Estimating the Impact of Airbnb Activity on Housing Prices in New York City Author: Advisor: Andrew Udell Professor Stephen Sheppard A thesis submitted in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of Bachelor of Arts with Honors in Economics WILLIAMS COLLEGE Williamstown, MA May 2016 Contents 1 Introduction 7 1.1 Research Question and its Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 1.2 Contemporary Policy Debates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 1.3 Methodology and Analytical Framework . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 11 2 Literature Review 14 2.1 Literature Overview . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 14 2.2 The Hedonic Model of Housing Markets . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15 2.3 The Application of Hedonic Models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17 2.4 Research on Peer-to-Peer Platforms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 21 2.5 Contributions to Existing Literature . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 23 3 Theoretical Model 25 3.1 The Perfectly Complementary City . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 25 3.2 Partial Equilibrium Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 4 Data and Methodology 33 4.1 Data & Descriptive Statistics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 33 4.2 Empirical Identification Strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 42 5 Results 44 5.1 Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 44 6 Conclusion 50 6.1 Discussion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 6.1.1 Summary of Results . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 6.1.2 Policy Implications . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 50 6.1.3 Further Research . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 51 7 Appendix 52 7.1 Maps . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52 7.2 Meeting with Airbnb . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56 7.3 Stata Code . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62 7.3.1 Generating Time Series Airbnb Data . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 62 7.4 ArcGIS . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 7.4.1 Near Operation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 63 7.4.2 Spatial Join . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 64 7.5 Robustness Tests . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66 7.5.1 Different Spatial Measures of Airbnb Activity . . . . . . . . 66 7.5.2 Linear Estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68 7.6 Year of Sale Hedonic Estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68 2 List of Figures 1.1 Transmission Mechanisms for the Impact of Airbnb Activity on Housing Prices . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 3.1 Monocentric Urban Model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 26 3.2 Perfect Complements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 3.3 Land Rent Function . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 27 3.4 Theoretical Impact of a Rise in Population. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 3.5 Theoretical Impact of a Rise in Income . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 3.6 Theoretical Impact of a Decrease in ↵ . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32 4.1 Construction of Airbnb Dataset . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 36 4.2 Airbnb Listings Over Time . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 37 4.3 Sales & Buffer Zones . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 38 5.1 Housing Price Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 7.1 Airbnb Density: June 2015 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 53 7.2 Average Sale Price: September 2014 - August 2015 . . . . . . . . . . 54 7.3 Bivariate Choropleth: Airbnb Activity and Sales Prices . . . . . . 55 7.4 VisualizationofTable7.8: DifferentSpatialMeasuresofAirbnb Activity . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 66 3 List of Tables 4.1 Data Sources and Use . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34 4.2 Descriptive Statistics: Airbnb Activity Measures . . . . . . . . . . . 40 4.3 Descriptive Statistics: Sales and Controls . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41 5.1 Airbnb’s Positive Impact on New York City Housing Prices . . . . 47 5.2 Alternative Airbnb Activity Proxies . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48 7.1 Number of Listings by Type by Borough (as of 11/17/2015) . . . . 57 7.2 NumberofHostswithActiveEntireHomeListings(asof11/17/15) 58 7.3 Number of Listings by Type by Nights Hosted . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59 7.4 (Cont’d) Number of Listings by Type by Nights Hosted . . . . . . . 60 7.5 Median Listing Revenue by Type of Listing . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 7.6 Median Listing Revenue by Borough . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 7.7 Median Nights Booked per Listing by Borough . . . . . . . . . . . . 61 7.8 Different Spatial Measures of Airbnb Activity . . . . . . . . . . . . 67 7.9 Linear Hedonic Estimates . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68 7.10 Year of Sale Estimates from Table 5.1 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 69 7.11 Year of Sale Estimates from Table 5.2 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 70 7.12 Year of Sale Estimates from Table 7.8 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 71 4 Abstract I evaluate the impact of Airbnb activity on housing prices in New York City. Using a hedonic regression to estimate Airbnb’s impact, I find that Airbnb activity in New York City has positively impacted housing sales prices. This impact is robust to changes in the specification of my model and a 1% increase in the number of Airbnb listings within 300m increasessalespricesbyapproximately0.08%,whichincludescontrolsforthepropertyitself and local neighborhood fixed e↵ects to capture time-invariant neighborhood quality. The impact varies slightly, in the full specifications, from 0.06% to 0.1%, depending on the di↵erent proximate and descriptive measures of Airbnb activity; across all specifications, the impact is positive and both economically and statistically significant. Additionally, I estimatethetheoreticalimpactofAirbnbactivityonhousingpricesinamonocentricurban partial equilibrium model. 5 Acknowledgments I am filled with gratitude for the incredible amount of support I have received over the course of the past year. Professor Stephen Sheppard truly went above and beyond as an advisor, supporting me throughout each step of this process (even as he spent the second halfofthisyearintheNetherlands!). Thisthesisundoubtedlywouldnothavebeenpossible without his generous support. ProfessorSaraLaLumiaandProfessorSarahJacobsonwereconstantsourcesofhelpdur- ing the past year. Their feedback and suggestions were critical to the success of this thesis. Ben Blackshear provided many hours of technical advice for using ArcGIS. A conversation wehadinMarchof2014servedastheinspirationforthisresearch. Thoseseedsweresowed as a result of an internet economics course I took with Dr. Greg Taylor, Fellow at the Oxford Internet Institute. Professor David Love, my advisor in the economics department, encouraged me to write a thesis and helped me iron out a strong proposal. He has served as a mentor, formally and informally, throughout my entire academic career at Williams College. Professor Matthew Gibson devoted many hours to helping me with this project. Je↵rey Fossett, a Williams College alumnus and data scientist at Airbnb, provided incredi- bly useful feedback. We had several conversations as well as a long-standing email thread. My brother, Jacob Udell, provided me with comments and criticism that were immensely helpful. He pushed and goaded me as only an older brother can. Matt Rock and Molly Leonardprovidededitsonmanydrafts. MattMcNaughtonconsistentlyhelpedmetorefine my ideas and stay positive. Ryann Noe, on more than one occasion, helped me debug my Stata code, and served as a sounding board for ideas. I am thankful for Murray Cox open- sourcing his InsideAirbnb dataset, which is the basis for this research. Airbnb generously invited me to access their data and meet with their team. Ryan McCloskey drove to New York City with me for my meeting with Airbnb. Of course, this thesis would not have been possible without the support of Williams College and the Economics Department. Other 2015-2016 thesis writers in the Economics Department provided me with meaningful and thoughtful feedback during presentations and conversations. I am thankful for the advice I received from friends and family, and importantly, for dealing with me as I constantly discussed this research. Thank you to you all. All mistakes are my own. 6 1 Introduction 1.1 Research Question and its Implications This paper estimates the impact of Airbnb activity on housing prices in New York City. Airbnb is an internet-based peer-to-peer marketplace which allows individuals to “list, dis- cover, and book” over 2,000,000 accommodations in over 34,000 cities across the world (Airbnb, 2016). Airbnb acts as an intermediary between consumers and producers to re- duce the risk and cost of o↵ering a home as a short-term rental, which enables suppliers (homeowners) to flexibly participate in the commercial housing market. In New York City, Airbnb activity tends to be heavily concentrated in the boroughs of Manhattan and Brook- lyn. As of November 17th, 2015, there were a total of 35,743 active listings in New York City.1 These listings constitute a sizable portion of the accommodations industry in New YorkCity,asthereisatotalofapproximately102,000hotelroomsintheentirecity(Cuozzo, 2015).2 AirbnbhasasignificantpresenceinNewYorkCityandothercitiesacrosstheworld, so much so that some local city governments are attempting to shut down the company. Cities are concerned with Airbnb’s impact on a↵ordability as well as the way in which it evades housing and tax regulations. Airbnbispartofwhathasbecometobeknownasthe“SharingEconomy,”whichsimply putreferstopeer-to-peerproducts, services, andcompanies. Alargepartofthemotivation behind the Sharing Economy, according to the companies that self-define as part of the sector, is to make use of otherwise under-utilized goods.3 In the case of housing, homes mightnotbeutilizedtotheirfullextent(forexample, duringvacationsorduetoanunused bedroom). This allows homeowners to “share” (e.g., rent) parts or the entirety of their 1ForfurtherinformationonthemarketdynamicsofAirbnbinNewYorkCity,seeSection7.2. 2There are 3,394,486 housing units in New York City measured in 2013 (Been et al., 2015), meaning thatover1%ofhousingunitswerebeingactivelylistedonAirbnbonNovember17th,2015. Giventhatthe distributionofAirbnbisnotnormallydistributedthroughoutthecity,weshouldexpectthatinsomeareas, theratioofAirbnblistingstototalunitsissignificantlyhigher. 3See“TheSharingEconomy: FriendorFoe?”(Avitaletal.,2015)foraconcisesummaryofthedi↵erent viewpointssurroundingthefutureoftheSharingEconomy. 7 homes during these times and earn revenue. The potential for and ease of these types of transactions is greatly increased by better matching technologies, a trend which has been driven by the Internet (Horton and Zeckhauser, 2016). Airbnb further reduces transaction costsforbothconsumersandproducersbyprovidingafeedbackandreputationmechanism, allowing for a safer and more streamlined transaction. DespiteAirbnb’se�ciencyimprovementsandtheabilityitgiveshomeownerstogenerate revenue, there are concerns about the economic and welfare e↵ects of Airbnb’s presence on the residential housing market.4 The following research examines those economic e↵ects. Put simply, the study is motivated by the following question: in a highly constrained and regulated housing market, where residential homes are both in high demand and located in dense neighborhoods, what is the impact of being able to transform residential properties into revenue streams and partly commercial residences? In New York City, this question has been raised explicitly, as the role of Airbnb has been at the center of a number of policy discussions at the municipal level. In 2014, the Attorney General of New York State, Eric Schneiderman, investigated Airbnb’s presence in New York City (Schneiderman, 2014). The New York Attorney General O�ce’s findings indicated that 72% of Airbnb listings in New York City violated property use and safety laws and were therefore illegal.5 The Attorney General’s O�ce also found that over 4,600 units in New York City were booked for more than three months of the year, leaving the Attorney General’s O�ce to question the impact that Airbnb has on the supply of housing stock and New York City’s a↵ordability. As of the Attorney General’s investigation in 2014, Airbnb saw an increase of over 1000% in both listings and bookings from 2010 to 2014. To understand Airbnb’s scale of growth, or at least the way their investors value its business, an oft cited statistic is that in its most recent funding round, Airbnb was valued at approximately $25B. This suggests it is more valuable than Marriott International Inc., 4There are several firms similar to Airbnb. As these types of companies become more prevalent and continuetoexpand,thisareaofresearchbecomesincreasinglyimportant,assuchfirmsmostlyenterhighly constrained and regulated markets, the dynamics of which often have welfare consequences. The analysis here is not directly applicable to, for example, understanding the economic impact of Uber on a city, a ride-sharingservice. However,theresearchpresentedinthispapersuggeststhatthesecompaniescanhave asignificantimpact,oneworthyofstudy. 5This is largely due to New York State’s Multiple Dwelling Law, which imposes strict regulations on safetyandhealthconditionsthatmustbemetaswellaslimitsonbusinessusesofhomes. 8 which has a market capitalization of $17.9B and which owns over 4,000 hotels. In 2014, MarriottInternationalInc. had$13.8Binrevenue,overtentimesAirbnb’sprojected revenue in 2015 (Kokalitcheva, 2015). That investors are still willing to purchase an equity stake in Airbnb at its current valuation suggests an expectation of continued, extraordinary growth. Their expected revenue for 2020 is $10B, implying an annual growth rate of approximately +75% (Kokalitcheva, 2015). Especiallygivenitsrapidgrowth,theAttorneyGeneral’sinvestigationrevealsthatthere are real concerns about the presence of Airbnb in cities across the world. Central to this consideration,accordingtoauthorDougHenwood,isthepotentialofAirbnb’s,“real,ifhard- to-measure, impact on housing availability and a↵ordability in desirable cities,” (Henwood, 2015). Indeed, as this study will expand upon below, almost all of the welfare consequences (both positive and negative) of Airbnb circle around the question of its impact on housing prices. Assuch,thisresearchgrappleswiththequestionofAirbnb’simpactinNewYorkCity by presenting both empirical and theoretical information on Airbnb’s impact on residential housing prices – an issue that is brought up often, but rarely quantified. This paper seeks not to make a judgment on whether or not Airbnb is good or bad for cities, but rather to provide the first estimates on Airbnb’s impact on residential housing prices. 1.2 Contemporary Policy Debates Residentsofcitiesandlocalgovernmentsacrosstheworld,bothinfavorandagainstAirbnb’s presence, are growing increasingly vocal. The arguments against Airbnb focus primarily on three areas:6 1) Airbnb’s impact on decreasing a↵ordability, 2) the negative externalities causedbyAirbnbguests,7and3)theshadowhotelindustrythatallowscommercialoperators 6An article on the impact of Airbnb in Los Angeles articulates these concerns clearly: “Airbnb forces neighborhoodsandcitiestobearthecostsofitsbusinessmodel. Residentsmustadapttoatighterhousing market. Increased tourist tra�c alters neighborhood character while introducing new safety risks. Cities lose out on revenue that could have been invested in improving the basic quality of life for its residents. Jobsarelostandwagesareloweredinthehospitalityindustry”(Samaan,2015,p. 2). 7Hortondescribesthisphenomenonwell: “IfAirbnbhostsbringinginloudordisreputableguestsbut, critically, still collect payment, then it would seem to create a classic case of un-internalized externalities: thehostgetsthemoneyandherneighborsgetthenoise”(Horton,2014,p. 1). 9 to use Airbnb in order to evade important safety regulations and taxes.8 On the other side, those who argue in favor of Airbnb’s presence tend to focus on its positive economic impact on the city, including creating new income streams for residents as well as encouraging tourism and its associated economic benefits for a city (Kaplan and Nadler, 2015). The contemporary policy debates surrounding Airbnb can be summarized by the fol- lowing question: should Airbnb be regulated and, if so, what is the appropriate type and level of regulation? This has been debated in New York City Council Hearings, protests haveformedinsupportofandagainstAirbnb, andthispastNovember(2015), Airbnbeven made it onto the ballot in San Francisco through Proposition F.9 There is strong language on both sides; some are scared of Airbnb’s impact on the a↵ordability of neighborhoods and others suggest that its net welfare e↵ects are positive. Additionally, the policy debates surroundingAirbnbandothersharingeconomycompaniesareconcernedthatthesecompa- nies degrade important regulations. Arun Sundararajan argues that new regulations need to be developed to protect individuals, both consumers and workers, as a result of these companies: “Asthescaleofpeer-to-peerexpands,however,societyneedsnewwaysofkeep- ing consumers safe and of protecting workers as it prepares for an era of population-scale peer-to-peer exchange” (Sundararajan, 2014). In the New York City Council hearings, as well as in protests and debates in the public sphere, there is a consistent lack of data and analysis upon which people can rely. Because of this void, arguments are, to put it bluntly, mostly rhetorical and ideological rather than empirical. Thus, in addition to pursuing the analysis of Airbnb’s impact on housing prices in New York City, the data collection work included in this paper will also hopefully begin to fill that void so that individuals can better understand Airbnb’s impact in a way that is mathematically rigorous and econometrically robust. 8MuchoftheuproarinNewYorkCityconcernsnon-uniformtaxationandregulation;hotelsandmotels facetaxeswhichAirbnbisnotcurrentlysubjectto. InNewYorkCity,itisuptohoststopaytaxesonthe revenuetheygeneratefromAirbnb. Insomeothercities,Airbnbhasa“collectandremit”featuretocollect taxes. 9Proposition F was ultimately rejected but would have limited the number of nights an Airbnb could beavailableeachyear. 10
Description: