ebook img

Happiness and altruism within the extended family PDF

19 Pages·2011·0.3 MB·English
by  
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Happiness and altruism within the extended family

JPopulEcon(2011)24:1033–1051 DOI10.1007/s00148-010-0326-8 ORIGINAL PAPER Happiness and altruism within the extended family JohannesSchwarze·RainerWinkelmann Received:2September2008/Accepted:21May2010/ Publishedonline:29June2010 ©Springer-Verlag2010 Abstract Weproposeadirectmeasureofaltruismbetweenparentsandadult children, using survey data on happiness from the German Socio-Economic Panel for the years 2000–2004. The question of altruism within families has policy relevance, for example, to understand whether public transfers crowd out private ones. Previous empirical evidence, based on observed transfer behavior,hasfailedtoestablishaclearconsensus.Usingvariouscrosssection, paneldata,andinstrumentalvariableestimators,wefindarobustassociation betweenthehappinessofparentsandthatoftheiradultchildren.A1standard deviationincreaseinachild’shappinessisassociatedwiththesameincreasein ownhappinessasthatofa20–45%increaseinhouseholdincome,depending onspecification. Keywords Utilityinterdependence·Sympathy·Paneldata JELClassification D64·C25·J10 “How selfish soever man may be supposed, there are evidently some principles in his nature, which interest him in the fortune of others, and Responsibleeditor:ChristianDustmann AnearlierversionofthepaperwaspresentedatseminarsinBerlin,Gottlieben,Lausanne, Philadelphia,andatthe2005populationeconomicsmeetingoftheGermanEconomic AssociationinBasel. J.Schwarze FakultätfürSozial-undWirtschaftswissenschaften,Otto-Friedrich-UniversitätBamberg, 96045Bamberg,Germany R.Winkelmann(B) DepartmentofEconomics,UniversityofZurich,Zürichbergstr.14,8032Zurich,Switzerland e-mail:[email protected] 1034 J.Schwarze,R.Winkelmann rendertheirhappinessnecessarytohim,thoughhederivesnothingfrom itexceptthepleasureofseeingit.” AdamSmith(1790) “...we might suppose that the object which X (whose own utility is P) tends—inacalm,effectivemoment—tomaximise,isnot Pbut P+λ(cid:3); whereλisacoefficientofeffectivesympathy.” FrancisYsidroEdgeworth(1881,p.53) 1Introduction Altruism denotes the willingness to make voluntary transfers of resources to another person or other persons, disregarding of own benefit. The empirical importance of altruism for economics has been debated for several decades, yetnoclearconsensushasemergedsofar.Aninitialliteraturewasconcerned with the way resources are distributed within the extended family and its consequences for optimal public transfer policies (Becker 1981; Altonji et al. 1992). More recently, evidence on widespread pro-social behavior in labo- ratory experiments has led to renewed interest in altruism and challenged theviewthateconomicagentsmostlybehaveselfishly(FehrandFischbacher 2003).Importantly,altruisticbehaviorisfoundnotonlyamongrelatedfamily membersbutalsoamongstrangersinone-shotinteractions. Behavior-based research of altruism faces the obstacle that such transfers canalmostalwaysbeattributedtoanumberofdifferentmotives.Ifthemotive foratransferis“nothingexceptthepleasureofseeingthehappinessofothers”, as Adam Smith puts it, then we have indeed an instance of genuine altruism. But other motives reflect plain selfishness because they give the donor a personal benefit. Among the possible benefits are “joy-of-giving” or “warm glow”effects(Andreoni1990),wherebytheactofgivingprovidesasourceof satisfactionperse,forexample,byaccordingprestigeorrespecttothedonor,a benefitthatisindependentofhowthebeneficiaryvaluesthetransfer.Another potentialbenefitisreciprocity,i.e.,theexpectationthatafavorisreturnedin thefuture.Also,pro-socialbehaviorcanleadtopositivereputationeffectsthat eventuallyprovidematerialbenefits. While the literature has proposed a number of tests between these alter- native explanations, some based on observational data, others on laboratory experiments (e.g., Altonji et al. 1992; Ribar and Wilhelm 2002; Fehr and Fischbacher2003),wesuggestinthispaperanalternativerouteforuncovering genuine altruism, namely by exploiting information on measured utility of people.Suchinformationcanrevealtheextenttowhichpreferencesareother regardingorinterdependent.Interdependentpreferences,inturn,canbeseen astheproximatemechanismbywhichgenuinelyaltruisticbehaviorisinduced in humans. In other words, without interdependent preferences, all observed behaviorsofapparentlyaltruistictransferswouldneedtobeascribedtoselfish motives. Happinessandaltruismwithintheextendedfamily 1035 Inthissense,interdependentpreferencesaremorefundamentaltoaltruism than actual transfers: the absence of transfers (or altruistic behavior more broadly defined) in a specific period and environment does not rule out altruismingeneral,whiletheabsenceofinterdependentpreferencesdoes.For theformer,considerthesituationofparentsandtheirchildren:Ifincomeflows areverysimilar,altruisticparentswillnotmaketransfersalthoughtheywould dosoifasufficientlylargeincomegapweretodevelop. Theapproachweproposeisbasedonself-reportedhappinessasaproxyfor utility.Weanalyzetheextentofinterdependentpreferencesinthecontextof parents and their adult children who have moved out and live on their own. Theobjectiveofthepaperisthustotestwhetherandtowhatextentparents’ happinessisrelatedtothatoftheirchildren.Forthatpurpose,auniquelinked parent–child dataset has been extracted from the German Socio-Economic Panel(GSOEP)fortheyears2000to2004. Our primary finding is that of a strong association between the utility proxies, i.e., evidence for interdependent preferences. We explore a number of potential explanations, including shared environment, inherited predispo- sition toward happiness, paternalistic preferences, and reversed causation. Thepositiveassociationpersistsaftercontrollingforahostofsocioeconomic background variables and, exploiting the longitudinal structure of the data, individualspecifictimeinvariantfixedeffects.Wealsoperformedinstrumental variable estimation, although it is difficult to find credible instruments in the data,andtherequiredexclusionrestrictionsmaynotholdfortheinstruments we used. While this leaves some uncertainty as to the magnitude of the association, we can reject the null hypothesis of no preference independence inallspecifications.Thisrobustnesssupportstheviewthatparents’andchild’s happinessareindeedrelatedandthatthisrelationcanbemeasuredinsurvey data.Dependingonspecification,a1.5point(1standarddeviation)increasein child’shappinessisassociatedwithanincreaseinparents’reportedhappiness thatequalsthatofa20–45%increaseinownincome. 2Happinessandaltruism Measures of happiness have been developed and tested extensively in psy- chological research (Diener 1984). In the simplest case, there is a single item question on life satisfaction or happiness. According to Veenhoven, “happinessisthedegreetowhichapersonevaluatestheoverallqualityofhis present life-as-a-whole positively” (Veenhoven 1988, p.3.) There is a general consensusthatsubjectivewell-beingtapsprimarilyintocognitivedimensions, toalargeextentindependentlyofaffect(Dieneretal.1985). These happiness data are increasingly used to tackle important questions in economics, as reviewed in Frey and Stutzer (2002), Layard (2005), and Di Tella and MacCulloch (2006). Indeed, the recent surge in interest is quite dramatic, as pointed out by Clark et al. (2008a), who counted 417 happiness related articles between 1960 and 2005 in Econlit. Of these, 76% had been 1036 J.Schwarze,R.Winkelmann publishedsince1995and30%since2003.Mostofthesepapersuse,inoneway or another, answer to current happiness or life satisfaction questions in cross section and panel survey data to study the factors that determine well-being, among them economic policies and institutions. Some of them test whether happinesspredictsbehavior.Clarketal.(1998)showthatlowjobsatisfaction predicts quits; Clark et al. (2008b) show that low happiness among married peoplepredictsdivorce. Themajorityofpapershastakenanindividualisticapproachtohappiness: One person’s happiness is not directly affected by how happy others are. Instead,there has beena substantialamountof work onindirect interdepen- dence, such as status interdependence or other kinds of externalities (e.g., Clark and Oswald 1996). Where direct interdependence has been studied, it has been limited to happiness interdependence among individuals within the samehousehold(e.g.,ShieldsandPrice2005;Winkelmann2005;Powdthavee 2009). Inthispaper,webroadenthescopeofanalysisandinvestigateinterdepen- denceamongindividualslivinginseparatehouseholds.Clearly,itismeaning- lesstosearchforinterdependencebetweenrandomlyselectedhouseholds.The households must be somehow related, know each other, communicate, and interact. In our case, the relationship is that of kinship, as we consider par- ent households and child households. Alternative relationships are possible. FowlerandChristakis(2008),forinstance,analyzehappinessinterdependence amongfriends. Our focus on the relationships between parents and children ties in with the economic literature on altruism within extended family. Becker (1981, 1991), taking seriously the Edgeworth (1881) proposal, formalized altruism withinaframeworkofutilitymaximizationunderinterdependentpreferences. Formally,supposethat V =U +ηU p p k wherethetotalutilityofaparent V isadditivelyrelatedtothechild’sutility p U . In this very simple model, η is the “coefficient of effective sympathy”, to k followEdgeworth’sdefinition,or,inourcontext,thealtruismparameter.Ifηis 0,wehaveasituationofnon-interdependentpreferences,or“selfishness”.For positiveη,anincreaseinthechild’sutilityleadstoanincreaseintheparent’s utility.Wecallthissituationoneof“altruisticpreferences”.Anegativeηwould reflectenvy. Becker (1981) showed that utility function 1 implies altruistic behavior: Undercertaincircumstances,parentswilltransferresourcestotheirchildren. But the inverse conclusion does not hold: Transfers can have many motives, and knowing whether they are driven by altruism, exchange, or joy of giving is relevant for many policy questions, including efficient reform of old age security, long-term care, and social assistance. It can be shown, e.g., that attempts by governments to redistribute income between generations can be neutralized if families are altruistic since if the income of a beneficiary of an Happinessandaltruismwithintheextendedfamily 1037 altruistictransferisincreased,thattransferwillbereducedbyanequalamount (seeLaferréreandWolff2006,forarecentsurveyoftheliterature). The majority of empirical papers estimate inter-household transfer equa- tions where the amount of transfers from parents to children is regressed on the parents’ income and income of the child together with other variables. Subsequently, tests can be set up to verify predictions from the model of altruistic families. However, this approach requires specific data on transfer paymentsbetweenfamilymembers.AsindicatedbyAltonjietal.(1992),the timingoftransfersisarbitrary,sothatstudiesthatarenotabletocoveralong periodmayleadtoincorrectconclusions.Inaddition,non-monetarytransfers, suchasservicesorhouseholdproducedgoods,aredifficulttoobserve. 3Data Our empirical analysis is based on the 2000–2004 waves of the GSOEP. This panel household survey was started in 1984 with a random sample of 5,624 householdsinWestGermany(Wagneretal.1993).In1990,itwasaugmented by a sample of East German households. From the outset, an attempt was made to trace and interview adult children who moved from their parents’ household to live in an own household alone or together with a partner and own children. If the tracing was successful, the GSOEP allows to link the originalhouseholdwithitsspin-off(s).Itisthereforepossibletomergedataon parentswiththoseontheirchildrenwhohavemovedout.Initially,suchcases wererarebutinrecentyearsthenumberoflinkableparent–childobservations became quite large, enabling the kind of analysis we want to conduct. We therefore selected the year 2000 as our first year of analysis. For that year, wecouldidentify930parenthouseholdswithlinkablespin-offs.By2004,that numberhadincreasedto1,118parenthouseholds. Thebasicunitofobservationisaparent–childpair.Westartedbyextracting all parents. If we could find for any of these fathers or mothers in any year information on at least one child living in a spin-off household, this parent– childpairconstitutesoneobservation.Eachadditionalyearforagivenchild, oreachadditionalchildinagivenyear,generatesoneadditionalobservation. The cross-sectional structure of the dataset from the parents’ point of view, for the year 2002, is depicted in Table 1. There were 1,750 parents for whom information on up to five children not living in the same household was available. Information for exactly one adult child not living in the same household was present for 1,317 parents. Three hundred sixty-three parents canbematchedtotwochildrenandsoon.Alltogether,the2002datacomprise 2,264observations(=parent/childpairs).Fromthetotalof1,750parents,1,454 or83%arecoupleswhereastheremaining296casesrefertosingleparents. Inthe2000–2004timedimension,thedataformanunbalancedpanel.The numberofparents(countingmothersandfathersseparately)withatleastone entryinanyofthe5yearsis2,562;26.4%ofparentsareobservedatmostthree times,19.6%areincludedfourtimes,andtheremaining54.0%isobservedin 1038 J.Schwarze,R.Winkelmann Table1 Structureofthedataset2002 Childrennotlivingin Numberofparents Mothers Fathers Numberof parents’household observations Frequency % Frequency Frequency Frequency % 1 1,317 75.3 708 609 1,317 58.0 2 363 20.7 199 164 726 32.2 3 61 3.5 33 28 183 8.1 4 7 0.4 4 3 28 1.2 5 2 0.1 1 1 10 0.4 Total 1,750 100 945 805 2,264 100 Parentsin2-parent 1,454 83.1 – – – – households Source:GSOEP2002 all 5 years, adding up to 8,630 separate parent-year observations. The total number of adult and independently living children contributing at least one observationis2,009.Again,manychildrenareobservedrepeatedlyovertime, sothatthereisatotalof6,520child-yearobservations. The particular structure of the dataset deserves some comment, as it de- viates from the standard random sampling assumption in a number of ways, necessitating corresponding adjustments to the econometric analysis. First, therearemultipleobservationsforthesameparent–childpairovertime.Time invarianteffectscanbeaccountedforbyusingfixedeffects,randomeffects,or byadjustingthestandarderrorsforclustering. Second, at any point in time, there can be either one or two parent–child observations in the same household. Two observations occur if both mothers and fathers respond in the survey. Household effects can be either period specific or time invariant. In the latter case, since parents are nested within households,householdfixedeffectsdonotcontributeanythingoverandabove parent fixed effects mentioned previously. In the former case, it is not an optiontoconditiononperiodspecifichouseholdeffectssincethemainvariable ofinterest,childhappiness,doesnotvarybetweenfathersandmothersatone point in time. Instead, standard errors can be adjusted for clustering at the householdlevel. Third, instances where the same parent is matched to several children constitute a problem in a regression context. The stochastic error capturing the unobserved determinants of a parents happiness is essentially the same, regardless of whether we condition on the happiness of a first or that of a second child, and hence, these observations cannot be independent. While this does not make running a regression technically impossible, one would need to account for the near perfect correlation when computing standard errors. Alternatively, one can average over the children’s observations and run the regression using such synthetic parent–child pairs. This approach is choseninthispaper.Italsoensuresthatparentswithmultiplechildrendonot get stronger weights in the regression than parents with a single child. The sensitivity of the results to taking averages was explored by using alternative Happinessandaltruismwithintheextendedfamily 1039 sampleslimitedtoparentswithonechildortheoldestchildonly,butnoneof thesubstantiveconclusionswasaffected. For each parent and child, we extracted a wide range of household and person specific socioeconomic variables. Happiness is measured using the following question: “How satisfied are you with your life, all things consid- ered? Please answer according to the following scale: “0” means completely dissatisfied,“10”meanscompletelysatisfied”.Lifesatisfactionandhappiness are treated here as synonymous. Potential determinants of happiness include age,agesquared,health,gender,nationality,yearsofeducation,maritalstatus, whetherwidowed,whetherdivorced,householdsize,numberofchildren,place ofabode,employmentstatus,andincome.Healthismeasuredbyaself-rating of the respondents on a five-point scale and converted to a “good-health” indicator for the values 4 and 5. Income is measured as disposable monthly post-government income of the household. Instead of applying an arbitrary equivalence scale, all models adopt a flexible specification of economies of scalebyincludingthelogofhouseholdsize,inadditiontothelogofhousehold income. The following variables are extracted for adult children not living in the parent’shousehold:age,gender,maritalstatus,health,education,employment status, and household income. They are computed in the same way as they wereforparents.InTable2,weseethatthearithmeticmeanofthehappiness Table2 Descriptivestatistics Parents Children Variable Mean Standarddeviation Mean Standarddeviation Happiness 6.57 1.80 7.06 1.59 Female 0.54 0.50 0.51 0.50 Age 57.4 8.7 30.7 6.1 Goodhealth 0.31 0.46 0.70 0.46 Married 0.82 0.38 0.46 0.50 Yearsofschooling 11.2 2.4 12.3 2.5 Unemployed 0.08 0.28 0.07 0.25 Retired 0.33 0.47 Houseownership 0.56 0.50 0.26 0.44 Loghouseholdincome 8.29 0.52 8.16 0.56 Loghouseholdsize 0.80 0.39 0.77 0.54 Distance(inkm) 49.3 112.1 Samedistrict 0.64 0.48 Numberofchildren 1.97 1.19 Ageatleavinghome 23.3 4.4 Year2000 0.18 0.39 0.18 0.39 Year2001 0.19 0.39 0.19 0.39 Year2002 0.20 0.40 0.20 0.40 Year2003 0.21 0.41 0.21 0.41 Year2004 0.22 0.41 0.22 0.41 Observations 8,630a 6,520b Source:GSOEP2000–2004 aExcludesmultipleperson-yearobservationsforparentswithseveralchildren bExcludesmultipleperson-yearobservationsforchildrenwithtwoparents 1040 J.Schwarze,R.Winkelmann responseisa6.6forparentsanda7.1forchildren.Parentsareonaverageabout 26.7yearsolderthantheiradultchildren.Childrenreportasubstantiallybetter healththanparents(70%asopposedto31%with“goodhealth”).Ontheother hand,themaritalrateismuchloweramongadultchildrenthanamongparents (46%asopposedto82%).Feweradultchildrenownahouse,andtheiraverage logincomeisabout13logpointsbelowthatoftheirparents. We also observe when children left their parental home and how far they moved.Theaverageageatmovingoutis23.3years.Sincetheaverageageat thetimeofsurveyis30.7,itmeansthatthesechildrenhavelivedontheirown foranaverageofabout7years.Thereissubstantialvariationinthetimeaway. About 20% of all children have moved within the last 2 years; about 25% of all children have moved out more than 10 years earlier. One might suspect that the elapsed time since moving out can affect the strength of measured preferenceinterdependence,aninteractionthatwillbetested. A similar moderation might result from the distance between parent and child. For example, any happiness interdependence effectively requires that parents know about their children’s momentary happiness, and distance can serve as a measure of the quality of that information. For example, the greaterthedistancebetweenthehouseholds,thelessaccuratelymightparents be informed about the living conditions and well-being of their children. In addition,ofcourse,distanceitselfmightdirectlyinfluenceaparent’shappiness. We employ two measures for geographical distance (this part of research using regional information was carried out at the DIW Berlin. We thank the staff for making the information available). The first is a simple indicator whether or not the child lives in the same district as the parents—this is the case for 65% of all children. The second is the distance in kilometers, using thegeographicalcoordinateofthecountyofresidence’smidpoint(European Terrestrial Reference System, ETRS89). The average distance between a parent’shouseholdandachild’shouseholdamountsto49km. 4Results Whatprimafacieevidenceisthereforinterdependenthappinessinourdata? In particular, is it the case that happier parents also have happier children? Table3showsasimplecross-tabulationofhappinessforparentsandchildren. Observationsarepooledover5years.Theoriginal11-pointscaleiscollapsed into a trichotomy: 0–5, 6–7, and 8–10 corresponding to the notions of below, average,andaboveaveragehappiness,respectively.Thetablerevealsastrong positiveassociationbetweenthehappinessofadultchildrenandthehappiness oftheirparents.Forexample,only23%ofparentsofadultchildrenwithbelow average happiness report an above average happiness themselves, compared to 44% of those parents with above average happy adult children. A formal Pearson chi-squared test rejects the independence hypothesis with p value of zero. A similar result is obtained when the original 11-point scale is used insteadofthegroupedcategories. Happinessandaltruismwithintheextendedfamily 1041 Table3 Happinessresponses Happiness Happinessofchild ofparentsandchildren (inpercent,n=8,630) ofparent 0–5 6–7 8–10 Total 0–5 40.0 27.9 20.1 26.6 6–7 36.9 40.7 36.3 38.3 8–10 23.1 31.4 43.6 35.1 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Source:GSOEP2000–2004 As mentioned before, the association in happiness of parents and children can reflect genetic and environmental factors as well as a true causal inter- dependence due to altruistic preferences. If happiness between parents and children were causally related, then one would expect to find that changes in happiness of parents are related to changes in happiness of children. Such an association is more convincing evidence for a causal relation, as it eliminates anypotentialconfoundinginterferenceoftime-invariantgeneticandenviron- mental factors. In Table 4, we show the distribution of year-to-year changes inaparent’shappiness(decline/increase)conditionalonyear-to-yearchanges inthereportedchildhappiness.Thefirsttwocolumnsareforanydecreaseor increase,respectively,whereasthesecondtwocolumnsrefertolargechanges in a child’s happiness, a decline or increase by a minimum of three points on the11-pointresponsescale. Indeed, we find an association in first differences as well. For example, the relative frequency of an increase in happiness for parents is lowered by 7.1 percentage points if the child’s happiness decreased by a minimum of 3, comparedtothecasewherethechild’shappinessincreasedbyaminimumof3. Inthe“allchanges”comparison,thecorrespondingassociationisreducedtoa 4.6percentagepointsdifference.APearsonchi-squaredtestindicatesrejection oftheindependenceassumption. To summarize, the evidence is compatible with the notion that part of the associationinhappinessresponsesofparentsandadultchildrenisduetodirect utility interdependence, or altruism. However, such a descriptive analysis cannot rule out that there are alternative explanations for interdependence. Foracloserunderstandingofwhattheseresultstellusaboutaltruism,weturn nowtoamoreformalmodelingapproach. Table4 Changesin Changeinhappiness Changeinhappinessofchild happinessresponsesof parentsbetweent−1andt, ofparent Anychange Largechange conditionalonchangesfor ≤−1 ≥+1 ≤−3 ≥+3 children(inpercent) Decrease 55.5 50.9 59.6 52.5 Increase 45.5 49.1 40.4 47.5 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Observations 1,173 954 166 143 pvaluechi-squared 0.036 0.204 Source:GSOEP2000–2004 1042 J.Schwarze,R.Winkelmann 4.1Regressionmodelsofparentalwell-being Astochasticversionofalinearizedutilityfunctionofparentscanbewrittenas V =U +ηU +u (1) p p k where V istheoverallutilityfunction,U =U(x )istheutilitythatparents p p p derive from things other than their child’s well-being, U =U(x ) is the k k child’s utility, u is a stochastic error term, and η is the altruism parameter of interest.x andx includeallfactorsthathavebeenidentifiedbytheprevious p k happiness literature as determinants of individual well-being. In traditional microeconomicutilitymodels,asexemplifiedbyBecker(1981),thiswouldbe primarily own consumption. The subjective well-being approach is broader, however, and x therefore includes many other factors, such as marital status, health,andemployment,besidesincomeandconsumption. The important assumption captured by Eq. 1, apart from linearity, is the absence of paternalistic preferences. By this, we mean that x enters the k parents’ overall utility not directly but only by way of mediation through the child’s utility U(x ). This assumption may not be very plausible, depending k on the variable x we have in mind. We can easily think of some factors that k makethechildhappybuttheparentunhappy(suchasperhapsanextramarital affairofthesonordaughter).Forothervariables(suchasage),theexclusion restrictionofnodirecteffectmaybemorereasonable.Ofcourse,thepresence ofpaternalisticpreferencesdoesnotmeanthataparentcannothavealtruistic preferencesatthesametime.Itonlymakesitsmeasurementfromsurveydata harder, as it generates endogeneity in model 1, through correlation between U andu.Wereturntothisissuelater. k Finally, the model does not say anything about more complex patterns of happinessinterdependence,suchasaltruismofchildrentowardtheirparents, or altruism between spouses. With altruism among spouses, a third term, V , should be included. An increase in child happiness increases V directly, s p throughη,andindirectly,throughitseffecton V .Equation1shouldthenbe s interpretedasapartialreducedform,measuringtheoveralleffect. 4.2Pooleddataregressions Happiness equations are often estimated using the ordered probit or the ordered logit model. However, as pointed out by Van Praag and Ferrer-i- Carbonell(2004),suchmodelsimplyanimplicitcardinalizationaswell.While linear regression models do not allow to draw inference on single outcome probabilities (such as the probability of scoring an 8 or above on a 0–10 response scale), trade-off ratios can be computed, and there is widespread evidence(exploredamongothersinFerrer-i-CarbonellandFrijters,2004)that these are quite robust to the choice of model. We use here the linear model approachsinceitmakestherequiredextensionstopaneldataandinstrumental variablemethodsmuchmoretransparent.

Description:
into a trichotomy: 0–5, 6–7, and 8–10 corresponding to the notions of below, average, and above average happiness, respectively. The table reveals a .. In addition, fixed effects models will differ out genetic (and thus heritable) differences in one's attitude to happiness. For instance, “o
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.