ebook img

Documentary Sources in Ancient Near Eastern and Greco-Roman Economic History: Methodology and Practice PDF

344 Pages·2014·5.661 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Documentary Sources in Ancient Near Eastern and Greco-Roman Economic History: Methodology and Practice

DOCUMENTARY SOURCES IN ANCIENT NEAR EASTERN AND GRECO-ROMAN ECONOMIC HISTORY M P ethodology and ractice edited by Heather D. Baker and Michael Jursa Oxbow Books Oxford & Philadelphia Published in the United Kingdom in 2014 by OXBOW BOOKS 10 Hythe Bridge Street, Oxford OX1 2EW and in the United States by OXBOW BOOKS 908 Darby Road, Havertown, PA 19083 © Oxbow Books and the individual contributors 2014 Hardback Edition: ISBN 978-1-78297-651-6 Digital Edition: ISBN 978-1-78297-759-9; Mobi: ISBN 978-1-78297-760-5; PDF: 978-1-78297-761-2 A CIP record for this book is available from the British Library Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Documentary sources in ancient Near Eastern and Greco-Roman economic history : methodology and practice / edited by Heather D. Baker and Michael Jursa. 1 online resource. Includes bibliographical references and index. Description based on print version record and CIP data provided by publisher; resource not viewed. ISBN 978-1-78297-759-9 (epub) -- ISBN 978-1-78297-760-5 (mobi (kindle)) -- ISBN 978-1-78297-761-2 ( pdf) -- ISBN 978-1-78297-758-2 1. Economic history--To 500. 2. Babylonia--Economic conditions. 3. Rome--Economic conditions--30 B.C.-476 A.D. 4. Rome--Economic conditions--510-30 B.C. 5. Egypt-- Economic conditions--332 B.C.-640 A.D. I. Baker, Heather D. II. Jursa, Michael. HC31 330.935’5--dc23 2014027386 All rights reserved. No part of this book may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical including photocopying, recording or by any information storage and retrieval system, without permission from the publisher in writing. Printed in the United Kingdom by Short Run Press, Exeter For a complete list of Oxbow titles, please contact: UNITED KINGDOM UNITED STATES OF AMERICA Oxbow Books Oxbow Books Telephone (01865) 241249, Fax (01865) 794449 Telephone (800) 791-9354, Fax (610) 853-9146 Email: [email protected] Email: [email protected] www.oxbowbooks.com www.casemateacademic.com/oxbow Oxbow Books is part of the Casemate Group Cover details: P.Vindob. G 2119 Recto (Papyrus, Hermupolis, 6th/7th century AD): SPP III2 97. Receipt for the payment of rents as share of an inheritance. SPP III2 97. © Österreichische Nationalbibliothek, Papyrussammlung. BM 77394 (Cuneiform tablet, Babylon, 494 BC): H.D. Baker, The Archive of the Nappāḫu Family. Vienna, 2004, p. 401, no. 66a. Promissory note for silver with temple prebend as security. © H.D. Baker and the Institut für Orientalistik, Universität Wien. Table of Contents Preface v Contributors vi 1. Introduction 1 M. Jursa 2. House Size and Household Structure: Quantitative Data in the Study of Babylonian Urban Living Conditions 7 H. D. Baker 3. The Historian and the Old Babylonian Archives 24 D. Charpin 4. The Old Assyrian Trade and its Participants 59 J. G. Dercksen 5. Economic Development in Babylonia from the Late 7th to the Late 4th Century BC: Economic Growth and Economic Crises in Imperial Contexts 113 M. Jursa 6. Legal Institutions and Agrarian Change in the Roman Empire 139 D. Kehoe 7. The Papyrological Evidence for Water-Lifting Technology 154 M. Malouta 8. Plagues and Prices: Locusts 163 R. Pirngruber 9. On Payment Transactions and Monetisation in the Rural Region of Late Antique Egypt: the Case Study of Small-Format Documents 187 S. Tost 10. Social Network Analysis of Cuneiform Archives—a New Approach 207 C. Waerzeggers iv Contents PRICES IN THE ANCIENT MEDITERRANEAN AND NEAR EAST 11. The Volatility of Prices of Barley and Dates in Babylon in the Third and Second Centuries BC 234 R. J. van der Spek 12. Wheat Prices in Ptolemaic Egypt 260 S. von Reden 13. Mediterranean Grain Prices c. 300 to 31 BC: the Impact of Rome 289 D. Rathbone 14. Mediterranean and Near Eastern Grain Prices c. 300 to 31 BC: Some Preliminary Conclusions 313 D. Rathbone Index 323 Preface This volume comprises the proceedings of an interdisciplinary conference held in Vienna in 2008 to mark the final phase of the START Project “The Economic History of Babylonia in the First Millennium BC” funded by the Fonds zur Förderung der wissenschaftlichen Forschung (Austrian Science Fund). The preparation of this book has benefitted from the assistance of a number of individuals, to whom the editors owe their grateful thanks. With exemplary care and efficiency, Daniela Niedermayer and Georg Tanzler took care of the preliminary formatting of most of the contributions, and we thank Judith Pfitzner for preparing one article and especially for her work on compiling the Index. We are also greatly indebted to Emmanuelle Salgues and Elvira Wakelnig, who translated the articles by Dominique Charpin and Sven Tost from their respective original French and German. Finally, we thank Julie Gardiner and her colleagues at Oxbow Books for accepting this volume and seeing it through to publication. Heather D. Baker and Michael Jursa Vienna, October 2013 Contributors Heather D. Baker (Vienna University) Dominique Charpin (Paris) Jan Gerrit Dercksen (Leiden University) Michael Jursa (Vienna University) Dennis Kehoe (Tulane University) Myrto Malouta (Oxford University) Reinhard Pirngruber (VU University Amsterdam) Dominic Rathbone (King’s College London) Sitta von Reden (Albert-Ludwigs-Universität, Freiburg im Breisgau) R. J. van der Spek (VU University Amsterdam) Sven Tost (Vienna University) Caroline Waerzeggers (VU University Amsterdam) 1 Introduction Michael Jursa This collection of papers is the result of a conference in Vienna in 2008 that brought together scholars of different periods of Mesopotamian history and classicists working on Greco-Roman sources. The conference was held under the auspices of the START project ‘The Economic History of Babylonia in the First Millennium BC’ which was directed by M. Jursa at the University of Vienna between 2002 and 2009. Correspondingly, the objective of the conference was to explore the potential of interdisciplinary approaches to ancient economic history on a methodological and a factual level, a research programme that has since led to the establishment of a joint project of classicists, papyrologists, Islamic historians and Assyriologists exploring aspects of ancient administrative history.1 In fact, similar agenda are being pursued also elsewhere, e.g., by the ‘Legal Documents in Ancient Societies’ group.2 The Vienna conference aimed not only at establishing a dialogue between different academic fields that might eventually broaden the protagonists’ perspective as they pursued their respective interests; it was also intended – as this volume intends – to address methodological points of contact in the study of Ancient Near Eastern and Greco-Roman documentary sources, and to investigate the potential commensurability of the results of such investigations. More specifically, the conference’s agenda was informed by the – admittedly very old – question of whether it should be accepted, following in the footsteps of Moses Finley, that the basic structure of the Ancient Mesopotamian economies, in which institutional households and redistributive bureaucracies played an important role, precludes making useful comparisons with the economic systems of the Greco-Roman world, in which such institutions generally 1 http://imperiumofficium.univie.ac.at/ (accessed 22.8.2013). 2 http://www.ldas-conf.com/ (accessed 22.8.2013). See now Faraguna 2013, where some issues related to ancient archival documentation from the Ancient Near East and the Greco-Roman world that are at stake also in the present volume are explored. 2 Michael Jursa did not have an important function.3 While this position continues to be held in the field of Greco-Roman history, it is – increasingly, it would seem – at odds with the perception of Assyriologists that the nature of the Mesopotamian economies is not captured sufficiently by the institutional household model which informed Finley’s thesis. Nowadays a much more important role is ascribed to the economic agency and the economic interdependence (on the basis of commercial exchange) of individuals and nuclear households. The papers presented by Charpin and especially Dercksen in this volume can serve as an example for the state of research on the first half of the second millennium BC.4 A ‘modernist’ or ‘formalist’ view of the Mesopotamian economy is especially prevalent among the specialists in the Mesopotamian Iron age, where, as can now be demonstrated, from the sixth century BC at least, a strongly monetized economy experienced phases of noticeable aggregate and per capita growth on the strength of agricultural intensification and efficient institutions, which include fairly well performing commodity markets and, at least in part and for some time, also factor markets.5 Incidentally, at the same time some students of the Greco-Roman economy have turned against what used to be minimalist or primitivist readings of the evidence, emphasizing the remarkable performance especially of the Roman economy, and seeing evidence for economic growth that is structurally not dissimilar (albeit happening on a much larger scale) from the model that can be posited for the economic development in Mesopotamia’s imperial phase of the Iron Age.6 However, while the ‘formalist’ reading of the Mesopotamian economy of the first millennium BC can be supported not only by a rich body of qualitative information extracted from thousands of economic documents, but also by an irregular, but still quite abundant flow of quantifiable data (see, e.g., the contributions of van der Spek, Pirngruber and Jursa in this volume), such data are largely lacking for much of Greco-Roman antiquity – and archaeological data, which can serve as a proxy for textual data, is quite often ambiguous.7 It comes thus as no surprise that opinions on the Roman (and Greek) economy still differ widely and that a reviewer might state that a book on “The Roman Market Economy” did “a good job of persuading me that there was really nothing resembling an integrated Roman market economy”,8 that “there are no ancient statistics” and that “as Finley insisted, the crucial point is that the Romans simply did 3 See below the contribution by Jursa, notes 5–7. 4 For a nuanced view of the data from the third millennium BC, which lend themselves best to the traditional ‘household model,’ see Garfinkle 2012. 5 Van der Spek et al. (forthcoming). 6 See, e.g., Morris et al. 2007, Bresson (2014) and Jongman (2014). 7 As can be shown by the divergent interpretations of the huge amphora mound (Monte Testaccio) outside Rome as evidence for long-distance trade in olive oil or for state-controlled distribution: e.g., Thonemann 2013, 10–11 (to which Jongman (2014) can be added). 8 While, according to Rathbone 2007, 719, “the main stimulus to economic development in Roman Egypt came from the Roman creation of a peaceful and open Mediterranean market, and the boom in demand caused by empire-wide urbanization.” 1 Introduction 3 not conceive of their “economic” activity (buying, selling, lending) in what we would think of as economic terms at all.”9 The specific contribution of this volume, beyond the methodological level, lies in its offering a point of comparison that may cause the Greco-Roman data to appear in a new light. Ancient Near Eastern data, once they are demonstrated to be commensurable with corresponding Greco-Roman information, can serve as proxy-data to compensate for the lack of data on the Greco-Roman side (providing this comparison is done with some control over the different cultural settings, obviously). Two examples: it may potentially be conceded that Romans, or perhaps some Romans, thought about their economy “not in terms of commerce, contracts and profits, but obligations, benefits, and reciprocity,” rendering this a “moral economy”10 – but Ancient Near Eastern data can show that this is quite probably a misleading contrast in that, for instance, “a characterization of Old Assyrian merchants as profit-driven private entrepreneurs is correct, but ignores the all-permeating influence of religious, legal, and other institutions into which the trade and the traders (as in other periods and places) were embedded” (Dercksen, this volume): the market is evidently as culturally embedded as any other institution of socio-economic life. While this is perhaps by now a commonplace among economic historians and economic anthropologists,11 it is satisfying to note that the Old Assyrian evidence as discussed by Dercksen contains, if not the Assyrian equivalent of the lost work *De opibus gentium by a putative Roman Adam Smith,12 then at least explicit textual data that refer to the Assyrian merchants’ awareness of the economic rules of the socio-economic environment in which they operated. A second example: the mere fact that Rathbone, van der Spek and von Reden are able to make a meaningful comparison between grain prices in Seleucid Babylonia, Ptolemaic Egypt and Rome is a remarkable first, especially as the robust Babylonian data lend considerable additional weight to the argument: “We seem to be dealing with a world where regional factors of production and consumption set normal ranges of grain prices but there was sufficient overarching market integration to link these ranges in patterns of fairly stable relationships” (Rathbone, this volume): a conclusion not easily squared with a Finleyite view of the Mediterranean economy. Two papers present the extraordinarily rich information from Middle Bronze-Age Mesopotamia. Drawing on evocative anecdotal information and quantitative data alike, Dercksen presents a nuanced picture of Old Assyrian trade and the workings of the embedded markets he posits, and of the institutions that governed their functioning.13 Charpin offers a survey of the even more vast and more variegated, but also more 9 All quotes from Thonemann 2013. 10 All quotes from Thonemann 2013. 11 In direct opposition to Polanyi’s view of the market, in fact. This is relevant because Polanyi is still frequently invoked with respect to the Ancient Near East (Dale 2013), but it does not seem that there is still much to be gained here. 12 Who, according to Thonemann 2013, 11, is literally inconceivable. 13 Note that a recent systematic survey of the structure of the documentary record which Dercksen uses can be found in Veenhof 2013. 4 Michael Jursa dispersed Old Babylonian corpus. This is a background article to an ongoing project directed by Charpin that aims at building an online database of Old Babylonian texts (http://www.archibab.fr/). The article explores some of the aspects of the corpus that are of relevance for economic history, e.g., institutional record-keeping, accounting and the forecasting of institutional resources, all of which was done in a controlled and rational manner. There are structural parallels here to the estate accounts from Roman Egypt studied, e.g., in Rathbone 1991: the implications of such functional parallels in accounting systems for the reconstruction of their socio-economic setting have yet to be explored. Three papers pursue an explicitly methodological interest. Kehoe brings the approach of New Institutional Economics to bear on legal and economic data relating to agrarian conditions in the Roman Empire. This institutional approach – which implicitly informs Dercksen’s contribution too – is demonstrably also fruitful for Ancient Near Eastern studies (Jursa 2013) and can be expected to elicit a considerable degree of interest. While Kehoe draws on recent developments in economics and economic history, Waerzeggers finds her inspiration in the social sciences. Exploring the possibility of applying Social Network Analysis to ancient data – in this case, Late Babylonian private archives, – she introduces into Assyriological discourse a potent methodology that is certain to be taken up elsewhere in the field. The prosopographical data offered by the vast Mesopotamian tablet archives from the late third millennium, the first half of the second millennium and from the seventh and sixth century BC are well-suited for a quantifying analysis of this kind.14 There is significant potential for dialogue between Ancient Near Eastern Studies and Papyrology here, as can be shown by a comparison of Waerzeggers’ work (or of the studies cited in note 14) with, e.g., the work of Ruffini (2008) on Byzantine Egypt (see Kehoe 2013, 13–14). By drawing on both archaeological and textual data for the study of house sizes and their implications for household structure in first millennium BC Babylonia, and by attempting quantification on the basis of this information, Baker demonstrates not only that such an approach is possible on the basis of the information that can be culled from the tablet archives of the period and from the archaeological record, but that it is in fact the only way to overcome the inherent bias of any single type of source material we possess. By correlating dwelling sizes and textual data bearing on the size of households, the resulting investigation is also a contribution to the comparative study of living standards and social status in antiquity as well as an important corrective to the tendency in the study of urban demography to adopt all too simplified models for calculating population densities. The remaining papers address some core issues of the economic history of the Iron Age and the Eastern Mediterranean world of Late Antiquity. Tost offers a nuanced reading of the evidence for money use in the Egyptian countryside from the fifth to the eighth century, i.e., from Late Antiquity to the early Islamic period. The 14 See now also, for instance, Brumfield 2013 and Bamman et al. 2013

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.