ebook img

ERIC ED456024: Linking Science Education to Labour Markets: Issues and Strategies. Secondary Education Series. PDF

26 Pages·2000·0.35 MB·English
by  ERIC
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview ERIC ED456024: Linking Science Education to Labour Markets: Issues and Strategies. Secondary Education Series.

DOCUMENT RESUME SE 064 955 ED 456 024 Lewin, Keith M. AUTHOR Linking Science Education to Labour Markets: Issues and TITLE Strategies. Secondary Education Series. World Bank, Washington, DC. Human Development Network. INSTITUTION 2000-00-00 PUB DATE NOTE 25p. Education Advisory Service, Human Development Network, The AVAILABLE FROM World Bank, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433; e-mail: [email protected]; Web site: http://www.worldbank.org. Reports - Descriptive (141) Opinion Papers (120) PUB TYPE MF01/PC01 Plus Postage. EDRS PRICE Developing Nations; Economic Factors; *Educational Change; DESCRIPTORS Foreign Countries; *Labor Market; *Science Education; Secondary Education Economic Growth IDENTIFIERS ABSTRACT During the last 35 years, due to the globalization of the world economy and developing technologies, a considerable change has occurred in secondary education. This publication explores the extent to which the development of science education should be linked to labor markets in "Science Education, Labor Markets developing countries. Sections include: (1) "Arguments for Links of SET [science education and and Economic Growth"; (2) "Arguments against Links with Labor training] to Labor Markets"; (3) "A Labor Market Metaphor for Science Education"; Markets"; (5) (4) "Strategies for Linking Science Education to Labor Markets"; and (6) "Concluding Remarks." (Contains 16 references.) (YDS) Reproductions supplied by EDRS are the best that can be made from the original document. SECONDARY EDUCATION SERIES LINKING SCIENCE EDUCATION TO LABOUR MARKETS: ISSUES AND STRATEGIES Keith M. Lewin PERMISSION TO REPRODUCE AND DISSEMINATE THIS MATERIAL HAS EN GRANTED BY TO THE EDUCATIONAL RESOURCES INFORMATION CENTER (ERIC) 1 U.S. DEPARTMENT OF EDUCATION Office of Educational Research and Improvement EDUCATIONAL RESOURCES INFORMATION CENTER (ERIC) IV.Thi.,s document has been reprnr111,0,1 -rebeived from the person or organization originating it. 0 Minor changes have been made to improve reproduction quality. Points of view or opinions stated in this document do not necessarily represent official OERI position or policy. EDUCATaIN WORLD BANK 2 BEST COPY AVAILABLE World Bank, Human Development Network Secondary Education Series Linking Science Education to Labour Markets: Issues and Strategies Keith M Lewin The World Bank Washington, DC 3 © 2000 The World Bank 1818 H Street, N.W. Washington, DC 20433 All rights reserved Manufactured in the United States of America First printing 2000 Papers in this series are not formal publications of the World Bank. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author(s) and should not be attributed in any manner to the World Bank, to its.affiliated organizations or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they represent. For free cOpies of this paper, please contact the Education Advisory Service, Human Development Network, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, NW, Washington, DC 20433-0002. E-mail: [email protected], or visit the website at www.worldbank.org. Contents ii Forward iii About the Author Introduction 1 Science Education, Labour Markets and Economic Growth 1 4 Arguments for Links of SET to Labour Markets Arguments against Links with Labour Markets 8 A Labour Market Metaphor for Science Education 1 1 Strategies for Linking Science Education to Labour Markets 1 3 Concluding Remarks 1 4 References 1 5 5 Forward Welcome to the Secondary Education Series of the Human Development Network, Education Group at the World Bank. The World Bank has been assisting developing countries in their efforts to reform their secondary education systems for more than 35 years. During this period, the context and imperatives for education reform have changed considerably due to various factors such as globalization of the world economy and the impact of neW technologies. This new environment requires rethinking the traditional way of providing secondary education and training systems and both industrializing and industrialized countries are grappling how best to prepare their youth to become productive workforce as well as responsible citizens. Thus, this series'will address a wide range of topics within secondary education that reflect the challenges that we are facing now. This paper, "Linking Science Education to Labour Markets: Issues and Strategies" is the third publication in the Secondary Education Series. Along with the second publication in this series, "Mapping Science Education Policies in Developing Countries", this paper was originally prepared for the workshop, the Secondary Science Education for Development (http://wwwl.worldbank.orgieducation/scied/Training/training.htm), which was organized by the Education Group in April 2000. The workshop aimed to explore some of the issues involved in science education reform within a larger context of social and economic development. We hope these two new volumes will provide with opportunities to further explore these issues with our clients. We welcome your comments. World Bank Human Development Network Education Group August 2000 About the Author Professor Keith M Lewin (e-mail: [email protected]) is the Director of the Centre for International Education, University of Sussex in England and holds a Chair in the Institute of Education. He has twenty five years of experience in education reform in Asia and Africa. He also co-authored the book with Francois Cailloid and Gabrielle Gottelman-Duret, Science Education and Development: Planning and Policy Issues at Secondary Level (IIEP/Pergamon, 1997), from which this paper was developed. Introduction The purpose of this paper is to explore the extent to which the development of science education should be linked to labour markets in developing countries. As with many other areas of the curriculum there are tensions between those who argue that the structure of knowledge and ways of knowing should be the basis for the curriculum, and those who emphasise the importance of shaping curricula around students understandings and motivations and the utility of what is learned. This paper is in five sections. First, it presents four general observations .about the roles science and technology have played in the development process. Second, it directly addresses the case for linking science education to labour markets. Third it considers some of the counter propositions which are advanced to oppose closer links. Fourth, a speculative metaphor is develolied to suggest one way in which science education could evolve to resonate more closely with skills and competencies associated with some forms of production. Fifth, specific strategies for links are suggested. Science Education, Labour Markets and Economic Growth Development has at its core transformations in economic activity, living conditions and values that generate social change. For these to be judged to be developmental there has to be some consensus that some conditions of life are preferable to others. Thus, it can be argued that there is some agreement that freedom from disease is beneficial, adequate nutrition and food security are basic human needs that should be met everywhere, and improvements in the material conditions of life are desirable, e.g., access to adequate housing, clothing, communications, energy. Some would add to this an increasing long list of human rights that need to be satisfied, e.g., the right to education, a sustainable livelihood, the rule of law, equitable access to public services, and fair income distribution. The longer the list, the more contentious some of its components may be. The arguments in this paper are based on accepting that material well-being resulting from economic growth is a valued objective, productive employment or self employment is a necessary condition for growth, and investment in education and training is a necessary, but not sufficient, condition to promote development linked to increased productivity. A simple view of development suggests that its basis is some combination of the ability to transform the physical environment, coupled with changes in how groups of people choose to organise themselves. These lie at the core of the development process. Development is therefore both a technological process and a cultural and socio-economic shift to more, rather than less, valued conditions of life. This paper focuses on science education and training' (SET) and its possible role in contributing to development through its links to employment and the application of science-based ideas. Four This paper uses the term "science education and training" (SET) to include technological application of science. Its position is one which sees science education as part of a continuum with what is sometimes separately identified as technology education. Arguably technologised science education and science-based technology education share similar educational objectives and content. observations set the scene for more specific consideration of links between SET and labour markets. First, history contains a myriad examples of how economic development and social change have been associated intimately with changes in technology (see e.g. Diamond 1999). The development of agriculture released populations from lifestyles based on hunting and gathering, which at best were precarious. It enabled cultures to develop that generated surpluses and allowed complex patterns of social organisation to flower. Stable civilisations developed language, writing and mathematics that enabled an accumulation of ideas across generations and promoted ways of systematically improving the capacity to manipulate the physical environment. Large scale irrigation became feasible, metal based tool making became sophisticated, the construction of towns and cities became possible. The simple point is that without the development of technologies much if not all of this development would have been impossible. What distinguished those populations that developed complex civilisation at an early date from those that did not, was a combination of technological accumulation and innovation, acting in concert with other conditions (social stability, geographically favourable locations, purposeful leadership). Early technological innovation occurred before the development of what is now recognised as science. Nevertheless, such innovation did depend on what are now recognised as scientific thinking skills and sowed the seeds for the development of more and more systematic methods of enquiry into the natural world. The long sweep of history intrigues with many unresolved debates about the relationships between technology and development. The motives for technological development may well have been mixed. Some may be explained as enlightened attempts to improve the living conditions of individuals and communities. Others were more obviously related to the imperatives of war and conquest. The point here is that any historical account of development has to recognise the key role played by changing technologies. These technologies are shared and refined through what are essentially education and training processes. Second, a brief reflection on the industrial revolution is relevant. Industrialisation from the rapid development in benefited first those countries that generated transformation of rural, agrarian-based production to economies based on manufactured goods (see e.g. Landes 1999, Landes 1969). The technologies that drove industrialisation may not have been the direct consequence of science as then practised. Many of the first innovators were poorly educated and practically, rather than theoretically, orientated. As the process unfolded it became clear that technological innovation increased in complexity and benefited from an understanding of the underlying science. Later generations of innovation, which resulted in comparative advantages in production, began to acquire the character of designed solutions to well specified problems explored using the intellectual and empirical tools for enquiry associated with science. The more it became possible to design solutions to production problems, the more successful and efficient the development process could be. Thus it became possible to design and build structures with more predictable properties, synthesise materials to substitute for natural products and create new materials, and act to reduce disease based on knowledge of its causes. No longer was it necessary to depend on trial and error. 2 Third, more recently there is at least suggestive evidence that the East Asian countries that developed rapidly in the latter part of the 20th century benefited from a highly educated labour force which had a relatively high level of skill endowment that was formally acquired (World Bank 1993). Basic education was well established and near universal in advance of periods of rapid economic growth. Most, but not all, of these countries invested substantially in secondary schooling, which included SET. Much of the export led growth that they experienced was in high value added products with high knowledge content. Many of these products and the associated production processes had a scientific and technological base. The story of rapid development in these countries is complex and not all of the factors advanced to explain their success relate to investment in science and technology. However it is clear that some do, and that without such investment in SET, growth would have been compromised. Fourth, globalisation is changing ways in which production is organised and the characteristics of labour markets. This has implications for SET. Development is associated with changes in the proportions of the labour force employed in agriculture, manufacturing, and services. Links between SET and the labour market have to be conceived in terms of the proportions of employment in the different sectors, and the nature of the production process. Strikingly the development of new information and communication technologies (ICTs) is transforming production and employment (Dicken 1998). Manufacturing and services increasingly depend on knowledge-based work dependent on ICTs. This has created demands in developing countries for highly skilled professionals who can provide ICT based services competitively and who may market these internationally. It has also facilitated the migration of lower level jobs based on information processing to developing countries. The "digital divide" between countries is becoming and increasing matter of concern. Though the adoption of ICTs is not directly related to SET, the infrastructure on which ICTs depend is. So also, at least in part, is the development of software which depends on the logical thinking and deductive reasoning can be information and associated with SET. Leading countries the in that communication revolution all have quality SET systems. The links between investment in SET and the use of ICTs may be diffuse, rather than specific. It is difficult to suppose that they are unimportant. These preliminary observations lead to the following propOsition. Economic development is widely associated with advances in technology. Technology benefits from investment in SET, though clearly the constructive application of technology depends on many other things. Linking SET to application . and skill, and hence to competencies valued in labour markets, appears to have a wide range of possible benefits. We now turn to consider specific arguments for and against promoting links between SET and the labour market.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.