ebook img

Economic Policy Reform in Mexico. A Case Study for Developing Countries PDF

229 Pages·1981·2.678 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Economic Policy Reform in Mexico. A Case Study for Developing Countries

Pergamon Titles of Related Interest Avery RURAL CHANGE AND PUBLIC POLICY: Eastern Europe, Latin America, and Australia Coombs MEETING THE BASIC NEEDS OF THE RURAL POOR Ewell/Poleman UXPANAPA: Agricultural Development in the Mexican Tropics Franko/Seiber DEVELOPING COUNTRY DEBT Lozoya/Estevez LATIN AMERICA AND THE NEW INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ORDER Meagher AN INTERNATIONAL REDISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH AND POWER Stepanek BANGLADESH — EQUITABLE GROWTH? Related Journals* HABITAT INTERNATIONAL INTERNATIONAL JOURNAL OF INTERCULTURAL RELATIONS LONG RANGE PLANNING REGIONAL STUDIES TECHNOLOGY IN SOCIETY URBAN SYSTEMS WORLD DEVELOPMENT LEARNING AND SOCIETY PROGRESS IN PLANNING *Free specimen copies available upon request. s PERGAMON ON INTERNATIONAL POLICY DEVELOPMENT STUDIES Economic Policy Reform in Mexico A Case Study for Developing Countries Leopoldo Soifs Pergamon Press NEW YORK · OXFORD · TORONTO · SYDNEY · PARIS · FRANKFURT Pergamon Press Offices: U.S.A. Pergamon Press Inc.. Maxwell House. Fairview Park, Elmsford. New York 10523. U.S.A. U.K. Pergamon Press Ltd.. Headington Hill Hall. Oxford 0X3 OBW. England CANADA Pergamon Press Canada Ltd.. Suite 104. 150 Consumers Road. Willowoale. Ontario M2J 1 P9. Canada AUSTRALIA Pergamon Press (Aust.) Pty. Ltd.. P.O. Box 544. Potts Point. NSW 2011. Australia FRANCE Pergamon Press SARL. 24 rue des Ecoles. 75240 Paris. Cedex 05. France FEDERAL REPUBLIC Pergamon Press GmbH. Hammerweg 6. Postfach 1305. OF GERMANY 6242 Kronberg/Taunus. Federal Republic of Germany Copyright © 1981 Pergamon Press Inc. Library of Congress Cataloging in Publication Data Solîs M Leopoldo. Economic policy reform in Mexico. (Pergamon policy studies on international develop- ment) Includes index. 1. Mexico—Economic policy—1970- I. Title. II. Series. HC135.S6383 1981 338.972 80-26937 ISBN 0-08-026330-5 All Rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system or transmitted in any form or by any means: electronic, electrostatic, magnetic tape, mechanical, photocopying, recording or otherwise, without permission in writing from the publishers. Printed in the United States of America Preface This is an essay in political economy that tries to assess the recent economic developments in Mexico, especially the attempt at economic reform in the early 1970s. At the beginning of the present decade, Mexican politicians and economic policymakers realized that the traditional goals of per-capita income growth and price and balance-of-payments stability were no longer sufficient. Therefore, a new objective was added, namely, improvement in income distribution and, perhaps of more in- terest, stepping up the economic activity of the State. Thus, an effort was made to begin to translate the concept of equal- ity into economic reality. I was fortunate enough to witness this process - sometimes quite closely - as head of the Economic Programming Directorate of the Secretariat of the Presidency during 1971-75. When Luis Echeverria became President of Mexico in 1970, the country was ripe for change. Ever since Cardenas' presi- dency in the 1930s, Mexico had enjoyed a good deal of political stability and economic growth. Cardenas' policies, especially his social and economic reforms, becomes the centerpiece of the Mexican revolution and, at the end of his administration, the main institutional features of modern Mexico took shape. The early 1940s marked the beginning of the phase of "national unity" and an end to the ideological and class struggles of previous years. The 1960s saw the end of that stage of Mexican history. For the first time during this decade, Mexico achieved continuous price stability; and this stability, plus sustained economic growth, became known as Stabilizing Devel- opment. The concept was in many ways an a posteriori ration- alization of the chain of economic events that followed the 1954 devaluation and the subsequent short-lived inflationary spurt. Politically, the Stabilizing Development period meant a coalition - sometimes called the "developmental alliance" - of ix x PREFACE the beneficiaries of economic progress, namely, organized labor, government bureaucracy, and private entrepreneurs. At the end of the 1960s, the economic policies of Stabil- izing Development became subjected to mounting criticism. The main issue was income distribution. It became clear that the families in the lower half of the income scale were relatively worse off, regardless of the evidence of production indicators. The general political dissatisfaction of the middle class (despite or perhaps because of the fact that it received many benefits through the Stabilizing Development period) was dramatically expressed in the 1968 student riots. The police repression of the movement turned the Diaz Ordaz administration into a lame-duck government, incapable of taking initiatives in matters of national importance. Observers of Mexican affairs commented that the political development of the nation lagged behind its economic growth, that political institutions had become stale and social mobility frozen. At this moment, incumbent President Luis Echeverria issued a call to the country in his Inauguration speech of December 1970, asking all Mexicans to support him in his efforts to provide Mexico with a more equitable and just society. The first chapter of this book examines the period of Stabilizing Development in order to provide the reader with a framework necessary for judging the environment in which the attempts at economic reform were undertaken. The chapter is a piece of applied economics that tries to assess the now too frequent attacks against that phase of economic policy. The following three chapters discuss the economic policy objectives of Echeverria1 s administration, the attempt at tax reform and the change in the structure and practices of public spending. The final chapter evaluates the experience and draws some inferences about the nature of decision making in economic policy and the constraints faced by a government that wants to use economic policy as an instrument for the promotion of social welfare. The style varies in the different sections of the book. The first chapter shows the detachment from the subject matter expected of an economist. The following three chapters de- scribe events in which I took part and are therefore written from a far more personal point of view. The concluding chapter contains afterthoughts arrived at within the intellectual environment of Princeton University, which is so conducive to serene and reflective thinking. I have included intact some staff papers prepared in the rush of the moment. Those papers were written quickly, usually in a few hours1 time, and therefore contain some faulty anal- yses, and their style is rough. I decided to manicure them in order to give the reader a fresh and honest view of the pres- sures, satisfactions, and frustrations of an economic advisor. PREFACE xi I wish to express my thanks to Sir W. Arthur Lewis, John P. Lewis, Albert Hirschman, Arnold Harberger, Larry Sjaastad, and Carlos Bazdresch for their valuable suggestions and com- ments. I also want to thank Jerry Kavanagh, who patiently typed several drafts of the book; Doris Garvey, who carefully converted Spanish-English and Czech-English into American- English; and Jirina Rybaczek from Czechoslovakia, who trans- lated all included documents and whose editorial help made it possible for me to finish the book much earlier than I ex- pected. The standard disclaimers apply. 1 Stabilizing Development ECONOMIC GROWTH AND PRICE STABILITY Mexico has had a long history of political and economic in- stability. Although political stability was assured with the merging of the revolutionary groups and forces into one po- litical party in 1929 (PNR, later PRM and now PRI), economic order in the form of price and balance-of-payments stability came into being much later, nearly three decades afterwards. The peso devaluation of 1954 that fixed the exchange rate at the old rate of 12.50 pesos to a dollar, was a traumatic event indeed. Policymakers of that time comment to this day that the labor unions1 response, triggered by the devaluation, shook up the whole party structure.(1) A wage increase was granted to appease the workers because it became evident that the economic growth with price instability was unacceptable to them. The share of wages and salaries in national income had actually decreased during the 1940s,(2) and policies had to be devised to prevent labor from bearing the whole burden of growth, i.e., to prevent labor's income share from going down further. The prevailing explanation of the time was that prices lead, wages lag, real wages go down. Inflation had to be stopped. This was in fact achieved in 1956-57 and, since 1958, economic variables have shown quite a different pattern of behavior. The 1958 recession of the U. S. economy, however, depressed the early years of the price stability period, and some analysts argued that the stabilization policies of the time were driving the country to stagnation.(3) Private investment slowed down and a sharp and critical exchange of comments between the public and private sectors took place, showing that a recession eroded the amity between entrepreneurs and the government. The ascent of Castro in Cuba also affected the private sector's 1 2 ECONOMIC POLICY REFORM IN MEXICO prevailing mood. In that context, the 1960s started and, with them, Stabilizing Development. We are fortunate enough to have a yardstick for judging the economic policies that followed in the 1960s. At the 1969 Annual Meeting of the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund, Antonio Ortiz Mena, Secretary of Treasury from 1958 to 1970, presented a comparative analysis of the 1950-58 period, which he called the inflation-devalua- tion cycle, and the 1959-67 period, which he called Stabilizing Development.(4) The document contains a useful conceptual framework that merits a detailed description. Ortiz Mena states that during the inflation-devaluation phase, in a cyclical upswing of investment, spending outpaced voluntary savings, increases in the price level closed the savings-investment gap, and subsequent changes in factor shares led to the worsening of income distribution. Stabilizing Development was intended to raise voluntary savings, improve the allocation of savings, and increase the stock of capital per worker. Tax policies were geared to foster the reinvest- ment of profits, and subsidies were selectively extended to favor the most productive projects. Profit reinvestment promotion, we are told, meant convincing investors that future capital gains - not taxed currently - were more attractive than current dividends that would be taxed.(5) Tax practices were adjusted in such a way as to support the processes of capital deepening; capital was also to be spread out in the productive absorption of the growing labor force. Debt policies were designed to tap both domestic and foreign savings. Foreign and domestic debts were quite low at the beginning of the 1960s. The central bank's reserve re- quirement mechanism was used to channel domestic savings into financing government deficits and complementing foreign funds in order to achieve levels of borrowing that would be, on the one hand, non-inflationary and, on the other, sufficient to promote development. To that end, government spending was budgeted at levels that would avoid excessive issues of high- powered money. In order to increase domestic voluntary savings, in the form of additional flows of financial inter- mediation channeled by financial institutions, and to induce a stream of capital inflow, real interest rates were set at levels sufficiently above those prevailing in the U. S. market. Interest was kept tax-free or taxed at very low, flat rates, and an array of fixed-income securities was permanently pegged at nominal prices. Such financial issues were in fact free of risk and, as time passed with the exchange rate unaltered, foreign exchange risk as perceived by investors and reflected in international rate differences gradually diminished. In the external sector, Stabilizing Development had, according to Ortiz Mena, two aims: to keep the foreign ex- change rate of the peso fixed and to borrow abroad to com- pensate for insufficient foreign exchange coming from exports STABILIZING DEVELOPMENT 3 and for insufficient public investment coming from tax col- lections. The analysis of Stabilizing Development showed that the GDP in real terms grew 6.5 percent annually in 1959-67 - having been 5.6 in 1951-58 - which was at a faster rate than during any previous period in Mexican history. The price deflator of the GDP rose only 3.6 percent a year while, in the 1950s, it had been 7.5 percent. Inflationary expectations gradually diminished. The ratio of price changes to real GDP changes fell from 1.34 in 1951-58 to 0.55 in 1959-67. The other objectives of Stabilizing Development (besides more rapid growth and a slowing down of the rate of price change) were achieved to a certain extent: a rise in the savings ratio, increases in factor productivity, an improvement of real wages and an expansion of the wage-share in national income, and a stable foreign exchange rate. The record shown in Tables 1.1 and 1.2, however, merits some additional comments. In order to raise the savings/income ratio, policies focused on domestic price stability and on improving the competitive position of Mexican financial institutions vis-a-vis the U. S. financial market by introducing high nominal interest rates on Mexican financial paper. A higher proportion of domestic savings was diverted to banks, and especially to other financial insti- tutions - mainly financieras (investment banks) - and these resources were complemented by a much more active use of foreign funds, mainly in the form of long-term loans to of- ficial institutions, which also passed through Mexican fi- nancial intermediaries. Total savings, which averaged 0.13 percent of the GDP in 1951-58, increased to 0.21 percent in 1959-67. Foreign loans and domestic credit accommodated the government's financial needs without forcing inflationary monetary expansion. Public spending was kept at levels that required no inflationary financing and made it possible to keep the exchange rate unchanged. International capital flows became increasingly free of foreign exchange risk. The use of foreign savings made up for the insufficient inflow of commod- ity export earnings and for low revenues from tax collections. Consequently, the public sector was forced to supply energy and other essential public services at low prices and was able to do so without severe supply restrictions. As a complement to a higher savings ratio, the government intended to raise the private productivity of capital. In this context, the official attitude favored external economies, the channeling of investment into activities of high productivity (thereby increasing product per unit of labor input) and a fuller use of plant capacity. Public spending, especially in the capital account, was directed toward increasing the profitability of private in- vestment. In general, however, private expenditures were favored by a system of tax benefits, exemptions, and subsidies, 4 ECONOMIC POLICY REFORM IN MEXICO which were used to promote the reinvestment of profits by the private sector but which made fiscal policy ineffective in increasing tax revenues. This chapter will examine the economic record of the 1960s, with separate sections devoted to the following issues: import substitution and growth of manufacturing, stagnation in agriculture, boom in financial intermediation, tax reform attempts, and distribution inequality. The final section will deal with the evolution of economic policy and will offer some conclusions on domestic and foreign equilibrium. Before turning to the economic analysis of the 1960s, however, we may ask what was the political meaning of the period of Stabilizing Development. We may suggest that the objectives of stability and growth were supported both by the entrepreneurial class and by organized labor, who mainly appropriated the benefits of growth. The middle class, al- though belonging to the beneficiaries,(6) lacked as well as anybody else channels for overt political participation. More importantly, however, the position of the lower classes worsened relatively. Budget constraints on public sector spending meant that the sectors and social groups unable to apply political pressure, especially those outside the modern or commercial segments of the economy, were by-passed by public spending; and their efforts to be subsidized or otherwise supported, and thereby to improve their income and wealth position, were thwarted. This was to have important political and economic repercussions in the latter part of the 1960s, which will be discussed in the final assessment of the overall characteristics of the decade. IMPORT SUBSTITUTION AND THE GROWTH OF MANUFACTURING During the 1960s, economic growth was fairly steady, averaging 7 percent annually, varying from a low of 4.7 percent in 1962 to a high of 11.7 percent in 1964, the last year of the Lopez Mateos administration.(7) Income per capita exceeded a level of U.S. $700 in 1970. The structure of the spending components of the GDP showed some changes: there was a relative decrease of private consumption and exports; government consumption increased; and gross fixed investment gained nearly three percentage points, reaching 19.0 percent of the GDP in 1970 - a figure well above the 12.8 percent achieved 20 years earlier. The structure of output changed somewhat, with agriculture and cattle raising declining from 15.9 to 11.6 percent of the GDP, and industry increasing to 34.4 percent of the total (see Table 1.3). In manufacturing, the production of consumer goods con- tinued losing importance in the aggregate, but at a slower rate

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.