged for cash. The experimenter then circulated the room with a bag of piecesofpaperlabeledwithanumberfrom1–10,andeachsubjectdrewanumber. Eachsubjectthenreceivedthefollowingwritteninstructions: Theactualexperimentrequiresthathalfoftheparticipantsbeginthetaskwith$10.00in papertokens,butthathalfbeginwithnothing.Tocreatethissituation,eachpersonwill drawacardfromthebag.Halfofthecardshavetheword“KEEP”onthem,andtheother halfhavetheword“LOSE”writtenonthem.Ifyoudrawa“KEEP”card,youkeepyour papertokens.IfyoudrawaLOSEcard,putyournumbercardandyourtokensinthebag whentheexperimentercomestoyou. Thenextpartoftheinstructionsdifferedsubtletyforthoseinthedeterminedandunde- terminedconditions. Inthedeterminedcondition,theinstructionsread: Each“KEEP”participantwillnowbelinkedwithone“LOSE”participant.Ifyouarea KEEPparticipant,youwilldrawoneofthe“LOSE”participant’snumbersfromthebag. Pleasedosonowandwriteitonthefollowingline.Iamlinkedwithnumber . Ifyouarea“LOSE”participant,writeanXintheblank. HELPING AVICTIMORHELPINGTHEVICTIM 9 Intheundeterminedcondition,theinstructionsread: Inamoment,eachofthe“KEEP”participantswillbelinkedwithone“LOSE”participant byhavingthe“KEEP”participantdrawoneofthe“LOSE”participant’snumbersfrom thebag.Beforewedothat,however,wehaveadecisionforyou. Forparticipantsinbothconditions,theinstructionsthencontinued: KEEP participants: If you are a “KEEP” participant, you now have the opportunity toallocateyour$10.00endowmentbetweenyourselfandthe“LOSE”participant.The decisionthatyoumakeisfinal.Thatis,allofthetokensthatyouallocatetoyourselfare yourstocashinattheendoftheexperiment.Likewise,theLOSEparticipantyouhave been linked with will cash in whatever tokens you allocate to him/her. Remember, the rolesassignedandyourdecisionwillbeanonymous.Noonewilleverlearnthatyouare aKEEPparticipant,youwillneverlearntheidentityofthepersonyouarelinkedwith, andnoneofyouwillknowhowmuchmoneyeachparticipanttakeshome. Pleaseputthetokensyouwouldliketogivetheparticipantyouarelinkedwithinthe manilaenvelope.Also,writeyourdecisioninthefollowingblanks: Keepforself Givetolinkedparticipant $10.00TOTAL LOSEparticipants:Puttheseinstructionsbackinthewhiteenvelopeandsealit. Atthispoint,theinstructionsintheundeterminedconditionsaid: Now,wewilldrawthenumberoftheLOSEplayeryouwillbelinkedwith.Pleasedraw anumberfromthebagandwritethenumberhere . Finally, KEEP participants in both conditions were told to put the tokens they were keepingforthemselvesinthewhiteenvelopewiththeirinstructionssheetsandtosealthe envelope. Astheinstructionsindicate,theonlyaspectvariedbetweenthetwoconditionswasthe time when an allocator drew the number of the recipient: before making an allocation in the determined condition and after making an allocation in the undetermined condition. The experiment was implemented exactly as specified by the instructions. There was no deception;paymentwasdeterminedasdescribedtothesubjects. 1.2. Results Ourmajorhypothesis,thatAllocatorswouldgivemoremoneytorecipientsinthedetermined condition than in the undetermined condition, was supported. The results are reported in Table1. Because the contributions were not distributed normally, we analyzed the difference betweenthetwogroupswithaMann-Whitneynon-parametrictest,whichconfirmedthat 10 SMALLANDLOEWENSTEIN Table1. Summarystatisticsofallocationstoundeterminedanddeterminedrecipients inthelabexperiment. Undeterminedvictim Determinedvictim Condition (n=37) (n=39) Mean $2.12 $3.42 Standarddeviation $1.79 $2.51 Median $1.81 $3.81 Mode $2.00 $5.00 Percentof$5.00(orgreater)offers 18.9% 46.1% Percentof$0.00offers 18.9% 15.4% subjectsgavesignificantlymoretovictimswhohadbeendeterminedpriortotheallocation taskthantovictimswhowereyettobedetermined(Z =−2.3,p =0.02). From the last two rows of the table, it is apparent that the determination manipulation affectedthemagnitudeofdonationstovictimsbutnotthetendencytomakeanydonation atall.Therewasastrikingdifferencebetweenthetwogroupsinmean,medianandmodal contributions,butvirtuallythesamefractionofsubjectsineachconditiongavesomepositive amount.1 Figure1presentshistogramsofgivinginthetwoconditions,whichreinforcestheobser- vationthatthemajordifferencebetweenthetwoconditionsisinhowmuchsubjectsgave ratherthanwhethertheygave.Thefigurealsoshowsthatcontributionswerenotnormally distributed. Figure1. Comparisonofallocationstoundeterminedanddeterminedrecipients.Donationsareroundedtothe nearestdollar. HELPING AVICTIMORHELPINGTHEVICTIM 11 1.3. Discussion This study provides evidence for the effect of identifiability on altruism. The results are especiallystrikingbecausethe“victims”inourstudywere,inthegeneralschemeofthings, not particularly disadvantaged—they had simply missed out on the opportunity to gain a $10 windfall—and the determination manipulation was subtle. If such a weak form of identifiabilitycanproducesuchadramaticdifferenceinaltruisticbehavioritseemslikely that variations of identifiability will produce even more dramatic effects in naturalistic situationsinwhich,forexample,oneusuallydoesobtainatleastsomeinformationabout identifiablevictims.Nevertheless,suchaneffectcannotbeassumed,whichiswhywechose toconductourfollow-upstudyinthefield. 2. Fieldexperiment Inoursecondstudy,potentialdonorswerepresentedwithaletterrequestingmoneytobuy materialsforahousethatwastobebuiltforaneedyfamilythroughtheHabitatforHumanity organization.Theletterdescribedseveralfamiliesonthewaitinglisttomoveintohomes. Identifiabilitywasmanipulatedbyinformingrespondentsthatthefamilyeither“hasbeen selected” or “will be selected” from the list. In neither condition were respondents told whichfamilyhadbeenorwouldbeselected;theonlydifferencebetweenconditionswas inwhetherthedecisionhadalreadybeenmade. 2.1. Method AtpublicplacesaroundPittsburgh,includingtheairportandshoppingcenters,peoplewere approached and 234 individuals consented to fill out a survey on an unrelated topic for $5.00 pay. When they finished the survey, each was presented with 5 one dollar bills, a returnenvelope,andaletterfromHabitatHumanity.2Participantsweretoldthattherequest wasentirelyseparatefromthesurveyjustcompleted.Theywereaskedtoreadtherequest, regardless of whether they thought they would be interested in donating the money that they had earned, and to return the envelope, sealed with their receipt and any amount of the$5.00theychosetodonate,eveniftheyweregivingnothing.Thesurveyadministrators wereblindtothehypothesisandunawarethatthecharityrequestlettercameintwoforms thatwererandomlydistributedamongthesurveys.Thetextoftheletterinthe“determined” condition,withalternativewordingfortheundeterminedconditionpresentedinbrackets, wasasfollows: Severalfamilieshaveappliedtohelpbuildandpurchaseahomeforthemselves.Habitat protectstheconfidentialityofapplicants,butherearebriefdescriptionsofthefamilies, namesexcluded: 1) Asingledadwhoworksasapainter.Hehastwokids:his8-year-oldliveswithhim andhepayschildsupportforanotherchild. 2) Asinglemomwholiveswithher3childrenandherdisabledfather.Herkidsareages 4,2,and5months. 12 SMALLANDLOEWENSTEIN 3) Asinglemomwhoisondisability.Sheliveswithher2children:a12-year-oldanda 20-year-oldwhoisalsoondisability. 4) A single mom with 4 kids: ages 14, 11, 11, and 9. Her current home is plagued by infestation,aleakyroof,birdsintheattic,andhighgasbills. Eighty percent of the money raised will go directly toward building materials for the constructionofthenexthouse;therestgoestoadministrativecosts.PittsburghHabitat hasalreadydecided[willdecide],basedonneed,whichofthefamiliesjustdescribedisin themostneed,andthatfamilywillmoveintothehousebuiltbyCMUstudentsandfaculty. ThefamilythatHabitatchose[willchoose]willparticipateinthebuildingoftheirnew home.Ifyouwouldliketodonateanyofthemoneythatyoureceivedforfillingoutyour questionnairetohelpbuildahomeforthefamilythathabitathaschosen[willchoose], pleaseputitintheenvelope.Wedonotwantyoutofeelpressuredintogivingsofeeltostep asidefromtheresearcher,putwhatyouchooseofyour$5.00intheenvelope,andreturn ittotheresearcher,sealed,regardlessofwhether,orhowmuchyouhavecontributed. 2.2. Results Asinthepreviousstudy,wepredicted,andfound,thatcontributionswouldbelargerwhen the recipients had already been determined than when they were yet to be determined. SummarystatisticsforthestudyarepresentedinTable2. Whethermeasuredbymean,medianormode,donationswerelargerinthedetermined conditionthanintheundeterminedcondition,andthedifferencesissignificantbyaMann- Whitneytest(Z =−1.99,p =0.05).Moreover,unlikethepreviousstudy,morepeoplein thedeterminedfamilyconditiongaveanythingatall(69.5%)thanwhenthefamilyhadnot beendetermined(56.9%),againasignificantdifference(χ2(1)=3.99,p =0.05).Figure2 presentsahistogramoftheresults. Onepossiblealternativeinterpretationoftheresultsisthatrespondentsmighthavecon- struedeithertheorganizationorthepotentialrecipientsdifferentlybasedonwhetherornot HabitatforHumanityhadyetselectedtherecipientofthehome.Itispossiblethatrespon- dentsmightinferthattheorganizationislesstrustworthytocarrythroughwithitsplans,or thatthefamilythatwillbechosenwillbelessdeserving,ifthemoneyisbeingraisedbefore Table2. Summarystatisticsofallocationstoundeterminedanddetermined familiesinthefieldexperiment. Undeterminedfamily Determinedfamily Condition (n=116) (n=118) Mean $2.33 $2.93 Standarddeviation $2.31 $2.25 Median $2.00 $4.00 Mode $0.00 $5.00 Percentof$5.00offers 38.8% 49.2% Percentof$0.00offers 43.1% 30.5% HELPING AVICTIMORHELPINGTHEVICTIM 13 Figure2. Comparisonofdonationstoundeterminedanddeterminedhabitatforhumanityfamiliesreceivingaid. abeneficiaryhasbeenchosen.Totestthesepotentialalternativeaccountsoftheresults,we conductedabriefsurveytoexplorewhetherpeopleconstruedthesituationdifferentlyinthe twoconditions.Wepresentedaseparatesampleof42undergraduatestudentsatCarnegie MellonUniversitywiththecharityrequestletter(halfreceivedthedeterminedfamilycon- ditionandhalfreceivedtheundeterminedfamilyversion)andaskedthemtorespondtothe followingquestionson7-pointlikertscales: 1) Howlikelydoyouthinkitisthatmoneydonatedwillactuallygotobuildingahomefor aneedyfamily;and 2) Assumingsuchahomeis,infact,constructed,whatisyourbestguessoftheneediness ofthefamilythatreceivesit. There were no differences across conditions in the responses (p = 0.74; 0.69 respec- tively).Meanresponsestoquestion1were5.7fortheunidentifiedconditionand5.8forthe identifiedcondition,andforquestion2were5.6fortheunidentifiedconditionand5.7for the identified condition. It seems unlikely, therefore, that the effect we observed resulted fromdifferentinterpretationsofthesituation.3 2.3. Discussion This field study provides even stronger support that identifiability of the victim affects altruism. By moving out of the laboratory, we eliminated potential artifacts such as the concern that students might have felt of being “found out” by their peers or other non- empatheticmotives.Bycollectingmoneyforarealcharitytohelppeopletrulyinneed,we illustratetherealworldimplicationsofthiseffect. 3. Generaldiscussionandconclusions Incombination,thesetwostudiesprovidenewevidencesupportingtheexistenceofaniden- tifiablevictimeffect.Theweakformofourdeterminationmanipulationshows,furthermore, 14 SMALLANDLOEWENSTEIN thattheeffectisnotduetospecificinformationthatpeoplereceiveaboutvictims(although thatcanbeacontributingfactor).Althoughreferencegroupsizemayagainbeacontribut- ingfactorintherealworld,evenwhenoneholdsthereferencegroupsizeconstant,there remainsaneffectofidentifiability. Although we conjecture about the cause of the effect, and specifically speculate that identifiabilityaffectsthewaythatpeoplethinkabout,andemotionallyreactto,victims,our studiesprovidenoevidencethatthesearetheactualmechanismsthatproducetheeffect. Futureresearchcouldtestformediationbymeasuringemotions,orbyexaminingtheimpact ofinducingorsuppressingspecificemotions. Another possible contributing factor is that determined victims provide more salient reasons to act. Shafir, Simonson, and Tversky (1993) maintain that many decisions are driven by arguments or reasons, rather than value-based calculations of options. Thus, in onestudy,somesubjectswereaskedtoimaginethattheyhadagreedtotakeawagerthat gavethema50–50chanceofwinning$150orlosing$100andhadlost,andwereaskedif theywouldliketoplayagain.Amajoritysaidthattheywould.Othersweretoldthatthey had taken the wager and had won; again they wanted to play again. However, when they weretoldthattheyhadacceptedthefirstwagerbuthadnotyetplayed,amajoritysaidthat theydidnotwanttoplayagain.Apparently,actuallyresolvingtheuncertaintyinitiateda lineofreasoningthatsubjectsdidnotspontaneouslyengageinwhentheuncertaintywas not resolved. In future research it would be interesting to test whether statistical victims similarlyevokedifferentargumentsorreasonsfromvictimsthathavebeenidentified. In ongoing research, we are attempting to generalize these results beyond the impact of identifiability on empathy for, and altruism toward, victims. If it is true that simply determiningavictimincreaseshelpingbyreducingthepsychologicaldistancebetweenthe selfandavictim,thenitispossiblethatdeterminingatargetotherthanavictimcouldhave animpactaswell.Victimsarevictimsbecausetheyarenotresponsiblefortheirsituation andthusevokesympathyandpity(Weiner,1980).If,instead,apersoninneedisconsidered responsiblefortheiradversesituation,thentheresultingemotionsmightinsteadbeanger anddisgust.Angerfollowsfromthebeliefthatanotherperson“couldandshouldhavedone otherwise,”andtheemotiondiminishesourinclinationtohelpthisperson(Weiner,1995). If we feel greater pity for a victim who has been determined, it might be the case that wefeelstrongerangertowardadeterminedtargetwhocausedandisresponsiblefortheir predicament.Thereforethe“determinedvictimeffect”behindidentifiabilitymaysimplybe onecaseofamoregeneral“determinedothereffect,”inwhichanydeterminedtargetevokes astrongeremotionalreactionthananundeterminedtarget.Futureresearchshouldexplore therangeofothersocialjudgmentsandbehaviorsthataremoderatedbydetermination. Acknowledgments WethankJenniferLerner,MargaretClark,andLindaBabcockfortheirhelp.Loewenstein’s participation in this research was supported by the Center for Integrated Study of the HumanDimensionsofGlobalChange,ajointcreationoftheNationalScienceFoundation (SBR 9521914)andCarnegieMellonUniversity.

Description:
Altruism and Identifiability. DEBORAH A. SMALL∗ [email protected]. GEORGE LOEWENSTEIN. Department of Social and Decision Sciences, Carnegie
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.