Green Expectations: Current Effects of Anticipated Carbon Pricing∗ Derek Lemoine Department of Economics, University of Arizona McClelland Hall 401, 1130 E Helen St, Tucson, AZ, 85721-0108, USA [email protected] University of Arizona Working Paper 13-09 June 2013 First version: April 2013 Forward-looking markets respond not just to current policies but also to expectations of future policies. The “green paradox” literature suggests that a future environmental policy increases emissions today, potentially even rendering the policy ineffective. However, the theory’s relevance has been an open question in the absence of empirical confirmation and measurement. I generalize the green paradox to a market with imperfectly substitutable commodities in order to measure it in U.S. energy markets. An event study confirms the primary prediction: coal futures produced positive excess returns of around 2% upon the unexpected collapse of the U.S. Senate’s 2010 climate effort. If coal producers had expected the proposed legislation to become law, their resulting production increase would have made the future emission constraint act like a current subsidy of up to $12 per ton of carbon dioxide. The response of natural gas prices and the theoretical analysis together suggest that while the legislative process was indeed increasing U.S. emissions prior to 2013, passing the legislation would have eventually decreased cumulative emissions. JEL: H23, Q41, Q58 Keywords: green paradox, anticipation, hotelling, energy, futures, commodities, emissions, climate, leakage ∗IamgratefulforcommentsfromseminarparticipantsatArizona,ArizonaState,HECMontr´eal,Toronto, UC Berkeley, UC Davis, and Yale. Hoa Nguyen provided research assistance. This work was supported by the University of Arizona’s Renewable Energy Network, with special thanks to Ardeth Barnhart and Stan Reynolds. I also thank Keisuke Hirano and Ashley Langer for helpful discussions. Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 In 2009, the U.S. House of Representatives passed a bill to cap carbon dioxide emissions. TheSenatesoonbegandraftingcomplementarylegislation. Theemissioncapwastobeginin 2013, four years after the House bill’s passage, twelve years after Congress first voted on cap- and-trade legislation, and twenty-five years after attention-grabbing Congressional hearings. Energymarketshadampleforewarning. The“greenparadox”literaturesuggeststhatenergy producers increase near-term extraction when they anticipate future adoption of a climate policy. In many models, the increase in near-term emissions completely offsets the eventual environmental benefits of climate legislation. However, the existence and magnitude of green paradox effects are both open questions. For instance, van der Werf and Di Maria (2012) conclude their recent review by lamenting that “the most striking void in this literature is an empirical assessment of the green paradox, without which it is hard (if not impossible) to provide even order of magnitude estimates of green paradox effects.” I use an event study of the weekend collapse of the U.S. Senate’s climate effort to establish the existence of a green paradox in U.S. energy markets and to bound its magnitude from below. I find that if coal producers had anticipated that the proposed climate policy would actually pass, they would have increased coal production as if offered an emission subsidy of between $1 and $12 per ton of carbon dioxide. This current subsidy stands in stark contrast to the tax of between $5 and $65 per ton required to internalize the climate externality (Greenstone et al., 2013). The current situation of not pricing carbon emissions for a bit longer is generating more contemporary emissions than simply not pricing carbon emissions at all. Further, the increase in coal production during the unsuccessful legislative process distortedpricestoasimilardegreeasdidrailroads’marketpower(BusseandKeohane,2007) and utility regulation (Cicala, 2012). Green paradox effects are economically significant, and they have probably been distorting energy markets for years. Theoretical models of green paradox effects disagree about whether intertemporal emis- sion leakage completely offsets the future benefits of climate policy. First, in Hotelling (1931) models of physical exhaustion, producers have a finite endowment of homogeneous energy resources to allocate over time. An anticipated climate policy increases current emissions but has no effect on cumulative emissions, which are completely determined by the physical endowment (e.g., Sinn, 2008, 2012; Di Maria et al., 2012). By tilting the emission profile towards the present, the future policy actually increases the present value of environmental damages. In contrast, Heal (1976) models endogenize total resource use by making marginal cost increase in cumulative extraction. Commodity producers no longer decide merely how to allocate a given resource over time but also decide how much to extract in total. The future carbon price reduces planned future extraction, which also reduces the incentive to conserve low-cost resources for the future. In this setting, the anticipated climate policy decreases cumulative emissions because it decreases cumulative extraction. The policy’s net effect on the present value of damages depends on the importance of the early increase in emissions relative to the ultimate decrease in emissions (e.g., Gerlagh, 2011; Hoel, 2012). The U.S. Senate’s climate legislation would have primarily regulated electricity markets, 1 Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 which are dominated by generation from coal and natural gas. Physical exhaustion is not a prime concern for these resources.1 However, previous models which endogenize cumulative extraction have only considered markets with a single resource. When there are multiple resources, substitution effects complicate the standard green paradox story. The future policy taxes both commodities, but it taxes the higher-emission commodity (coal) more than the lower-emission commodity (natural gas). The future policy therefore could increase future natural gas consumption and reverse the direction of that commodity’s anticipation effect. My theoretical analysis generates a testable prediction for coal markets and links natural gas market outcomes to electric power sector emission outcomes. First, I predict that coal consumption increases in anticipation of an emission price. Second, I show that if the policy proposal also increases pre-implementation consumption of natural gas, then it eventually succeeds in decreasing cumulative emissions. While green paradox effects do undercut climate policy, they do not render it completely ineffective as long as natural gas and coal markets move in the same direction. I find that coal prices responded to the collapse of the Senate’s climate effort with a statistically significant jump in the theoretically predicted direction. Further, the estimated response of natural gas prices has the same sign as the response of coal prices. Therefore, while energy producers were increasing emissions in anticipation of the proposed cap-and- trade program (manifesting a “weak” green paradox), the program’s implementation would have decreased emissions after 2013 and in total (avoiding a “strong” green paradox). While not discussing a climate bill at all would have generated fewer contemporary emissions, the climate would nonetheless have eventually benefited from the bill’s passage. However, the bill did not pass. The additional emissions from its discussion in 2009–2010 were therefore neveroffsetbyacarbonprice. Whilepassingthelegislation wouldhavedecreasedcumulative emissions, the unsuccessful legislative process actually increased cumulative emissions. The anticipation effect at the heart of the green paradox is a more general feature of pub- lic economics. Anticipating future changes in taxes on investment, income, or consumption can induce smoothing behavior or offsetting behavior (Hall, 1971; Branson et al., 1986; Judd, 1985; Auerbach, 1989; Yang, 2005; Mertens and Ravn, 2011). These anticipation effects can strongly affect the excess burden of taxation (Judd, 1987). The Hall (1971) consumption tax has particularly similar effects to a proposed emission tax: the future change in the tax causes a jolt to real flows which an anticipation effect offsets by shifting earlier real flows in the opposite direction.2 The empirical literature on tax anticipation has obtained mixed 1Indeed, Jones et al. (2013) question the relevance of the green paradox on the basis of the common assumption of exhaustibility: “Perhaps most fundamentally, however, whether fossil fuels are best modeled as exhaustible is questionable: empirically, the evolution of resource prices is not well-described by simple Hotelling-typemodels;andstocks—especiallyofcoal—aresolargethattherelevanceofexhaustionismoot.” 2Inmodelsofrationaladdiction,presentconsumptionincreasesthemarginalutilityfromfutureconsump- tion. Anticipated taxes therefore reduce present and future consumption. These effects have been identified in, for instance, cigarette markets (e.g., Becker et al., 1994; Gruber and K¨oszegi, 2001). In our setting, present production increases the marginal cost of future production. Anticipated taxes therefore increase 2 Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 results that depend on how one constructs the timing of tax changes (Mertens and Ravn, 2012; Perotti, 2012). Identifying anticipation effects in commodity markets is more straight- forward for two reasons: these markets probably lack liquidity constraints that could mask the effect for individuals or households, and proposals for emission pricing are not themselves responding to commodity market movements as, for instance, personal taxation responds to aggregate output or consumption. My results indicate that hypothesized anticipation effects need not make overly strong demands of market efficiency. I use an event that occurred among the parties developing climate legislation to isolate an exogenous shift in the probability of regulation. Narrative evidence, contemporary news accounts, and prediction market trades all indicate that expectations of regulation shifted when Senator Lindsey Graham walked out of his climate collaboration over the weekend before its scheduled unveiling. I measure the strength of green paradox effects by estimating how futures markets responded to Graham’s decision. Event studies typically examine stock market returns. In particular, event studies of energy policy have used changes in equity prices to learn about the cost of regulation and about the distributional consequences of cap-and-trade programs (Lange and Linn, 2008; Linn, 2010; Bushnell et al., 2013). Futures markets instead teach us about the consequences for energy consumption and emissions. In contrast to equity market outcomes, these consequences are largely independent of how regulators choose to allocate emission permits in a cap-and-trade program. I begin by analyzing how commodity spot prices, futures prices, and emissions respond to new information about future emission policies. The theoretical model highlights the in- terplay between higher- and lower-emission commodities and generates predictions relevant to proposed climate legislation. Section 2 combines several lines of evidence to argue that Senator Graham’s weekend withdrawal from his climate bill conveyed unanticipated infor- mation that altered expectations. Section 3 introduces the estimation framework by which I identify the event’s effect on futures markets. Section 4 demonstrates the anticipation effect in coal futures across a range of specifications. Section 5 demonstrates that other days with similar prediction market movements also saw sizable increases in coal prices. It then evaluates the magnitude of the event’s effect on coal prices and uses the effect on natural gas prices to learn about the existence of a green paradox in emissions. Section 6 concludes with the policy implications of finding that markets are distorted by the suggestion of regulation. 1 Current effects of anticipated taxation Consider a two-period model with two commodities, indexed by H and L. A representative consumerobtainsutilityU(qH,qL)fromconsumingquantitiesqH andqL attimet,whereutil- t t t t ity is increasing, quadratic, twice-differentiable, and strictly concave. The two commodities present production and decrease future production, though substitution between commodities can reverse these effects. 3 Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 are at least partially substitutable: U < 0, where subscripts indicate partial derivatives.3 HL Consumingthehigher-emissioncommodityH generatesemissionsatrateeH, andconsuming the lower-emission commodity L generates emissions at rate eL, with eH ≥ eL ≥ 0. Aggre- gate time t emissions are E ≡ eHqH + eLqL. A two-commodity market roughly matches t t t the empirical setting: the two major sources of dispatchable generation in U.S. electricity markets are coal (the higher-emission product) and natural gas (the lower-emission product). The emissions are externalities, with the usual first-best policy pricing them in each period at their marginal damage. We consider the case where emissions are not priced in the first period, but the regulator imposes a linear emission tax τ in the second period. There are twoequivalentwaysofinterpretingthissetting: thegovernmentdoesnotsucceedinadopting the pollution policy until the second period, or the government adopts the policy in the first period but delays its implementation to allow regulators and firms time to prepare. Firms anticipate the second-period tax when selecting their first-period production schedules. Firms are identical price-takers, allowing us to analyze them via a representative firm. Production cost for product type k is an increasing, quadratic, twice-differentiable, strictly (cid:0) (cid:1) convex function of cumulative production: Ck Qk . Let Qk indicate the cumulative quan- t (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:0) (cid:1) tity produced prior to time t. Then the cost of time t extraction is C qk +Qk −C Qk . t t t Increasing either current or previous extraction increases current marginal cost by the same amount.4 Neither coal nor natural gas markets face a clear threat of exhaustion, but pro- ducers in both markets have steadily moved towards less accessible reserves: coal mining has progressed from surface seams to mountaintop removal, while gas companies have developed techniques to access ever deeper reservoirs and “unconventional” shale reserves. The representative firm maximizes the present value of profits, with discount factor β ∈ (0,1] and Q normalized to zero: 1 (cid:88) (cid:8) (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:2) (cid:0) (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:0) (cid:1)(cid:1) (cid:3)(cid:9) max pkqk −Ck qk +β pkqk − Ck qk +qk −Ck qk −τekqk , (1) 1 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 2 {qH,qL,qH,qL} 1 1 2 2 k∈{H,L} 3Other work on extraction profiles with multiple commodities has assumed physical exhaustion and/or perfectsubstitutability (e.g.,Chakravortyet al.,2008; Smuldersand van derWerf,2008). Michielsen (2011) develops a green paradox model with one exhaustible resource and two imperfectly substitutable, inex- haustible resources. Because these two backstops are each produced at constant marginal cost, their supply is not intertemporally linked. Di Maria et al. (2012) consider implementation lags when there are two perfectly substitutable, exhaustible resources. I also find that first-period extraction of the high-emission commodity usually increases in the emission tax (as with their “abundance effect”), but its cumulative ex- traction nonetheless usually decreases in the present setting. I also describe cases in which extraction of the low-emission resource declines in the first period (similar to their “ordering effect”), but in the present set- ting,thischangeneednotbefullyoffsetbyincreasedextractioninthesecondperiodandisevencompatible with declining second-period extraction. 4The crucial feature of the cost function is that second-period marginal cost increases in first-period extraction, as is common in Heal (1976) models. Two papers take other approaches to endogenizing total resource use. Fischer and Salant (2012) posit a series of exhaustible resource pools, each with a different marginal cost of extraction. Smulders et al. (2012) generate a green paradox via households’ consumption and savings decisions in a general equilibrium setting where energy and capital are complements. 4 Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 where subscripts index time and superscripts index commodities. The firm’s optimal quan- tities solve the following four first-order conditions: (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:2) (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:0) (cid:1)(cid:3) pk =Ck(cid:48) qk +β Ck(cid:48) qk +qk −Ck(cid:48) qk , for k ∈ {H,L}, (2) 1 1 1 2 1 (cid:0) (cid:1) pk =Ck(cid:48) qk +qk +τek, for k ∈ {H,L}, (3) 2 1 2 where primes indicate derivatives. The firm equates marginal revenue to a comprehensive measure of marginal cost. In both periods, marginal cost includes the marginal extrac- tion cost. In the first period, it also includes the (discounted) additional cost imposed by extracting from more costly reserves in the second period. In the second period, it also includes emission tax payments. Quantity decisions are linked over time by the dependence of marginal extraction cost on cumulative extraction. Substituting among the four equations and recognizing that equilibrium prices are equal to marginal utility, we obtain: (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:0) (cid:1) U qH,qL +βτeH =βU qH,qL +(1−β)CH(cid:48) qH , and H 1 1 H 2 2 1 (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:0) (cid:1) (cid:0) (cid:1) U qH,qL +βτeL =βU qH,qL +(1−β)CL(cid:48) qL , L 1 1 L 2 2 1 where subscripts on the utility function again indicate partial derivatives. These equations characterize firms’ intertemporal decisions. The left-hand side measures the marginal benefit of extracting in period 1 instead of period 2: it includes the revenue from selling the com- modity in period 1 and the gain from not paying the tax in period 2. The right-hand side measures the marginal cost of extracting in period 1 instead of period 2: the firm forgoes revenue by not selling in period 2 and no longer discounts extraction costs. At an optimum, the firm is indifferent between extracting in these two periods. The anticipated tax provides an incentive to extract more of the resource earlier, and that incentive is stronger for more emission-intensive commodities. 1.1 Effects on coal markets Begin by considering a system with only one commodity. The solid lines in the left-hand plot of Figure 1 show demand and supply in a model in which second-period extraction costs are independent of first-period extraction or, equivalently, in which the firm is myopic (β = 0). The firm’s profit-maximizing quantity (point A ) occurs at the intersection of 1 these curves. When extraction costs instead depend on cumulative extraction and the firm is forward-looking, the first period’s supply curve is shifted inward (dashed line) because additional extraction increases costs in the second period. These intertemporal linkages reduce first-period extraction (to point B ). 1 Now consider the effect of introducing an emission tax in the second period. The right- hand plot in Figure 1 shows second-period supply and demand. Introducing the tax reduces the second period’s equilibrium quantity from B to C(cid:48). This is the tax’s direct effect. 2 2 5 Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 Figure 1: When costs depend on cumulative extraction, first-period marginal cost (dashed line) includes the effect on second-period costs, which reduces the equilibrium quantity to B 1 from the myopic equilibrium A . Imposing a second-period tax reduces the second-period 1 market-clearing quantity from B to C and increases the first-period quantity from B to 2 2 1 C . 1 Because the tax reduces the marginal benefit of conserving resources for the second period, the firm has a smaller opportunity cost to exploiting first-period reserves. Equivalently, when second-period extraction decreases, additional first-period extraction increases second- period costs by a smaller amount. The first-period supply curve therefore shifts out (dotted line) part of the way towards the myopic curve. Raising the second-period tax increases first-period extraction from point B to C , but extraction remains lower than it would have 1 1 been in a world with only one period. Greater first-period extraction shifts supply inward in the second period (dotted line), which further reduces the equilibrium quantity to C . The 2 increase in first-period extraction and the further decrease in second-period extraction are anticipation effects. In a system with both a more emission-intensive commodity (coal) and a less emission- intensive commodity (natural gas), the effect of a marginally greater tax depends on the relative emission intensity of the two commodities. Figure 2 summarizes the appendix’s formal results regarding how the higher-emission commodity responds to the tax. In the region on the left, coal is relatively dirty and its first- and second-period quantities respond as in the system with only a single commodity. In the three regions on the right, coal is not much dirtier than natural gas. Now coal’s quantity responses can be reversed from the single-commodity setting due to interactions with natural gas markets. These rightmost regions exist only if marginal utility responds strongly to coal consump- tion while neither marginal utility nor marginal extraction cost respond strongly to natural 6 Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 Figure 2: The response of the equilibrium quantity of coal to the tax, as proved in the appendix. The region marked with an asterisk is guaranteed to exist. The existence of the other regions depends on the curvature of the utility and cost functions. gas consumption.5 Both gas and coal might have a similar price elasticity of demand in electricity markets, but natural gas also has major markets in relatively price-inelastic res- idential and industrial applications. Further, natural gas probably has a more curved cost function due to the smaller size of each reserve, and its emission intensity is around half that of coal. Therefore, supply, demand, and emission considerations suggest that the leftmost region of Figure 2 is the only region of interest in our empirical application. In that case, a greater tax has a qualitatively similar effect on coal consumption in both the one- and two-commodity settings. 1.2 Effects on natural gas markets Natural gas markets more plausibly deviate from the single-commodity intuition. Three effects determine the sign of the change in second-period natural gas consumption. First, the tax wedge always acts to reduce consumption (direct effect), where the per-unit tax is smaller in the natural gas market than in the coal market due to its lower emission intensity. Second, changes in first-period natural gas extraction via anticipation effects affect second- period supply. For instance, when first-period extraction increases in anticipation of reduced second-period extraction, the corresponding reduction in second-period supply further re- duces second-period extraction. Third, the reduction in coal’s second-period consumption 5When marginal utility and marginal cost are flat for product L, its quantity responds strongly to small changes in its per-unit tax. This strong change increases the value of additional product H (i.e., it shifts out residual demand for H). When residual demand for H is sufficiently inelastic, the tax’s direct effect is small. Therefore, when both products have similar emission intensities (and so similar per-unit taxes), the greater residual demand for H can overturn the direct effect of the tax. 7 Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 Figure 3: The response of the equilibrium quantity of natural gas to the tax, as proved in the appendix. The region marked with an asterisk is guaranteed to exist. The existence of the other regions depends on the curvature of the utility and cost functions. increases the residual demand for natural gas, which tends to increase second-period con- sumption of natural gas (substitution effect). The net effect is ambiguous because the direct effect always opposes the substitution effect. The change in first-period extraction is also ambiguous. While first-period substitution effects always decrease residual demand for nat- ural gas, the first-period change in supply from anticipation effects is ambiguous because the second-period change in extraction is ambiguous. Because of the stronger substitution effects and smaller direct effects in gas markets, each period’s natural gas consumption could plausibly increase or decrease in response to a larger second-period tax. Figure 3 orders the possible outcomes based on the formal analysis in the appendix. Towards the right, natural gas is nearly as dirty as coal. Substitution effects are weak because the two commodities are taxed at nearly the same level, and natural gas markets therefore respond to a greater tax as they would in a single-commodity setting. Towards the left, natural gas is very clean relative to coal. Substitution effects are so strong that they reverse its quantity responses in all periods and in total: because the emission tax imposes a much greater cost on each unit of coal, second-period consumption shifts strongly towards natural gas and first-period consumption of natural gas decreases in anticipation of this greater second-period demand. As U shrinks towards zero, substitution effects become HL smaller and the rightmost region grows to fill nearly the whole area. As U increases in HL magnitude, substitution effects become stronger and all vertical lines shift to the right. The crucial part of Figure 3 is the ordering of the middle regions, where the response of natural gas to the tax is the same as in the single-commodity system over some timeframes butdifferentoverothers. Inparticular, notethatwhenmovingfromrighttoleft(i.e., making naturalgascleanerrelativetocoalandtherebyincreasingthestrengthofsubstitutioneffects), thefirst-periodquantityresponseswitchesitssignbeforethesecond-periodquantityresponse 8 Lemoine Green Expectations June 2013 Figure 4: When a marginally greater second-period tax increases the second period’s equilib- rium quantity of natural gas (from X to Y ), the first period’s anticipation and substitution 2 2 effects both work to decrease the first period’s equilibrium quantity (from X to Y ). 1 1 does. While it might seem that there are four plausible combinations of first- and second- period quantity responses, only three are actually possible. The analytic results rule out any case where a marginally greater tax increases natural gas consumption in both periods. If we observe a greater tax increasing first-period natural gas consumption, then we know it decreases natural gas consumption in the second period and in total. Figure 4 provides the intuition for why a greater tax cannot increase natural gas con- sumption in both periods. Assume that second-period consumption of natural gas increases in the tax. Recall that three effects determine second-period consumption: the tax wedge tendsto reduceit(direct effect), the greaterresidualdemand due todecreased coal consump- tion tends to increase it (substitution effect), and the altered supply curve due to changes in first-period extraction (anticipation effect) has an ambiguous effect. The anticipation effect increases first-period extraction (and shifts second-period supply inward) when the height of the tax wedge is greater than the outward shift in residual demand at the original market-clearing quantity, and it decreases first-period extraction otherwise. The anticipa- tion effect reinforces the net effect of the other two. Under our assumption of an increase in second-period consumption (e.g., from X to Y ), the residual demand curve must shift 2 2 out (to the dashed line in the right-hand plot) by a large amount relative to the tax, and the anticipation effect must decrease first-period extraction while shifting out second-period supply (to the dotted line). Now consider the determinants of first-period consumption. Second-period consump- tion of natural gas increases when substitution effects make future sales more profitable, in 9
Description: