ebook img

Handbook of Agricultural Economics. Volume 1A: Agricultural Production. Handbooks in Economics 18 PDF

836 Pages·2001·12.43 MB·english
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Handbook of Agricultural Economics. Volume 1A: Agricultural Production. Handbooks in Economics 18

INTRODUCTION TO THE SERIES The aim of the Handbooks in Economics series is to produce Handbooks for various branches of economics, each of which is a definitive source, reference, and teaching supplement for use by professional researchers and advanced graduate students. Each Handbook provides self-contained surveys of the current state of a branch of economics in the form of chapters prepared by leading specialists on various aspects of this branch of economics. These surveys summarize not only received results but also newer devel- opments, from recent journal articles and discussion papers. Some original material is also included, but the main goal is to provide comprehensive and accessible surveys. The Handbooks are intended to provide not only useful reference volumes for profes- sional collections but also possible supplementary readings for advanced courses for graduate students in economics. KENNETH J. ARROW and MICHAEL D. INTRILIGATOR PUBLISHER' S NOTE For a complete overview of the Handbooks in Economics Series, please refer to the listing on the last two pages of this volume. CONTENTS OF THE HANDBOOK VOLUME 1A PART 1 - AGRICULTURAL PRODUCTION retpahC 1 Production and Supply YAIR MUNDLAK retpahC 2 Uncertainty, Risk Aversion, and Risk Management for Agricultural Producers GIANCARLO MOSCHINI and DAVID A. HENNESSY retpahC 3 Expectations, Information and Dynamics MARC NERLOVE and DAVID A. BESSLER retpahC 4 The Agricultural Innovation Process: Research and Technology Adoption in a Changing Agricultural Sector DAVID SUNDING and DAVID ZILBERMAN retpahC 5 Structural Change in Agricultural Production: Economics, Technology and Policy JEAN-PAUL CHAVAS retpahC 6 Land Institutions and Land Markets KLAUS DEININGER and GERSHON FEDER retpahC 7 Human Capital: Education and Agriculture WALLACE E. HUFFMAN retpahC 8 Women's Roles in the Agricultural Household: Bargaining and Human Capital Investments .T PAUL SCHULTZ retpahC 9 Human Capital: Migration and Rural Population Change J. EDWARD TAYLOR and PHILIP L. MARTIN retpahC 01 Agricultural Finance: Credit, Credit Constraints, and Consequences PETER J. BARRY and LINDON J. ROBISON vii viii Contents of the Handbook Chapter 11 Economic Impacts of Agricultural Research and Extension ROBERT E. EVENSON Chapter 12 The Agricultural Producer: Theory and Statistical Measurement RICHARD E. JUST and RULON D. POPE VOLUME 1B PART 2 - MARKETING, DISTRIBUTION AND CONSUMERS Chapter 13 Commodity Futures and Options JEFFREY C. WILLIAMS Chapter 14 Storage and Price Stabilization BRIAN WRIGHT Chapter 15 Food Processing and :noitubicasiD An Industrial Organization Approach RICHARD J. SEXTON and NATHALIE LAVOIE Chapter 16 Marketing Margins: Empirical Analysis MICHAEL K. WOHLGENANT Chapter 17 Spatial Price Analysis PAUL L. FACKLER and BARRY K. GOODWIN Chapter 18 Duality for the Household: Theory and Applications JEFFREY .T LaFRANCE Chapter 19 Economic Analysis of Food Safety JOHN M. ANTLE Chapter 20 Marketing and Distribution: Theory and Statistical Measurement JAMES VERCAMMEN and ANDREW SCHMITZ Chapter 21 Production and Marketing RACHAEL E. GOODHUE and GORDON C. RAUSSER INTRODUCTION The subject matter of agricultural economics has both broadened and deepened in re- cent years, and the chapters of this Handbook present the most exciting and innovative work being done today. The field originated early in the twentieth century with a focus on farm management and commodity markets, but has since moved far into analysis of issues in food, resources, international trade, and linkages between agriculture and the rest of the economy. In the process agricultural economists have been pioneering users of developments in economic theory and econometrics. Moreover, in the process of intense focus on problems of economic science that are central to agriculture - mar- ket expectations, behavior under uncertainty, multimarket relationships for both prod- ucts and factors, the economics of research and technology adoption, and public goods and property issues associated with issues like nonpoint pollution and innovations in biotechnology - agricultural economists have developed methods of empirical investi- gation that haveb een taken up in other fields. The chapters are organized into five parts, contained in two volumes. Volume 1 con- tains Part ,1 "Agricultural Production", and Part 2, "Marketing, Distribution and Con- sumers". These two parts include much of the traditional scope of agricultural eco- nomics, emphasizing advances in both theory and empirical application of recent years. Volume 2 consists of three parts: "Agriculture, Natural Resources and the Environment", "Agriculture in the Macroeconomy", and "Agricultural and Food Policy". Although agricultural economists have always paid attention to these topics, research devoted to them has increased substantially in scope as well as depth in recent years. A large-scale effort to review and assess the state of knowledge in agricultural eco- nomics was previously undertaken by the American Agricultural Economics Associ- ation (AAEA), with publication in four volumes from 1977 to 1992.1 Those earlier survey volumes have strikingly different subject-matter content from that of the present Handbook, especially considering that they described the same field only 20 years ago. The AAEA volumes have extensive coverage off arm management issues, costs of pro- duction in agriculture, and estimates of efficiency of marketing firms. In our judgment little in any fundamental way has been added to our knowledge in these areas, and applications have become routine rather than imaginative research. The largest AAEA volume was devoted entirely to agriculture in economic development. This remains a 1 A Survey of Economics Literature, eeL ,nitraM ed., :silopaenniM ytisrevinU of atosenniM .sserP -loV emu ,1 lanoitidarT dleiF of larutlucirgA scimonocE ;)7791( emuloV ,2 evitatitnauQ sdohteM ni larutlucirgA scimonocE emuloV ;)7791( ,3 scimonocE of ,erafleW laruR ,tnempoleveD dna larutaN secruoseR ;)1891( emuloV ,4 erutlucirgA cimonocE ni tnempoleveD .)2991( xi x Introduction most important topic, but we cover it in only one complete chapter and parts of sev- eral others. This reflects in part the integration of work on developing countries with mainstream applied work. For example, our chapters on production economics, expec- tations, and risk management also encompass applications to agriculture in developing economies. That integration points to another gradual but notable change in agricultural economists' research. The AAEA surveys had most of the chapters of one volume de- voted to quantitative methods. We do not have any separate methodological chapters. In contrast, we have several chapters with substantial development of economic theory. This reflects an evolution in the research priorities of leading agricultural economists who, following the earlier work of Nerlove on supply and Griliches on technological change, are working at the theoretical frontiers and simultaneously undertaking empiri- cal work - not just purveying new theories to their more "applied" colleagues. As its title indicates, the AAEA volumes were surveys of literature, and aimed at completeness of coverage within their subject matter. We asked our authors to be se- lective, to focus on what they saw as the main contributions to the area they covered, and to assess the state of knowledge and what remains to be learned. This approach has left some gaps in our coverage, and has given us some chapters that are perhaps more idiosyncratic than is usual for a survey chapter. In order to pull things together at a higher level of aggregation, we commissioned five "synthesis" chapters, one for each of the five parts of the Handbook. And, to provide our own even broader overview, the editors have written closing syntheses of each volume. Because these syntheses provide capsule summaries of each Handbook chapter, we will not present further description of content here. Although advances in research in agricultural economics are increasingly being made in many countries, our authors and coverage of applied topics is heavily U.S.-weighted (only six authors work outside of the U.S.: two in Europe, two in Australia, one in Canada, and one in Israel). Of those in the U.S., however, six are economists at the World Bank, an international rather than American institution. Probably in another twenty years or so one will have to become more international to capture the most interesting and exciting developments in the field, but that day has not arrived yet. Among the many debts we have accrued in the preparation of this Handbook, the most important was Rachael Goodhue. She not only assessed the substance of many chapters, but she persuaded many reviewers and authors alike to complete their assigned respon- sibilities. Other critical contributors include the dedicated staff who provided support at the University of California, Berkeley, and at the University of Maryland. At Maryland, Liesl Koch served as copy editor and guided the authors' final revisions and preparation of the manuscript with sure judgment and a finn but diplomatic hand, a job best likened to driving a herd of cats. Coordination of correspondence with authors and reviewers was organized and carried out at Berkeley with exemplary efficiency and organizational skill by Jef Samp, Jessica Berkson, and Jennifer Michael, under the direction of Nancy Lewis. Introduction ix eW also want to recognize the comments and suggestions received from 54 review- ers of chapter drafts: Julian Alston, Jock Anderson, Richard Barichello, Eran Beinen- baum, Michael Boehlje, Dan Bromley, Steve Buccola, Allan Buckwell, David Bul- lock, Michael Caputo, Jean-Paul Chavas, John Connor, Klaus Deiniuger, Jeffrey Doff- man, Marcel Fafchamps, Gershon Feder, Joe Glauber, Dan Gilligan, Rachael Goodhue, Tom Grennes, Zvi Griliches, Geoff Heal, Eithan Hochman, Matt Holt, Wallace Huff- man, D. Gale Johnson, Zvi Lerman, Erik Lichtenberg, Ethan Ligon, Alan Love, Jill McCluskey, Mario Miranda, Arie Oskam, Dick Perrin, Mark Rosegrant, Vern Ruttan, Ed Schuh, Kathleen Segerson, Larry Sjaastad, Spiro Stefanou, Jo Swinnen, Frans van der Zee, Finis Welch, Abner Womack, and Jacob Yaron. BRUCE GARDNER GORDON RAUSSER Chapter 1 PRODUCTION AND SUPPLY YAIR MUNDLAK Faculty of Agriculture, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Rehovot, Israel Contents Abstract 4 .1 Primal estimates or the Cobb-Douglas culture 5 1.1. The setting of the agenda 5 1.2. A simple production model 9 1.3. Productivity 12 1.4. The productivity of capital 16 1.5. Productivity and heterogeneous technology 16 1.6. Heterogeneous technology 18 1.7. Cross-country studies 20 1.8. The rate of technical change 26 1.9. Primal estimates - summary 27 2. The duality culture 28 2.1. Studies based on cost functions 32 2.2. What is the message? 35 2.3. Studies based on profit functions 36 2.4. Dual estimates - summary 39 3. Multiproduct production 40 4. Nonparametric methods 43 4.1. Description 43 4.2. Discussion 45 5. Supply analysis 47 5.1. Background 47 5.2. Static analysis 49 6. Dynamics 51 6.1. The firm's problem 51 6.2. Discussion 53 6.3. The role of prices and technology 53 6.4. Disinvestment 55 6.5. Empirical investment analysis 56 6.6. Exogenous dynamics 57 Handbook of Agricultural Economics, Volume ,1 Edited by B. Gardner and .G Rausser © 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved Y kaldnuM .7.6 suonegodnE scimanyd - eht lamirp hcaorppa 58 .8.6 suonegodnE scimanyd -the laud hcaorppa 59 .9.6 laciripmE tnemtsevni sisylana ni erutlucirga 61 .01.6 cimanyD rotcaf dnamed gnisu ytilaud 63 .11.6 noissucsiD 68 7. The scope for policy evaluation 71 .1.7 yrammuS dna snoisulcnoc 73 Acknowledgement 77 References 77 Abstract The work of more than 50 years aimed at gaining empirical insight into the production structure of agriculture and the related modes of farmers' behavior is reviewed, and orders of magnitude of the various parameters of interest are quoted. The review follows the lines of the evolution of the pertinent research, and it builds on it in forming a general framework for empirical work. This approach broadens the scope of producers' decisions to include the choice of the implemented technology and it also overcomes statistical problems that have accompanied the relevant research for a long time. JEL classification: Q11 .hC :1 noitcudorP dna ylppuS 5 Technology along with the competitive conditions constitute the core of the supply side of the economy. There is hardly a subject in economics that can be discussed with pro- duction sitting in the balcony rather than playing center stage. To mention the main favorable subjects in agricultural economics research: product supply, factor demand, technical change, income distribution, the relationships between factor prices and prod- uct prices, the competitive position of agriculture, returns to scale, the size distribution of firms, and capital accumulation. The nature of the relationships and the conclusions derived in any particular analysis depend on the order of magnitude of the parameters in question. Hence, whether we want it or not, the empirical analysis of technology and its changes is of cardinal importance, and measurement problems are pertinent even if on the surface it seems that the subject matter is not 'technical'. In this review, we deal with the various aspects of the analysis. As will become clear, much of the discussion in the literature is methodology driven, not always accompanied by substantive applications. Inasmuch as methodological innovations are desirable, the question is how do they help us to think of, or deal with, specific issues of interest. This is a question that the reader should try to answer for himself, depending on his particular interest. To assist in this endeavor, we summarize here the empirical findings that bear on the main parameters of interest and address some important methodological issues essential to the interpretation of empirical studies and to future research. In many cases, the empirical results display a wide range and thus highlight the need for an appropriate framework for their evaluation. The choice of subjects and the coverage in the discussion are carried out with the purpose of constructing a uniform framework to meet the purpose. This is built on the cumulative experience and contributions provided by numerous studies and on the evolution of the thinking that is so valuable in the reading and the interpretation of the data. To emphasize this aspect, the subjects are introduced largely in an Order that highlights this evolution. There are two fairly distinct periods in the study of agricultural production functions: before and after duality. The changing of the guard was in the early 1970s, although a few studies employing direct estimation continue to appear after 1970. The appear- ance of duality changed not only the method of estimation but also the questions asked to the extent that there is little continuity in the subjects of interest. This can be ac- counted for by the fact that much of the work is methodology-driven rather than being an indication that the old questions had been adequately answered or of any explicit agenda. 1. Primal estimates or the Cobb-Douglas culture 1.1. The setting of the agenda It seems that the empirical work on agricultural production functions originated in a methodological paper by Tintner (1944) and an application by Tintner and Brownlee (1944), which appeared as a short paper in the Notes section of the Journal of Farm 6 E Mundlak Economics and was followed by a full size paper by Heady (1946). This work was influenced by the work of Cobb and Douglas (1928). 1 It thus took about fifteen years to adopt the work of Cobb and Douglas in agricultural economics application. These studies used data from a random sample of Iowa farms for 1939. The data were classified by area of the state, type, and also size of farm. The inputs included were land, labor, equipment, livestock and feed, and miscellaneous operating expense, a classifi- cation that is still applicable today. Interestingly, this early work anticipated some of the more difficult subjects in the empirical work of production functions. Management was recognized as an input, but "the productive agent management has been excluded since there is no satisfactory index of inputs for this factor" Tintner and Brownlee (1944, p. 566). Allusions were also made to the importance of input quality. 2 Heady (1946) expressed similar concerns about the quality issue and the omission of man- agement. 3 Also, based on the criticism of the Cobb--Douglas work that appeared at that time by Reder (1943 ), Bronfenbrenner (1944), and Marschak and Andrews (1944), Heady (1946) noted that "Ithe functions which have been derived ... are of the inter- firm rather than intrafarm variety ... it can he expected that a multitude of functions exists ... because of the varying combinations of techniques employed and commodi- ties produced" (p. 999). This is a recognition of the problems caused by aggregation over techniques. Similarly, Smith (1945) observed that firms in cross section may em- ploy different techniques, particularly due to fixed plants inherited from the past, and the long-run production functions so derived may represent "mongrels" or hybrids. Aside from the question of input quality, Bronfenbrenner (i 944) raised the point that capital and labor are not on the same footing because labor is a flow ("quantity used"), whereas capital is a stock (representing the "available quantity"). This can be interpreted as an early recognition of the conceptual problem of the evaluation of the productivity of durable inputs. These studies were concerned with the contribution of inputs to output variations and with a comparison of the factor productivity on different farm types and the relationship to their returns. The estimated production elasticities reported by Tintner and Brownlee (1944) for the sample as a whole are: land, 0.34; labor, 0.24; and other assets and vari- able inputs, 0.41. The sum is 0.99. Heady used a larger sample and a somewhat different classification of inputs to obtain for the sample as a whole: land, 0.23; labor, 0.03; and other assets and variable inputs, 0.59. The sum is 0.85. 1 A noisserger noitauqe linear in eht smhtiragol "is ralimis to eht noitcudorp function employed by luaP salguoD in sih laciripme "seiduts rentniT dna eelnworB ,4491( .p .)765 nO eht history of eht salguoD-bboC noitcudorp ,noitcnuf ees salguoD .)6791( 2 "Using eht number of serca ni eht farms sa a erusaem of stupni of land serongi snoitairav ni eht quality of .dnal gnirusaeM stupni of labor in smret of shtnom of labor also serongi snoitairav in eht ytilauq dna ytisnetni of ,robal ylralucitrap that of rotarepo dna sih family" rentniT dna eelnworB ,4491( .p .)665 3 At eht time eht issue of tnemeganam bias saw ,dezingocernu erofereht both papers detaluceps that dah tnemeganam been ,dedulcni eht mus of eht ,seiticitsale sa a erusaem of snruter to ,elacs would have desaercni reutniT dna eelnworB ,4491( .p ,)965 Heady ,6491( .p 995). ,revewoH Heady also setacidni that eht mus of eht seiticitsale might have desaerced eud to eht noitcudortni of tnemeganam ,,dibI( .p .)799

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.