ebook img

From the Paris Agreement to a Low-Carbon Bretton Woods : Rationale for the Establishment of a Mitigation Alliance PDF

250 Pages·2017·2.79 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview From the Paris Agreement to a Low-Carbon Bretton Woods : Rationale for the Establishment of a Mitigation Alliance

Michele Stua From the Paris Agreement to a Low-Carbon Bretton Woods Rationale for the Establishment of a Mitigation Alliance From the Paris Agreement to a Low-Carbon Bretton Woods Michele Stua From the Paris Agreement to a Low-Carbon Bretton Woods Rationale for the Establishment of a Mitigation Alliance Michele Stua C+3C Sistemi e Strategie srl Venezia, Italy The views expressed in this book are attributable only to the author in a personal capacity, and not to any institution with which he is associated, or to the funders or supporters of the paper. ISBN 978-3-319-54698-8 ISBN 978-3-319-54699-5 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-54699-5 Library of Congress Control Number: 2017933478 © Springer International Publishing AG 2017 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. The publisher remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations. Printed on acid-free paper This Springer imprint is published by Springer Nature The registered company is Springer International Publishing AG The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland A Federico With so much at stake, and with such enormous difficulties of inducing countries to surrender their sovereignty to the global good, surely it pays to look back carefully at history. (Maurice David Levi) Foreword Twenty short years ago, an American delegation, inspired by the adoption of the Clean Air Act of 1990 that established an emission trading system for sulphur emis- sions in the north-eastern states of the USA, had the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) inserted in the Kyoto Protocol. Since then, the idea of trading in emission rights has been prominent in all talks about reduction of GHG emissions – this in spite of the fact that trading concededly has never had, and was never intended to have, any emissions reduction outcome (some would even argue to the contrary) and this also despite the recent demise of the CDM, suffering many ills, but in the end killed by starvation (in the sense that markets had lost their appetite). Hardly by design, the Paris Agreement reinvigorated if not the CDM, then the idea that trading is part of the solution. Although Article 6 is careful to avoid any reference, the CDM looms large. Although wording on ‘net reduction’ is included, possibly to comfort those that are convinced of the counterproductivity of trading, it is nevertheless a basis for a new trading regime at risk of repeating history. ‘Those who cannot remember the past are condemned to repeat it’. Article 6, however, is not a likely result of a failing memory. Hopefully it is not the result of a selective one either. The CDM was immensely successful in some areas – but fatally flawed in others. It is worth considering what objective trading serves. The CDM was burdened with a multitude of objectives, not least technology transfer and cost-efficiency, but not emissions reduction as any emissions reduction, real or calculated, would be offset in the buyer’s account. The post-rationale has been that Kyoto’s global target would have been lower without CDM included. A similar rationale may eventually emerge for the Article 6 mechanisms even if the Nationally Determined Contributions (NDCs) were determined long before Article 6 was predicted. Surely there will be claims that the future updating of NDC will show higher ambition than would have been the case in the absence of Article 6. Such battles are fruitless. But they do relate to the most important part of carbon trading, the part that creates the demand for offsets in the first place, the emissions constraint imposed through the cap in a cap-and-trade system. ix x Foreword In this regard, the message of this book is important, not so much for its embrace of Article 6, but for articulating in which context Article 6 could, and probably should, work. I always claimed that if anyone wanted to see what CDM would look like at a level playing field, look at JI, not that the JI was flawless, but at least that the trading was a zero sum game. Allowances sold were intended to reduce the seller’s emission budget. Only in such a system, and only if the budget restriction is tangible, can the value of trading be determined. The author addresses this point excellently, while Article 6 is silent. Among all the possible learnings from CDM, this is probably the most important: trading must succeed among equal partners, possibly in an Alliance as proposed in this book, among which emission budgets have been determined transparently. Ultimately, it is the emission budget that deter- mines if emissions are reduced, not the trading. If a trading option helps reaching agreement on the budget, it is of course helpful. Only it must be asked: What is the expected benefit that lends such importance to trading? There have been many attempts to document the benefits of CDM. But beyond its indisputable achievement in bringing the emissions reduction agenda to all cor- ners of the world, there is no uniform conclusion. If a Mitigation Alliance is estab- lished among relatively equal partners, then the argument of technology transfer is likely to become mute. Rather the argument is likely to relate to a cost-efficient emissions reduction response. There is, however, only limited merit in the cost- efficiency argument. Throughout the CDM heydays, low-cost industrial gas projects were developed in parallel to high-cost hydro and wind energy projects with no particular price differences among resulting CERs. Although price formation theo- ries may be employed to explain the phenomenon, it is hard to conclude that the markets were in clear pursuit of cost-efficiency. This volume points out that the Paris Agreement was the surprise compromise that brought multilateralism back on track but rightfully questions if that is a good or a bad thing. It is not difficult to draw up a scenario, in which failure would have prompted a de facto ‘Mitigation Alliance’, in face of imminent disaster, to take action. With the Paris Agreement, unfortunately, in spite of the rapid depletion of the global emission budget, there is still no trace of a global burden sharing agree- ment. Although the Paris Agreement with 190+ countries involved is a major diplo- matic accomplishment, the principles upon which such burden sharing should succeed are never to be agreed as long as there are rents to be earned from disagree- ment – and as long as the cost of disagreement is poorly understood and to be paid by the next generation. Therefore, in the scenario developed here, the Mitigation Alliance still plays a central role in bringing about substantial emissions reduction. Although the Alliance is no longer a stand-alone structure and operates under the umbrella of the Paris Agreement, it does not depend on successful completion of UN-led negotiations that are to continuously ramp up ambition in updated NDCs in order to close the gap between current emissions and the 1.5–2-degree boundary. It is to be assumed that the Mitigation Alliance will constantly outperform the average NDC ambition level, which may either serve as inspiration for those outside the Alliance or as relief for those that consider themselves less obligated. Foreword xi Possibly, the Achilles heel of such alliance building is its attraction in practice. As Stua suggests, it depends on a strong governance system to which members subject themselves, including an objective burden sharing. Subjecting oneself to these conditions, the Mitigation Alliance concedes to its members’ usage of Article 6. But in face of collective shortage, even individual shortage, who will feel impelled to trade? If the Alliance is to become net-zero carbon over time, possibly a very short time, who will give up a part of its budget to serve the needs of a less fortunate Alliance member? Musketeer oaths are regrettably out of fashion. Trade propensi- ties in CDM were given as deals were one-sided in terms of hollowing or expanding emissions budgets, as the seller had an endless budget to sell from. Equally, in JI, the common seller had excessive budgets of hot air, the selling of which would not leave the seller constrained in any foreseeable future. But when Alliance members are to trade over the last tons of certified mitigation outcomes and everybody is in dire straits, you may have the money to buy, but nobody is selling. Stua experiments with ways out of this dilemma, including the opportunity to transform the certified mitigation outcome into a representative currency within the Alliance. Attributing a value to environmental, economic, financial, social and polit- ical co-benefits may be a way to overcome trade reluctance. This effectively repack- ages earlier thoughts of using trade policy as a lever to create tangible consequences of unabated emissions. But instead of a punishment for inaction is here a reward for action. The challenge, of course, is if such virtual ‘dollar-shops’1 can be established, if the goods in the shop are in clear demand and if it can be ensured that either the exchange rate to monetary currency significantly favours those in possession of the outcomes or if there is no exchange possible at all. The Bretton Woods idea presented in this volume addresses this challenge excel- lently – but it would be a pity to give it all away in a foreword. Read Chap. 8 for yourself. A commodity-based system – not like the gold standard from current emissions trading – is one key element in which the real value comes from the finite supply of CMO: the difference between current and net-zero emissions. No doubt that is ultimately where we need to go – or at least a very large majority of us – meaning that to be effective a Mitigation Alliance must include all major emitters. That is the foremost challenge to any system. No matter the sugar-coating, many might find that the pill is still a bitter one. For that, Stua’s reward system could well show the way forward. For sure the proposed Bretton Woods model could lend more (and needed) cred- ibility to an international agreement like the Paris Agreement, although those that have grown sceptical over the past 25 years of climate debate and negotiations would probably point to the fact that compared to gold, even if we all agree that the CMO is the basic and finite commodity, it remains intangible. But then read the final chapters. Although punishment specifically is not the approach, it could be consid- ered de facto ‘punishment’ not to be part of the Alliance. 1 Dollar-shops is used for shops, in currency-constrained countries, that trade in imported goods but only accept foreign currency, typically USD, as payment. xii Foreword From that perspective, it is not necessarily a given that the forum for creating the Alliance is a UN body like the UNFCCC. Many had already buried the Convention as a useful platform, when Paris produced its surprise compromise. With Paris in place, however, it is wise to embrace it, as Stua does by adopting the CMO, while not necessarily considering it sufficient. The near future will probably tell. Under all circumstances, even if our climate change negotiators have precious few successes to show for themselves, we must remain positive that it can still be done. UNEP DTU Partnership Søren E. Lütken Technical University of Denmark Marmorvej 51, København, Denmark

Description:
This book investigates the existing and possible links between the concept of a Carbon Club and the Paris Agreement. In doing so the book defines those criteria that may lead to an effective establishment of a Carbon Club acting within the mandate of the Paris Agreement and identifies the key questi
See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.