ebook img

Emerging behavior in electronic bidding PDF

4 Pages·0.1 MB·English
by  I. Yang
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Emerging behavior in electronic bidding

Emerging behaviorinelectronic bidding I. Yang1, H. Jeong2, B. Kahng1, and A.-L. Baraba´si3 1SchoolofPhysicsandCenterforTheoreticalPhysics,SeoulNationalUniversity,Seoul151-747,Korea 2DepartmentofPhysics,KoreaAdvancedInstituteofScienceandTechnology,Taejon,305-701,Korea 3DepartmentofPhysics,UniversityofNotreDame,NotreDame,IN46556,USA 3 (Dated:February2,2008) 0 0 Wecharacterizethestatisticalpropertiesofalargenumberofagentsontwomajoronlineauctionsites. The 2 measurements indicate that the total number of bids placed in a single category and the number of distinct n auctionsfrequentedbyagivenagentfollowpower-lawdistributions,implyingthatafewagentsareresponsible a forasignificantfractionofthetotalbiddingactivityontheonlinemarket. Wefindthattheseagentsexertan J un-proportional influenceonthefinalpriceoftheauctioneditems. Thisdominationofonlineauctionsbyan 7 unusuallyactiveminoritymaybeagenericfeatureofallonlinemercantileprocesses. 2 PACSnumbers:89.75.-k,89.75.Da. ] h c Electroniccommerce(E-commerce)isanytypeofbusiness distinctauctions. e m or commercial transaction that involves information transfer Tobespecific,wecollectedauctiondatafromtwodifferent acrosstheInternet. Overthepastfiveyears,E-commercehas sources.First,wedownloadedallauctionsclosingonasingle - t expandedrapidly,takingtheadvantageoffaster,cheaperand dayoneBay,including264,073auctioneditems,groupedby a t more convenient transactions over traditional ways. A syn- theauctionsite in194subcategories. Thedatasetallowedus .s ergetic combination of the Internet supported instantaneous toidentify384,058distinctagentsviatheiruniqueuserID.To at interactions and traditional auction mechanisms, online auc- verifythevalidityofourfindingsindifferentmarketsandtime m tionsrepresenta rapidlyexpandingsegmentofE-commerce. spans, we collected data overa one yearperiodfromeBay’s - Indeed,withtheadventoftheInternetmostlimitationsoftra- Korean partner, auction.co.kr, involving 215,852 agents that d ditional auctions, such as geographicaland time constraints, bidon287,018itemsin62subcategories. n have virtually disappeared, making a significant fraction of o Inatypicalonlineauctionasellerplacestheitem’sdescrip- the population potential auction participants [1, 2]. For ex- c tion on the auction site and sets the starting and the closing [ ample eBay, the largest consumer-to-consumer auction site, time for the auction. Agents (bidders) submit bids for the boosts over 40 million registered consumers, and has grown 1 item. Each new bid has to exceed the last available bid by in revenueover100,000percentin the past five years. With v apresetincrement. Agentscanbidmanually,placingafixed 3 therapidlyincreasingnumberofagentstheroleofindividuals bid, or on some auction sites (such as eBay but not on their 1 diminishes and self-organizing processes increasingly dom- Koreanpartner)theycantakeadvantageofproxybidding. In 5 inate the market’s behavior [3, 4]. On the other hand, re- proxybiddinganagentindicatestotheauctionhousethemax- 1 cently the self-organizingfeatures of complex systems have 0 imumpricehe/sheiswillingtopayforthegivenitem(proxy attracted the attention of the statistical physics community 3 bid),whichisnotdisclosedtootherbidders.Eachtimeabid- because they contain diverse cooperations among numerous 0 derincreasesthebidprice,theauctionhousemakesautomatic / components of a system, resulting in patterns and behavior t bidsfortheagentwithanactiveproxybid,outbiddingthelast a which are more than the sum of the individualaction of the bid with a fixed increment, until the proxy price is reached. m components. While many systematic studies have been car- In online consumer-to-consumerauctions the agent with the - riedouttounderstandsuchemergingpatternsinvarioussys- d highest bid wins and pays the amount of that bid; all other tems, little attentionhas been paid to electronic auctions. In n participantspaynothing. this Letter, we collect auction data and show that the bid- o Most online auction sites keep a detailed, publicly avail- c dingofhundredsofthousandsof agentsleadstounexpected : emergingbehavior,impactingoneverythingfromthebidding ablerecordof allbidsandidentifythebiddingagentsvia an v uniqueloginname. Itisthistransparencyofthebiddinghis- i patternsoftheparticipatingagentstothefinalpriceoftheauc- X tory that allows us to characterize in quantitative terms the tioneditem. Wefoundthatthetotalnumberofbidsplacedin r asinglecategorybyagivenagentfollowsapower-lawdistri- auction process. Each completed auction can be character- a izedbytwoquantities: thenumberofdistinctagentsbidding bution. The power-lawbehavioris rootedin the finding that on the same item (n ) and the total number of recorded an agent that makes frequentbids up to a certain momentis agent bidsfortheitem(n ),wheren ≥n ,aseachagent morelikelytobidinthenexttimeinterval.Moreover,wefind bids bids agent canplacemultiplebids. InFig.1weshowthedistributionof thatthenumberofdistinctitemsfrequentedbyagivenagent n and n over all auctionsrecordedon eBay, finding alsofollowsapower-lawdistribution. Thepower-lawbehav- agent bids thattheybothfollowP(n) ∼ exp(−n/n ),wheren = 5.6 iorimpliesthatafewpowerfulagentsbidmorefrequentlyand 0 0 for n and n = 2.5 for n . We obtained similar re- on more distinct items than others. We will show that such bids 0 agent sults for the Korean market, with n = 10.8 for n and powerful agents exert strong influence on the final prices in 0 bids n = 7.4 for n . This simple exponentialform is unex- 0 agent 2 0 0 10 10 (a) nnP( )P( ),agentbid 1100−−24 κ P( )bid10−2 −4 10 (a) −6 10 0 20 40 60 80 100 0 1 2 3 nagent,nbid 10 10 κ 10 10 0 bid 10 (b) (c) 100 0 10 nP( )bid 10−2 nP( )bid 10−2 nP( ),agent nP( ),agent 10−2 nP( )auct10−4 −4 10 (b) −4 10 −6 0 20nagen4t,0nbid60 80 0 n2a0gent,n4bi0d 60 10 100 101 102 103 nauct FIG.1: BidandagentdistributiononeBay.(a)Distributionofnum- ber ofagents(n ,(⋄))simultaneously bidding onacertainitem FIG.2: Frequencyofbidsplacedbyindividualagents. (a)Cumula- andnumberofbiadgsen(tn ,(+))receivedforanitem,obtainedbycon- tivedistributionoftotalnumberofbids,κbid,placedbyagivenagent bids inauctionsinthesamecategory. Foreachofthe194categorieswe sideringallitemscontainedinthe194categoriesonindividualbids separatelydeterminedthecumulativedistributionsandaveragedthe thatwerecollectedfromauctionsendingonJuly5,2001oneBay.(b) obtained curves. (b) Cumulative distributionof thenumber of dis- and(c)Agentandbiddistributioninthelargest(b)andthesecond tinct auctions, n , frequented by agiven agent. Thedotted line largest(c)categoryoneBay. Thelargestcategorybythenumberof auct on (a) has slope -2 while on (b) has slope -2.5, indicating that the auctioneditemscontains21,461itemsrelatedtosporttradingcards correspondingprobabilitydistributionfollowsP(κ ) ∼ κ−3 and wprhinilteedthaendserceocnodrdleadrgmesutscica.teTgohreystirnacilguhdtelsin1e3s,6c1o0rreitsepmonsdretloateexdpoto- P(nauct)∼n−au3c.t5,respectively. bid bid nentialfitsandthesymbolsarethesameasin(a). ofκ followsapowerlaw bid pected,asoneexpectsthatthebiddingdistributionistheresult P(κ )∼κ−γ, (1) bid bid of many independent events, and therefore follows a Gaus- sian,peakedaroundtheaveragenumberofbidsanddecreas- whereγ =3(Fig.2a)onbotheBayandtheKoreanauction.A ing as ∼ exp(−an2) with a constant a. The deviation from similarpowerlawcharacterizesthedistributionofthenumber aGaussiandistributioncouldcomefromthefactthatFig.1a of differentauctions, nauct, frequentedby individualagents, collapses data from different categories, displaying different findingthat biddingpatterns. InFig.1bandcweshowthedistributionin P(n )∼n−β , (2) twosubcategories(sportstradingcardsandprinted,recorded auct auct music), findingthat they follow the same functionalform as whereβ = 3.5(Fig.2b). Thepower-lawdistributionshown the aggregateddata. Therefore,the exponentialformfor the in Fig. 2a implies that while most agents place only a small activitydistributionappearstobeageneralfeatureofallauc- numberofbids,afewagentsbidveryfrequently,placingsev- tions,indicatingthatthemajorityofauctionshaveonlyafew eralhundredbidsonthesameday.Similarly,Fig.2bindicates biddersandauctionswithalargenumberofbidsorparticipat- thatwhilemostagentsparticipateinafewauctionsonly,afew ingagentsareexponentiallyrare. agents bid very widely, some placing simultaneous bids on To characterize the activity of individual agents we deter- overahundreddistinctitemsonthesameday.Therefore,un- minedthenumberofbidsplacedbyeachagentoneachauc- knowntomostparticipants,theauctionprocessisdominated tion. Asagentsplacesimultaneousbidsonitemsthatclosely by a small number of highly active agents, or power-agents, resemble each other, we denote by κ the total number of thatpursuea veryaggressivebiddingpattern, placingsimul- bid bidsplacedbythesameagentinauctionsinthesamecategory. taneously a large number of bids on a wide range of items. Forexample,ifseveralsimilarcomputersaresoldonseparate Thesepower-agentsareresponsibleforthepower-lawtailof auctions, agentslookingfora computeroftenbid simultane- the distributionshownin Fig. 2. Our measurementsindicate ouslyforseveralorallofthem. We findthatthedistribution thatthereis a strongcorrelationbetweenthe numberof bids 3 1 0.6 0.9 nt e ag 0.8 0.4 n a f 0.7 o e 0.2 at 0.6 r s (a) es 0.5 c 0 c 1 3 rank 5 7 Su 0.4 0.8 n a g e n t =2 0.6 n a g e n t =3 0.3 0.6 0 10 20 30 40 0.4 Number of auctions 0.4 0.2 (b) 0.2 (c) FIG.4: Thedependenceofanagentssuccessrateonthenumberof 0 0 1 rank 2 1 ra2nk 3 auctionstheagentparticipates. Foreachproductsubcategory(con- n =4 n =5 taininghighlysimilaritems)wecalculatedPiwin,theaverageofthe 0.4 agent 0.4 agent winning prices for items won by agent i. For the same agent we alsocalculatedPilost,theaverageoverthewinningpriceoveritems 0.2 0.2 inwhichagentiparticipatedbutlost. Asuccessfulagentcangeta (d) (e) lowerpricefortheitemsitwonthanotheragentsbiddingonsimilar 01 2 3 4 01 2 3 4 5 itemsonparallelauctions,i.e. forasuccessfulagentPiwin<Pilost. rank rank Wefindthatthesuccessrateofanagent,measuredasthefunctionof auctionswonatalowerthanaverageprice(i.e.thefractionofagents FIG. 3: Frequent bidders more likely to win an auction. (a) The forwhichPiwin<Pilost)increaseswiththenumberofauctionsthese probabilitythatanauctioniswonbyagentswithgivenactivityrank. agentsparticipatein.Ahorizontaldottedlinecorrespondstothecase Using all completed auctions we calculated how many times the whenthereisnocorrelationbetween thefrequency of bidding and most, thesecond, or then-thfrequent bidder winstheauction. (b) the chances of getting a better price. A numerical fittingindicates The probability that the most frequent bidder wins the auction of thatthesuccessrateincreaseslogarithmically(dashedline). twoparticipants. (c)-(e): theprobabilitythatanagentwinsanauc- tion of n [(c) n=3; (d) n=4; (e) n=5] participants. (a) is based on 143,325auctions,while(b)-(e)arebasedon47,610,30,205,20,017, cate that frequentlybidding agentsplay a key role in setting and13,762auctions,respectively. thefinalpriceofmostauctioneditems:inthevastmajorityof thecasestheagentswhoplacethelargestnumberofbidsare thewinnersoftheauctionprocess. Thisfindingindicatesthat placed by an agent on an item and the number of items the despitethewidespreadpracticeofsnipingamongexperienced same agent bids for, indicating that power agents simultane- users[5]whenbiddersplacebidsonlyinthelast60seconds ouslybidfrequentlyandwidely. of the auction hoping to win the auctioned item, on average Agentswithanaggressivebiddingpatternsignificantlyal- frequentbiddersaremoresuccessful. terthenatureofthebiddingprocess,potentiallydistortingthe Asthepowerlawdistribution(Fig.2b)indicatesthatsome chanceofatypicalagenttowinanauction.Toinspecttheef- agentsbidratherwidely,thequestionis,doessuchwidebid- fectofthebiddingpatternonthesuccessrateofagivenagent, ding result in economic advantage for power bidders? Our we determinedthe fractionof auctionswonby the most, the results indicate that power agents not only are the frequent second, or the k-th most frequentlybidding agents. We find winners of the auctions in which they participate, but they thatin61%ofallauctionsthewinneristheagentthatmakes also pay less than other agents on similar items. Indeed, in themostbids,andin29%ofallauctionsthesecondmostfre- Fig.4weshowthefractionoftimesthemostfrequentlybid- quently bidding agent wins the auction (Fig. 3a). Less than ding agent pays less for an item than other agents that win 0.3%oftheauctionsarewonbyagentswhoseactivityranks auctionofitemsinthesamecategory. We findthatthemore fifthorhigher.Asmostauctionshaveonlyafewparticipating auctionsan agentparticipates, the largeris its chance to pay agents(Fig.1a),itisusefultore-examinethewinningpatterns lessforthesameitemthanthelesswidelybiddingagents. in auctions with the same number of agents. We find that if The observed power law distribution is rooted in the dy- onlytwoagentsparticipateinanauction,andeachplacemul- namics of the bidding process. Indeed, two processes con- tiplebids,in85%ofthecasestheagentwithmorebidswins tributetothefinalnumberofbidsplacedonagivenitem:new theauction(Fig.3b). Thesituationissimilarforthreeagents agents entering the bidding process and agents that already as well (Fig. 3c): in 64% of the cases the more active agent placed a bid increase their bid. We find that this pattern is wins,followedbythesecondmostactive,whichwinsin32% governedbyaprocessoftenreferredtoaspreferentialattach- of the cases. In auctions with larger number of participants ment,similar tothoseresponsiblefortheemergenceofscal- (Fig. 3d-e) we observe a similar pattern. These results indi- ingincomplexnetworks[6]: morebidsanagentplacesona 4 10 In conclusion, we have collected online auction data and analyzed the statistical properties of emerging patterns createdbya largenumberofagents. We foundthatthetotal number of bids placed in a single category and the number 1 of distinct auctions frequented by a given agent follow k power-law distributions. Such power-law behaviors imply ∆ that the online auction system is driven by self-organized 0.1 processes,involvingallagentsparticipatedinagivenauction activity. We also uncoveredthe empiricalfact that the more bids an agent places up to a givenmoment, more likely it is thatitwill place anotherbid in the nexttime interval, which 0.01 playsanimportantroleingeneratingthepower-lawbehavior 0.1 1 10 inthebiddingfrequencydistributionbyagivenagent. k FIG.5: Theoriginoftheobservedpowerlawisinpreferentialat- tachment.Thefigureshowsthechangeinthenumberofbidsplaced byanagentithatpreviouslyplacedk bids,averagedoverallitems This work is supported by the KOSEF Grant No. R14- andalltimes. Thelinearbehaviorinthelog-logplotindicatesthat 2002-059-01000-0intheABRLprogram. themorebidsanagentplacesuptoagivenmoment,themorelikely itisthatitwillplaceanotherbidinthenexttimeinterval.Suchpref- erentialbiddingisknowntoleadtoapowerlawbiddingdistribution [7,9].Thedottedlinewithslope1isshownforvisualreference. [1] E.vanHeckandP.Vervest,CommunicationoftheACM41,99 (1998). givenitemuptoacertainmoment,morelikelyisthathe/she [2] R.D’HulstandG.J.Rodgers,PhysicaA294,447(2001). willplaceananotherbidinthefuture(Fig.5).Thelinearityof [3] R.N. Mantegna and H.E. Stanley, An introduction to econo- theobservedrelationshipisknowntoleadtopowerlawdistri- physics: Correlations and complexity in finance. (Cambridge butions,asdemonstratedbystudiesinbotheconomics[7, 8] UniversityPress,Cambridge,2000). andcomplexnetworks[9,10,11]. [4] J.P.BouchardandM.Potters,Theoryoffinancialrisks: From statisticalphysicstoriskmanagement. (CambridgeUniversity While power laws have been often observed in economic Press,Cambrdige,2000). contexts, ranging from city [8] and company size distribu- [5] A.E.Rothand A.Ockenfels, AmericanEconomicReview (in tion [12, 13] to Pareto’s observation of wide income distri- press). butions[14]andtimeseriesanalysis[5],theyareratherunex- [6] A.-L.BarabasiandR.Albert,Science286,509(1999). pected during the frequency of bidding of individual users. [7] H.A.Simon,Biometrika42,425(1955). In order to develop an analytical framework to capture the [8] M.MarsiliandY.-C.Zhang,Phys.Rev.Lett.80,2741(1998). dynamics of the bidding process current auction models in- [9] R.AlbertandA.-L.Barabasi,Rev.Mod.Phys.74,47(2002). [10] R.Pastor-Satorras,A.VazquezandA.Vespignani, Phys.Rev. evitablymakeuseofequilibriumconcept[15,16]. Oftenthis Lett.87,258701(2001). requirestheassumptionthatthenumberofagentsisfixed[15] [11] M.Newman,Phys.Rev.E64,025102(2001). which,whileleadstoanalyticallytractablemodels,isnotre- [12] M.H.R.Stanley, L.A.N.Amaral, S.V.Buldyrev, S.Havlin, H. alistic in the contextof Internetauctions. Indeed, the power Leschhorn, P.Maass, M.A.SalingerandH.E.Stanley, Nature lawsobservedherearetheresultoftheauction’sfundamental 379,804-806(1996). openness and non-equilibriumnature. In the past few years [13] R.L.Axtell,Science293,1818-1820(2001). theobservationofsuchnon-equilibriumfeaturesineconomic [14] V. Pareto, Cours d’economie politique (Rouge, Lausanne et Paris,1897). phenomenahasledtoanincreasedinterestamongphysicists [15] K.Leyton-Brown, Y.ShohamandM.Tennelhotz,Gamesand and mathematiciansin the self-organizingprocesses govern- EconomicBehavior(inpress). ing economic systems [3, 4, 12, 17, 18]. Our finding, that [16] R.J.KauffmanandC.A.Wood,Proc.ofICIS(2000). similarnon-equilibriumprocessesgovernthebehaviorofon- [17] D.ChalletandY.-C.Zhang,PhysicaA246,407(1997). lineauctionsplacesthesemercantileprocessesintherealmof [18] D.M.Pennock,S.Lawrence,C.L.GilesandF.A.Nielsen,Sci- agentdrivenself-organization. ence291,987-988(2001).

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.