Europe in Question - and what to do about it Stuart Holland He is not a good citizen who does not wish to promote, by every means in his power, the welfare of the whole society of his fellow-citizens. Adam Smith. The Theory of Moral Sentiments, 1759, Part VI, Section II. In memory of Ken Coates and Egon Matzner – brilliant advocates of a democratic and social Europe – and to Alex and his generation, trusting that the book may help them achieve it Annex A Modest Proposal for Resolving the Eurozone Crisis Yanis Varoufakis, Stuart Holland and James Galbraith Figures 1.1: Jastrow-Wittgenstein and Gestalt 1.2: Deflation by Decree: Weimar and Greece 5.1: Denial, Projective Identification and Forecasting 10.1: Keynes, Fisher and Gestalt 10.2: Friedman, Fisher and Gestalt 10.3: Recovery and a European New Deal 12.1: Asymmetric Global Capital and Labour Flows 13.1: Psychological and Social Contracts 15.1: On the Centrality of Human Value 16.1: The G20 and a World Development Organization Tables 10.1: Multipliers from Public Spending and Investment 12.1: Europe’s Lagging Small and Medium Firms 14.1: Denial of New Deal Employment Creation Acknowledgements Without having known and worked with many of the politicians cited in the book it would have been different - even if Europe itself would have been different if Harold Wilson had followed through the confederal opening when Charles De Gaulle agreed to a 2nd British application to join the EEC. Knowing Jacques Delors since the mid-1970s and being able to work with him on policies and institutions that could realise the cohesion pillar of the 1986 Single European Act was invaluable, as was Andreas Papandreou’s endorsing the call for a New Messina conference which had led to it. As was working with Antonio Guterres when he was prime minister of Portugal and would go into a European Council in a minority of one, but then win, as he did in gaining the case for the terms of reference of the European Investment Bank to be extended to finance investments in health, education, urban renewal and the environment. To be shadow minister for development in the 1980s when Neil Kinnock was Leader of the Opposition was brilliant, and when Neil showed leadership qualities in turning the Labour Party on Europe that Harold Wilson lacked. Not in the sense that Europe since has been a success. Its current failure risks disaster. But that when capital is multinational, politics also should be so while the agenda Neil jointly endorsed with Andreas Papandreou and François Mitterrand still is relevant to this. Giuliano Amato and Romano Prodi, formerly prime ministers of Italy, have been strong advocates of several of the proposals made in the book. As were Ken Coates and Egon Matzner both in the Out of Crisis initiative of the early 1980s and after, when Ken also was a member of the European Parliament. Working with Willy Brandt, Michael Manley and other members of The Socialist International on what became its Global Challenge report was a privilege and led to strong interest in its proposals from parties in Latin America and from the governments of India and China which still are relevant to the feasibility now of global economic governance. In a more conventional sense of acknowledgements I am indebted to Gerald Wooster, a psychoanalyst, who encouraged me to develop the relevance of splitting and projective identification to how the European project has failed to fulfil its initial aspirations, as well as to Henry van Maasakker for briefings on fulfil its initial aspirations, as well as to Henry van Maasakker for briefings on materials I could have missed and for a range of insights that I lacked. I also owe much to colleagues in the Faculty of Economics of the University of Coimbra, where I have been welcomed as a Visiting Professor for some time, including Teresa Carla Oliveira, co-author of several papers cited in the book. As well as to Raphael Kaplinsky who introduced me to the case that it was the failure of flexible labour markets that led to flexible production and continuous improvement in Japan. Also to Yanis Varoufakis and James Galbraith both for their good humour and friendship, and for their joint authorship of The Modest Proposal appended to the book. Which is modest only in reflecting one of its main themes that Europe does not need new institutions, or new treaties, or fiscal transfers, or federalism to resolve the Eurozone crisis and restore what have been usurped rights of national democracies. The final stages of preparing the text were supported by the European Union and the State of Hungary, co-financed by the European Social Fund in the framework of the TÁMOP 4.2.4. A/2-11-1- 2012-0001 ‘National Excellence Programme’. Biographical Note Born in 1940, Stuart Holland studied and taught history and political theory at Oxford, then became an adviser to Harold Wilson on European affairs and in 1967 gained the consent of Charles De Gaulle for a 2nd British application to join the European Community on the basis of a confederal Europe, mutual currency support and a European Technology Community. Resigning from No. 10 when Wilson did not follow this through, he finished an economics doctorate at Oxford and taught at Sussex University. His case that Britain needed selective public ownership of big business and banks, accountability of multinational companies and an industrial policy was adopted in the economic programmes of the British Labour Party for a decade from 1972 but also strenuously resisted by Wilson and other members of the 1974-1979 Labour government. From 1979 to 1989 he was a Labour Member of Parliament and then worked with Jacques Delors on EU policies for economic and social cohesion. His 1993 proposals to Delors for EU bonds to offset the deflationary effects of the Maastricht debt and deficit criteria were supported thereafter by heads of state and government at successive European Councils but not enacted. Eurobonds then hit headlines from the onset of the Eurozone crisis when opposed outright by Angela Merkel and German finance minister Wolfgang Schäuble. Whereas, from September 2014 an initiative for an investment led recovery financed by EIB bonds was on the agenda of European finance ministers and could in principle achieve the 1993 design for them. His earlier advice to Andreas Papandreou, backed by François Mitterrand, prompted the first revision of the Rome Treaty with commitment to the principle of economic and social cohesion in the 1986 Single European Act. His later advice to Portuguese Prime Minister Antonio Guterres resulted in a cohesion and convergence remit for the European Investment Bank to invest in health, education, urban regeneration and the environment. He has published papers and books on economic theory, social and political theory, public enterprise, planning, regional policy, economic integration, international development and global economic governance. He currently is a Visiting Professor in the Faculty of Economics of the University of Coimbra, Portugal, and Senior Research Scholar of the Institute for Social and European Studies at Köszeg, Hungary within a programme jointly funded by the the European Social Fund and the government of Hungary. Introduction This book is in part autobiographical since, for better or worse, I have been an actor since the 1960s in initiatives to try to gain a democratic and social Europe in which markets would serve people rather than people serve markets whereas, since the onset of the Eurozone crisis, the European Union has been sacrificing their wellbeing and welfare on the altar of austerity. It is commonplace to attribute this failure to design faults for the introduction of the euro. But Europe in Question submits that these also were earlier in Jean Monnet’s flawed supranational ambition rather than a more confederal framework that could enable nations to do better together what they could not do well by themselves, and thereby enhance rather than deny national democracy. It draws on political and economic theory and also psychology in the sense that what are assumed to be facts depend on how they are perceived. Such as equating debt with guilt, or seeing public spending as draining rather than sustaining the private sector. Or the failure to recognise that while, as an outcome of salvaging banks, many European member states now are deep in debt, until May 2010, with the first major financial response to the Eurozone crisis, the European Union itself had none Further that EU has an under-recognised late starter advantage that America could welcome now, since its own borrowing still is less than the level from which the Roosevelt New Deal not only recovered employment in the US through shifting savings into investments through bond finance but also gave the private sector confidence in recovery and the public confidence that governments could govern rather than markets rule. A main claim in the book is that a European New Deal can be achieved by recycling global surpluses without these counting on national debt, without fiscal transfers or guarantees by member states, without an increased European budget, without new institutions and without a federal grand design. The case that Europe could countervail the deflationary debt and deficit conditions of the Maastricht Treaty by bond financed investment was integral to a report on economic and social cohesion that I made to Jacques Delors in 1993. As this book goes into production there are indications that such a case for investment-led recovery may finally have gained agreement. Whether it does so effectively remains to be seen. But the book also delves deeper, such as that postwar German concern with price stability neglects that it was not the hyper inflation of the early 1920s that enabled Hitler to seize power, but the deflation and austerity in the early 1930s insisted on by the government of Heinrich Brüning which increased unemployment, lost him support in the Reichstag and drove him to govern by decree, as Troikas recently have for several European countries. It relates this to the error of seeking ‘structural reforms’ and more ‘flexible labour markets’ to compete down on labour costs. Not only since, in Germany, this has reduced internal demand and imports from other EU member states and the rest of the world but also that not all goods or services are subject to international competition. Hospitals, health centres, schools, social services, other civic services and urban transport are local not global. And their economic and social efficiency can be gained by ‘continuous improvement’ to mutual advantage of both their employees and the public through innovation-by- agreement which was recommended in the 2000 Lisbon Agenda as a means of restoring the European Social Model. Also since it is Schumpeterian process and product innovation rather than reducing the cost of labour that can lift economies and societies to higher levels of income and welfare. Much of which, as illustrated later, has been achieved through public sponsorship and synergies, including most of the innovations in the US in recent decades including the world-wide-web itself, Google’s algorithm and entirely new sectors such a nanotechnology. It also submits that innovation should promote both efficient economies and efficient societies and recognise the centrality of human and social rather than only the market values which, since the endorsment of neo-liberal policies from the 1980s have encroached on the social domain with alleged ‘New Public Management’, which in reality has been a regression to Fordist concern with throughput and Taylorist surveillance. Further that while Keynes was right to stress effective demand, there also is latent social demand to be met if societies are to be able to achieve wellbeing and welfare. Such as for more labour intensity in education, health and social services - smaller class sizes, shorter waiting lists, more care for the young and the elderly – which actually was endorsed twenty years ago by the Essen European Council as a commitment to achieving a European Social Model. And which could be achieved in revenue terms if investment costs in education, health and urban renewal were shifted from national to European borrowing. In making this case it echoes the claim of Adam Smith that functional economies depend on functional societies, and that this implies recognising mutual advantage for the welfare of the whole of society rather than the comparative advantage which was a deceit of David Ricardo’s that became dominant in the IMF, the World Bank, GATT and the World Trade Organization. It relates this to models of global governance. Since the G20 of heads of state and government was formed after the financial crisis it has not even formed a permanent secretariat. Failure to allow the emerging economies a more significant share of voting rights in the Bretton Woods institutions has prompted their creation of their own development bank and, potentially, monetary fund. In this context it recalls that the postwar European recovery was not through the IMF and World Bank, but by a new, simpler and non-hegemonic institution - the Organization for European Economic Cooperation. It submits that the G20 should parallel the earlier success of the OEEC by nominating the governing body of a World Development Organization rather than trying protracted reform of the Bretton Woods institutions and that, unlike the 1943 Keynes Plan, do so on a confederal rather than supranational basis. It also analyses the limits of economic theories which have displaced or denied the feasibility of social welfare, some of which have been well critiqued by other economists, but which it seeks to explain in a manner which is accessible to non- economists. In doing so it recovers the case of Wilfred Pareto that there is no basis for projecting past market trends into future outcomes, which was an error of the ’rational expectations’ and ’efficient market’ theories that paved the path to the subprime crisis and the second Wall Street Crash. It also shows that Leon Walras, one of The Economists who, with Pareto, has been taken to be a founder of ’pure theory’ and equilibrium outcomes in mainstream economics, fulminated against this misrepresentation and not only stressed that all land, public utilities and public transport should be publicly owned and run on a non-profit basis but that all banks and other financial
Description: