ebook img

Dark Age Economics A New Audit PDF

87 Pages·2012·69.929 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Dark Age Economics A New Audit

Dark Age Economics A NEW AUDIT Richard Hodges Bristol Classical Press First published in 2012 by Bristol Classical Press Contents an imprint of Bloomsbury Academic Bloomsbury Publishing Plc 50 Bedford Square Preface VIl London WC1B 3DP, UK List ofillustrations XIll Copyright © 2012 by Richard Hodges All\rights reserved. No part of this publication 1. The debate 1 may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, electronic, 2. 'Forget the Trobriand Islands, the Kula Ring'? Models for 19 mechanical, photocopying, recording or othE;lrwise, early medieval economics without the prior permission of the publisher. 3. A golden age ofthe peasantry:the 'original affluent society'? 41 CIP records for this book are available from the 4. Shrine franchises: monastic cities and the transformation of 67 British Library and the Library of Congress the European economy ISBN 9780715636794 5. Debating the history of 'mushroom cities' 91 Typeset by Ray Davies 6. Audit: the 'hypostatic union of idea and material' 116 Printed and bound in Great Britain by MPG Books Group Ltd Bibliography 139 Index 157 www.bloomsburyacademic.com v For Kiinberly Preface ... it seems commonly to be overlooked that the excavators of Tarsus have found no Cloth Hall, that all ancient cities lacked the Guildhalls and Bourses which, next to the cathedrals, are to this day the architectural glories of the great niedieval cities of Italy, France, Flanders, the Hansa towns, or Eng­ land. Contrast the Athenian Agora with the Grande Place in Brussels. Itis no oversight on the part ofPausanias when heomitted that class ofbuilding from his sneer about the little town in Phocis (Moses I. Finley, The Ancient Economy (1999): 137-8). My original Dark Age Economics: the origins of towns and trade (1982; hereafter DAE) focussed upon the rise of towns and trade rather than economics as such. In particular, it concentrated upon the emerging role of markets in the post-Roman world, defining components of medieval European society. What it did not do was chart the early medieval journey from the consumption cities ofantiquity to the centres ofproduction in the Middle Ages. Nor did it explain, to any great extent, how this happened. Any 'imaginary' world involving, for example, the ritual economy was well beyond its purview (see the critique of DAE in Theuws 2004). Now, with a wealth of new archaeological evidence available, such questions, posed forty years ago by Moses Finley in bald and unequivocal terms, are closer to our grasp as the emphasis has swung towards understaJlding agency and the human engagement with materiality.­ As any scholar would now acknowledge, using the pejorative periodisa­ tion~term~'Dark Age' to separate off a period from the civilised eras before and after is today anachronistic (see Moreland 2010: 7). The 1970s, however, when DAE was written, were a different time when post-war 'progress' was undermined by economic challenge and the menace of nuclear war. 'Dark Age' had a powerful contemporary resonance. Yet in choosing this title, with its implicit homage to Marshall Sahlins' Stone Age Economics (1972), I was actually attempting to reach beyond the Renais­ sance perception that this was a primitive and barbarous era. " It is thirty years since fJAE was published in Colin Renfrew's Duck­ worth series, New Studies in Archaeology. Looking back now, the book seems like an ethnographic odyssey from another era, conceived when the archaeology of the Middle Ages was in its infancy, essentially practised to illustrate the margins of the written texts. DAE attempted to challenge the rhetoric of these texts, employing the then uneven archaeological evidence from north-west Europe. Nevertheless, it still belonged to a vi vu Dark Age Economics Preface paradigm, beginning with the dorlrinant nineteenth-century Austro-German model,of historical evolution, that by way of gradual stages, including analysing the economic base' (Hann and Hart 2011: 73-4). By c~ntrast, feudalIsm, charted the triumph of European modernism (see Shaw 2008: traditional archaeological thought in the 1970s p~aced emphaSIS ,upon !12; also Devr~ey 2006: 520-1). Today the archaeology of this era is excavating trading sites and interpreting these USIng the few, a~aIlable historical sources. Issues of dating the settlements and a fetIshIsm for Im~e~surably rIcher, the debates about its meaning have accordingly lost origins as well as continuity with a Roman past concerned most a:chae­ theIr Innocence, and the positivist treatment of the material and written ~ources has, been repla?ed by an increasingly fascinating debate about the ologists (cf. Biddle 1976). Explaining the re-emergence of towns lI~, the Issues and InterpretatIOns of the material itself rather than about differ­ post-Roman era was treated, as Matthew Johns~n has ~rgued, In, a ent strains of historical practice, particularistic manner and in many w~yst~at-yvere riddled :v:th menta~Ist arguments (with references to innate rekindling of the spIrIt of trade or , I had studie~ trade as culture process with Renfrew and was hugely 'the trading spirit of the Frisian peoples') (Johnson 1999: 70!. . Influenced by his ground-breaking Emergence of Civilisation (1972) _ 'one DAE took the North Sea area as a region within which SOCIal complexIty of the most important books in archaeology from the second half of the and the rise of towns and trade were connected by systemic feedback loops. ~wentieth century' (Ch~rry 2010: xxvi). DAE incorporated many of his Ideas that I had used In my doctoral th~sis on Southampton's traded D nderpinning this was the gradual evolution of ~ chiefdom ~ociety with a variable control of the production and circulatIOn of prestIge goods (cf. pottery of the seventh to ninth centuries (subsequently published as Hodges 1981)-In his ~nvi~ation to write,for ~is series, Renfrew encouraged Earle 2011). The more successful a chief was at c.ontr~lling the ,flow of goods, the more he could reward his followers With gIfts that In turn ,: me ,to make It ~ccesslble to archaeologIsts In Tucson', As we were experi­ e~cI~gthe ze~thofthe,so-~alled New Archaeology in the UK at that time, generated reciprocal obligations. The rise of a smal~ number o~ mono­ polistic urban centres (emporia) in the seventh to mnth centurIes was WInnIng AmerIcan admIratIOn was a seal ofapproval. Without doubt, DAE interpreted as an attempt to control production and distribution. The O\~ed a great deal to Renfrew's brilliant teaching and inspiring scholar­ S~I~. It also ?wed much to Klavs Randsborg, whose ground-breaking The planning of these emporia, I contended, reflected central control and VLkLng Age Ln Denmark also appeared in Renfrew's Duckworth series ~ therefore royal patronage of dendritic central-place systems. DAE ~lso attempted to set the processes of urbanisation in north-west Europe In a (Ra~dsb?rg 1980). ~ookingback, I was also influenced by my debates with larger anthropological context. These models, needless to say, based hCohurrIss WoIfC fkrI~eanmd,ly w Id~Ishc uwshsI~OmnsI, cIo lblaeblioervaetde dh oisn fhiiesltdo prircoajle cmtso idneTlst awlye. rFer otomo largely upon the work of the anthropologist and geograp~er, Ca~ol ~. ; . ' mech~nistic - too ?ooki~h. Total history, as it used to be called, involved ' Smith (1976), merited carefultreatment in terms ~fthe partIcular historI­ cal circumstances. Yet the processes, I believed, mIght be tested by further gras~Ing the r~latIOnshIp ?etween all the different sources. Today, Wick­ archaeological excavations. , . ham s ~ram~ng the MLddleAges (2005), encyclopaedic in scale, summarIses hIS views cogently; .w ith friencl.ly·admiration;"ollce again, I Since the publication<?f DAE in 1982, the debate about ur~aI?- OrIgIns hasmostlybeeIl a.evelopedby those focussing upon the economIC Issues, of ~hall .c hallenge some of them here. One final, but no less important the epoch as opposed to the creation of particular market-places. At ItS Influence -yvas Bronislav Malinowski's Argonauts of the Western Pacific heartthishasbecomea debate about urbanism and whether, as Hordern (1922). This great romantic economic history established a benchmark for the arguably comparable spirit of the. North Sea Frisian merchants and and Purcell provocatively put it: 'towns are settings in which ec?logi~al 'I their will to trade in the seventh and eighth centuries. processes may be intense, and in which the a~thropogene e~f~ct IS at ItS most pronounced. But they are not or not SImply by definItIon - more DAE set out to develop a systemic interpretation for the evolution of than that. And they should not be presented as conceptually detachable ~owns, trade and social complexity in post-Roman northwest Europe. At from the remainder of the spectrum of settlement types' (Hordern and ItS core ,was Karl, Polanyi's thesis of a substantivist as opposed to a (modernIst) form~lIst e,cono~y, and the contention that it was inappropri. "Purcell 2000: 100-1). This 'ruralising' of urban history has met",a sh~rp ate to use ~conomlCratIOnalIty as the operating mode for the tribal polities response from ancient historians, many of whom. wou~d e~p~tliI~e WIth William Harris in arguintthat this approach shrInks Into InSIgnificance of the perIOd (as Moses FinIey had argued was the case for classical the whole category of the town or city (2005: 29; see Hirth 2008 on the ~~tiquity) (Polanyi 1957; cf. SaIler 2005; Devroey 2006: 588-91). Context same debate regarding Mayan urbanism). IS Important. T~e 1970s ~arked the high-water mark ofthe 'golden age' of great debates In economIC anthropology. Later, taking a 'cultural turn' This 'spectrum' approach has become the corner~tone of ~on~emporary studies. of Anglo-Saxon England, explicitly 90ntestmg the sIgmficance of (Hann and Hart 2011: 84), French Marxist anthropology began to win over those who had been 'tilting at windmills in the superstructure instead ~f the emporia as political non-places advocated in DAE (cf. N~ylor 2004: 12-14; Brookes 2007: 23-6; Saunders 1991; 2001). Ben Palmer (In 2003: 50) viii ix Dark Age Economics Preface put ~hi~point of view bluntly: ~The "Hodgean" model of development has 2010: 56-9) . The same is true of the past. Our challenge is to shape this :~~~~eh as}ong as it has partly because of the prevalence of the "kings multi-vocal past into a history that has coherence and logic for our age, b ' IS, ops school of Anglo-Saxon history, ... and partly because it was Let me define this a little more closely. No one now emphasises urban Se heved t~at the. ar~ha~ologi?al evidence for rural sites of the Middle continuity from the Roman era into the Middle Ages, as was the norm , axon penod was Inslgnifica~t (but see Wickham 2005: 593-4). To be fair thirty years ago. The decline of the Roman town as a central-place and the In 1982 w~en DAE was publIshed, the archaeology of rural household .' eventual revival of regional urbanism by the eleventh century (if a little early ,medIeval Europe was limited (cf. Naylor 2004' 10-14) T d s 1n sha.l ld I llust' rate in Chapter 3 , the eVI'dence t ranSiLO" rms any re,a0di ay, f atsh l ealairkleie. rT ihne s momane nreegr iionn ws)h airceh nthoiws a'rcecbeiprtthe'd hbayp aprecnheade,o olof gcoisutrss aen, adn hdis tthoer iraonles perlO . ThIS same argument informs Chris W' kh' k nt? 0 . e in Framing the Middle Ag ( IC am s wor culmInatIng of (interlocking) regional markets embracing peasant households, remain s Journal ofAgrarian Chang: 9 ~~O:b;;e alsolihe co~lection of articles in a subject of debate. as the different approaches taken b ,a,s we ,as WlCkham 2009) as well The contemporary paradigm owes much to Henning (2007), McCormick Devroey (2006) .Joh M I d y cntlcal thInkers such as Jean-Pierre, (2001), Skre (2008), and Wickham (2005) with the many associated critical 00 (2004; 2007; '2008; ~rt;::~~ )(21 ;; 2000b; 2~10~ and Frans Theuws essays that provide a rich and detailed basis for appraising the economic g history, the debate is m h h · s or those still Interested in urban and urban histories of post-Roman Europe (e.g. Theuws 2004; Radtke evidence from numerous :ce~t arper, t~anks to the extraordinarily rich 2009; Scull 2009; Willemsen and Kik 2010). There are also excellent proceedings on this theme edi~~~a~atI3ns,~~ t~e two-:volume conference overviews ofthe economic history such as Devroey (2003; 2006) Verhulst Towns, Trade and Settlement' E y oac Im He~nlng. Post-Roman (2002) and Laiou and Morrisson (2007). This book, therefore, confines ingly demonstrates. In urope and Byzantlum (2007) convinc- itself to defining the debate once more, reviewing the particular - and An audit - a conventi ft' , indeed, salient - archaeological features of the evolving economy of early though, the place to tota~:0 t~ur I:es IS t~erefore timely. This is not, medieval western Europe. With evidence that was not available in the the context for listing the ,Jess~s~ tO~ or:gall?-st,th~ argument. Nor is it 1970s, this means grasping the scale of agrarian household production and the Roman econom' ImlS s an optImIsts as far as the end of its socio-political management, as well as its part in the transition from Instead, DAE now ;e:~ concerned, ~s Bryan Ward-Perkins did (1997). consumption to production cities, as identified by Max Weber and elabo­ land-owner and peasantS :~ ~:IIe~:l~trated from the, perspe~tive of the rated by Moses Finley (Finley 1999: 192; Saner 2005). largely controlled the cosmologies of th e Ch)urch (which domln,ated and, Given such a concise but abstract argument, it is tempting to broaden the urban craftsmen and trade Th' e~rak as opposed to the Impact of the purview of the debate to include Byzantium, the Islamic world in the perspective, challenmng my earl~s. IS 00 his.et~ out the scope for this Near East, North Africa and Spain (as Wickham has done with magisterial The cardI, nal lessob~n of th Nt wleAr ers say on t s s~u b~' ect. success~_(2005).For Byzantium, a new review of this era reveals .h ow and 1970s) was that we d e d chaeology (as practised in the 1960s reduce-d· the-economic capacity of the empire was (Brubaker and Haldon anthropology (as Dobres ~n~oR~~~ (~~~~)t~e intell~ctual poo~ cousin of 2011). For Arabic regions such as Syria, urban history, in particular, has contrast, historians of the' ave wrItten) or hIstory. By evolved-markedly over the past thirty years with many new excavations material culture in s ace per~od cannot overlook the central issues of and overviews depicting urban expansion coupled with powerful industri­ like those ofthe Victo~ian ~~; ~Ime ?ecaudse their written sources, rather alisation linked to palace economies (see, for example,Walmsley 2007). (cf. Thomas 1996) t SlOnanes an travellers in the Pacific Ocean But for the most part Arabic history is part of a larger issue that belongs this point about th,ea irmep o0r0t asnp aref andh r he1to rI' ca1. WI'C kham made exactly to the debate about the making of the modern world economy beyond the documentary sources for defc" e 0 ar,c. ta eo og,y. i n the a b sence 0 f suf f"lClent scope ofthis (or the original) book (cf. Pomeranz 2000: 5; Banaji 2007: 57). (Wickham 2005' 595) N thlnIlng Cl yness In the early Middle Ages As the archaeology of Tang China and its Indian Ocean and Spk Road . . ever e e'slsi cocooned l'k bl ' , present, there is still as in all d' ,le oggers, In a VIrtual connections to the Caliph~te become better known, European history quarters as to what ~onstitutesI~~~o;es, ~co~servative appr?ach!n some (including Byzantium) se~ins less central. But was it? At present it IS many forms and, discomfiting as it ' Ytan w at,does, not. Hlstones take wisest to conclude with Morris and Manning, that 'Sinocentricism is as much by the lives of their auth IS 0 many hIstorIans, are shaped as speculative as Weber's Eurocentrism and involves just as many untestable b education today, it is not surpri~f~ a:h!t the so~ces. Of c~~rse, given our counterfactuals' (2005: 24). ~, words, yet other texts of course e~st inSt~m~c eihasls ~s placed ?-pon In writing this book I should like to acknowledge the kind invitation culture that are no less compell' 'fi e ~rm 0 materIal and VIsual extended by Andrew Reynolds to lecture to the Society for Medieval lng manI estatlOns of our times (cf. Olsen Archaeology in October 2006. Two further occasions permitted me to x Xl s Dark Age Economics fashion my ideas more clearly. First, I was privileged to develop these' ideas in four Dalrymple Lectures, delivered at Glasgow University in February 2009. Special thanks to Stephen Driscoll and Ewan Campbell for making this such a stimulating opportunity. Then, a month later, in March 2009, I co-organised withSauro Gelichi a conference on the empo­ riumat Comacchio entitled· from 'From One Sea to Another' where List of Illustrations students of early medieval economics from all the seas around Europe exchanged ideas and presented an extraordinary amount ofnew evidence. I am happy to remember other debts too. The late Gerald Dunning gave me my first orientation about the long-distance trade in ceramics which' started my pursuit of Henri Pirenne's celebrated thesis on the origins of 1. Map ofprincipal places mentione~·hi~ the dte~t. 2 2. Simplified version of Carol A. Smlt. s ,mo e s. 4 medieval towns. The late John Hurst was exceptionally generous in helping me ~o visit all the places associated with the ceramics and trade. 3. L.D. Minc's revision of Carol A. SIDlth s model. 1 £ r the 24 Colin Renfrew, as I described above, Was both an inspiration and a 4. Alternative types ofrank-size curve and the formu a 0 25 memorably kind'mentor as I experimented with this complex subject. At log-normal. k AD that time, too, Wim van Es, the fabled excav?tor of Dorestad and the 5. The changing social structures of eastern Denmar ,c. 27 examiner ofmy doctoral thesis, encouraged me wholeheartedly. (Continu­ 800-1200. , f t B It' ing thisspirit ofDutch generosity, Wilfried Hessingkindly organised a day S0ren M. Sindbmk's synoptic comparIson 0 wes ern a IC 28 trip and round table briefing for me at Dorestad in October 2011, updating 6. sites: excavation and selected imports from Hedeby. . me on the important discoveries at the 'Veilingterrein' site.) Much of this 7. Stephen Gudeman's spatial model ofa great estate WIth 38 book has been written at the University ofPennsylvania Museum, where manses. t t t ith I have benefited from the patience of my colleagues and the excellent 8. Stephen Gudeman's spatial model of a grea es a e w 38 library. I also owe a great debt to my publishers, Duckworth, now trans- ' peasants. , d t t ferred to Bloomsbury, especially the late, idiosyncratic but patient, Colin 9. Stephen Gudeman's spatial modhel of IttnIdepent ep:t!:~s~~;V' 39 Haycraft, who painstakingly re-drafted the original text of DAE, and the~ o The pagus Texandrie. Modelof tese. e~en . 45 generous-spirited Deborah Blake. Thanks, too, to Sarah Leppard for pre­ 1 . single sand plateau after initial colonIsation (c. 550-625). I paring the illustrations, to Soren Sindbmk for making Figure 6 available 1 The pagus Texandrie. Model of the settlement pattern on a 45 to me, and to Flemming Bau for kindlyper:tnitting~me.to use.his.exquisite sa.n4~pla~~a.ll a. 1 . single fter the creation of a nucleated reconstructioh Painting ofKaupang (Fig. 22). settlement (c. 625-725). As to the ideas expounded in this audit, my thanks as ever to Andrea 12 The pagus TeX(1ndriif. Model of the ~ettlement pattern on a ) 46 Augenti, Giovanna Bianchi, Will Bowden;· Sauro Gelichi;John Haldon, . sirl' le sand plateau after the mid-eIghth century (c. 750-~~0 . Michelle Hobart, Mike McCormick, John Mitchell, John Moreland, Tim 13. Th;pagus Texandrie. Model of a composite estate comprIsIng 47 Pestell, Klavs Randsborg, S0ren Sindbmk, Dagfinn Skre, Frans Theuws and Marco Valenti. Special thanks to Chris Wickham and, above all, my several local grOUPs' (E 1 14. Mortality profiles for West Stow, Kilham, and Brandon ar y 55 wife, Kim Bowes, and the late and much missed Riccardo Francovich. to Middle Saxon), sheep. 15. Reconstruction of the water-mill atfrAugstbhur~~luwe region of 60 16. Spatial modelfor the trade in iron om e 64 the Netherlands. 'h 1 'th 17. The topography of San Vincenzo al Volturno In t e ear y nln 72 century. V I . th 780s 18. A hypothetical plan of San Vincenzo al ,0 turno In e , 75 phase 3c. AD 808 19. The topography of San Vincenzo all VVolltturno c. AD 830' 40 77 20. The topography of San Vincenzo a 0 urno c. -. 78 XlI xiii Dark Age Economics 21. The topograp~y ofSan Vincenzo al Volturno c. AD 840~50. 22. 80 A reconstructIOn ofthe emporium at Kaupang N 23. Th' h ' orway. 100 . e Ivory ead of a tonsured monk with blue glass eyes found 135 1 near the workshops at San Vincenzo al Volturno, c. AD '830-40. The debate A new age does not ... rewrite the world and inscribe new meanings upon it which archaeologists should hope to recover; rather, each age confronts the debris of its history, material and traditional, as a way of finding a home for itself. Archaeology must now be interested in considering how that may have been achieved and the various political and social consequences that arose from or were maintained by those practices (Barrett 2001: 67). The historian of science, Thomas Kuhn, believed that each scientific tradition possesses its own paradigms, and therefore its own notions of truth; it is a view that resonates well with the culturalist axiom that scientific truth does not transcend cultural truth. As a result, paradigms have, in Kuhn's view, a discontinuous relationship to one another. The shifts betweenparadigms are effected by agents with 'competing positions' due to their investment, political and otherwise, in existing or new para­ digms. So, in the applied and natural sciences, paradigm shifts drive the discipline: 'there is no room for the older-fashioned in science' (Morris 1999: xxiii). But in the humanities and social sciences almost the reverse is true. The influence of older models invariably extends across decades and even generations. This is particularly the case for the subject ofDark Age economics. The ~~~~competition··between paradigms has taken shape since the 1930s, acceler­ ated perhapsfirsfby the adv€mt of scientific archaeology in the 1970s (cf. Gerrard 2003: 172-80), and then by increasing collaboration between alsClplines and between scholars from different countries since the 1980s (e.g. Ransen and Wickham2000; Renning 2007). This isnot the place to review the history of this subject (see, for example, Gilchrist and Reynolds 2009). Rather, it is the context to summarise the three differ­ ent paradigms that set out to explain the rise of the medieval economy in the half millennium following the demise of the Western Roman Empire (Fig. 1). Thirty years ago there ~~re twoprevailing historical models: the trade model that Renri Pirenne ([1937] 2001) had championed before the Second World War was ceding ground to the agrarian model championed in the post-war years by Georges Duby (1968; 1974). Opinion was divided about i. these models, although the extant archaeology lent support to the trade modeL In the face ofthis Duby urged archaeologists to focus upon under­ standing the medieval countryside, and heeding this encouragement, in contrast to the archaeology of the ancient world, there is a remarkable new xiv 1 Dark Age Economics 1. The debate craftsmen as economic agents in the management ofGommerce and urban development in the Baltic Sea region. Drawing upon new archaeological evidence, however, a fourth model can be proposed that articulates elements ofthe other three by subsuming these to the changing purposes of a ritual economy. Let us look at each of these models in turn The trade model I The model advanced in DAE was not new. Since the 1920s Henri Pirenne had contended that medieval urbanism was revived in post-Roman north­ west Europe thanks to the causative role oflong-distance trade. The trade model (or distribution model, as Chris Wickham has called it: 2008: 19) is 11 at the heart of Pirenne's celebrated unfinished manuscript, Mohammed 11 and Charlemagne (2001 [1937]). Here he included archaeological discov­ 11 eries pertinent to his thesis: the emporium at Dorestad at the junction of -I , 'I the rivers Lek and Rhine in Holland, and the then new excavations at I, Haithabu (or Hedeby) in north Germany, near Schleswig (pirenne 2001: 237-9). His trade model was soon adopted. Holger Arbman used the 11 imported Frankish material from the excavations at Birka in Lake Miilaren to show the impact of trade upon the Viking world (Arbman 11 iI 1937). Six years later Herbert Jankuhn deployed the excavated evidence ii from Hedeby to advance the supremacy of the Carolingians in the Baltic 1! 1i region (1943). Published with overt Nazi support, the far-reaching influ­ 11 ence ofJankuhn's work cannot be understated (cf. Hodges 1982: 10; 1998; 11 11 Hi1l2001a: 3; Hilberg 2009: 86). New editions ofJankuhn's monograph on 1 i ; i his excavations at Hedeby appeared at regular intervals over the next fifty 11 i; ': ' " yearS.NCit:,sUi'pfis:liIglY,__his trade model, given the poverty of archaeologi~ !; 11 I o 0~ cal evidence, found followers in contiguous regions. I1I ' '. ,In the 1950s _a._uew .generation of archaeologists were drawn to the Mediterranean Sea argument. So, for example, G.C. Dunning published a seminal essay that 1/ / ; assembled imported pots found in Anglo-Saxon contexts, including London !i !;, I ' . and Southampton, and sketched an innovative outline for the birth of j! I North Sea commerce (Dunning 1956). Dunning's studies constituted a iII''; platform for the Gottingen conference in 1972 on 'Vor- undFriihformen i .. I 1 .' der europiiischen Stadt im Mittelalter' where the trade model was devel­ i, 500 km 'oped by many young archaeologists and historians and subs~quently l. Map ofprincipal places mentioned in the text. J published in the conference:proceedings (Jankuhn, Schlesinger and Steuer 1 1973). It would be misleading, therefore, to assert that DAE launched a body.ofdata pertaining to medieval r . 1 new paradigm. It did not. less .Important have been the man lIral socIety excavated since 1980. No The new twist to the trade model in DAE was anthropological archae­ medIeval science and craftsm~ attempts to re-define the origins of ology, following the American New Archaeology school. In particular, it Middle Ages. This led recentl anshIp that underpinned the rise of the Callmer (2007) which has ity ~o the ~roposal.ofa third model by Johann melded together the distinctly different ideas about trade and exchange of s ases In the dIaspora role of traders and the prehistorian Colin Renfrew and the anthropological geographer Carol A. Smith. Renfrew's systemic perspective assumed that social change j 2 3 Dark Age Economics 1. The debate Maximisation of benefits seemed and still seems an unacceptable model for examining urban evolution in early medieval Europe, although, as we" shall see, it is at the heart ofthe interpretation ofthe history ofmonetisa­ I tion in the early Middle Ages. Instead, the highly fragmented political polities of the era mediated against any straightforward maximisation of B benefits, with a few obvious exceptions. In DAE this was the motive for deploying the tri-partite substantivist model advanced by Karl Polanyi (1957). Polanyi advanced a simple model for socially embedded economies where first reciprocity existed, and then. redistribution, before market exchange. With the simplicity of his argument, Polanyi, it is now widely 2. Simplified version ofCarol AS' , central-place system' BSI . mlth s models: A. Dendritic acknowledged, leapt too schematica lly to explain the existence of the hierarchically arranged' ce~~:f_e~tral-pla~e system; C. Classic disembedded market (cf. Lie 1991; 1992). This evolutionary or progressive p ~ce market system. scheme fails to fully capture how economics b~came disembedded (though cannot be explained without .. see Skre 2008 for a so-called post-substantivist approach (and Chapter 2». culture. competItIOn operating at all levels f The . 0 a This is why I appropriated the work of Smith as the centrepiece of the pnmacy placed on com t'tl' on ! thesis presented in DAE.. Smith maintained that economic stratification argument was developed h pe I b ~as a cornerstone of DAE' Th. exch d ' owever Y USIng S .th' . e isa defining characteristic of agrarian societies. In her view, economic ange mo els for peasant societies . mI, s typology of regional classes are defined in terms of access to or control over the means of argued that the interaction of di (1976, s~: FIg. 2), Put simply, Smith production. Stratification, she contended, results 'from differential access through the growth ofan elite rou fferent p~h~Iesgenerates inequalities to or control over the means of exchange; variations in stratification goods. The establishment ofa ~ierI ~on~ohslngthe exch~ngeofprestige systems are related to types of exchange between producers and non-pro­ f?r the need to sustain a non-produ~~ y t en fu~ls economIC development ducers as they affect and are affected by the spatial distribution ofthe elite ~on and specialisation. This in tur:1scl~ss stl1~ulates rural intensifica~ and the level of commercialisation in the region and beyond' (Smith 1976: arket d~velopment, it might be said d t e basIs for economic take-off. 310). s gro:ut wIth an economic interest id bepe~~ed Upon elites effectively This model lays emphasis not upon control of production but upon SOCla y embedded economy So . 1 h rea Ing the political hold on a control of distribution, an index which archaeologists are normally well­ product of exogenous stimuii, s~~~ ~s ange, , therefore, is not solely the placed to measure, and embodies an accessible typology: . cul~ural system. Rather,itis the stru't . pr~~tlge.~goods,.enteringa closed aC~Ivate the system leading to indi~i~relofth~ ~xchange relations which 1. Uncommercialised exchange (nonmarket exchange) where transactions ot, er..T~e~e conditions, Smith . . ua pohtIes competing with each are direct. comme~clahsed market econo contended, paved~the way'for a 'fully 2. Partially commercialised, noncompetitive exchange (controlled market Aswillb my. d h e apparent, most critics ofDAE . exchange) where transactions are administered (by the elite). az: c allenged the historical part' ul }gnored Smith's theoretical model 3. Fully commercialised exchange (competitive market exchange). wIthstanding the increasing intere~t i:s.o my argument. Even today, not­ excha,nge, ,the spatial models that exist ~:xch~nge and ranked spheres of Ofcourse, the model, being more detailed than Polanyi's, still resembles a az:!histonans are essentially Walter Chri : ~~I(ds ofmany archaeolOgists fixed map. The early medieval era was not so static. Moreover, as a model WI 't:f:phasis upon maximising benefits s T~tr.s ~966)central-place theory devised for peasant market systems in modern Guatemala with its capi­ capI st model dependent Upon two pn.n'c.lp aI Sa IsSs, uimll pottihoenrs w: ords, a modern talist and global circumsta~ces, it is bound to have signal anthropological limitations. So since the publication of DAE,' rather than abandoning 1. The population and thus the . Smith's ideas, I have modified her model, introducing a broader range of un~ff~ren~iated and unbourfcr~~c~a;:ng power are distributed Over an interactionalforms, as follows: 2. MaXlmlsatIOn ofprofits and m' . . ~ce. ~re ~egulated in some way th:~~~~satI~nofcosts (supply and demand) 1. Smith places undue emphasis upon imbalanced exchange. This has lng In this spaCe. . a s ructured market system exist­ implications for the strategies adopted in monopolistic dendritic cen­ tres such as the urban centres known as emporia. No such evident o 4 5 J Dark Age Economics 1. The debate imbalance existed in these places, even though traders engaged on E,u rope and south-ern S cand I' naVI' a by the later tenth and eleventh centu- both sides doubtless attempted to win or maximise advantages over one another (see Skre 2008). The dominance theory implicit in the world systems approach, which informed Smith's model involving rieTs.h e origins and evolutI.O n 0 f t h e t ra d;' ng P lacesk -' empftohriea Maniddd wlei cAs g-esi.t dendritic systems, is too simplistic. Equally, the output of workshops d' DAE ere critical steps In t he ma Ing 0 was argue In , w posed involving first periodic fairs in solar central-places - administrative centres such as Carolingian A simple model of three stages was pro ermanent urban centres monasteries and palaces appears unbalanced (as I shall illustrate in l~m)ina~'p~a~:~ i~y~:nt~dt!:P~titive at designated markets. Stage by Chapter 4), but this takes no account of the 'invisible' reciprocity (and (Type B emporIa , w IC t' DAE proceeded empowered local its.cultural importance) made by those in receipt of high status work­ stage, these pla?es, so the. ~7gu~~n In political st~tus through the shop products. g with chiefdoms or kIngs, p1ro~ In th em thority to manage trade. With en­ 2. There are variants of the highly centralised dendritic system with, for t~aded 00 ~;:sta~:Su ownership of. of particular rulers grew and with example, occasions where several competing centres may indicate a hanced gIft-giVIng cyc es: ... f rian strategies. weaker central authority and competing forces attempting to partici­ time they invested in an In~enslflCatIO~:'~:::'~sation in this model, which pate in controlled commerce (cf. Scull 2002; Minc 2006: 86; Skre 2008); To sum up, trade ~ovZt e rr~~~~~g regional distributed markets in 3. There are evidently variants of solar central-places dominated by then served as a ba~Is or es a ISost-tribal states. administrative purposes, ranging from elite central-places in Anglo­ which taxed produc~IOn ~e~urced PI aedic and elegant study, Origins of Saxon England and early Viking southern Scandinavia (cf. Skre 2008), Michael McCormlck, In IS encyc op the trade model in a remarkable for example, to, conceivably, the idiosyncratic confederation of elites the European E~on?"!y (2001), dev:~oP~heses of Henri Pirenne and the under papal hegemony in eighth- and ninth-century Rome (Delogu way, building sIgmflCantl~ upon . e McCormick 2007: 59) by providing 2007). Swedish scholar, Sture Bohn (1953, cf. £ nces to travellers as well as a an annotated corpus of docU1:~enta~y r~o~r;:d in western contexts. McCor­ DAE concluded that the origins of the medieval market-town in north­ corpus of Islamic and Byzantine cOIns. hich 'Europe's small worlds west Europe belonged to the moment when a socially embedded economy mick argues for a culturally open agle, In;'e Muslim economies' (2001: became disembedded. The argument focussed upon systems ofredistribu­ t b l'nked to the greater wor d 0f , f t came 0 el, h t d d 'would fire the first rIse 0 wes ern tion and reciprocity through gift exchange before the ninth century. Com­ 797). These connectIOns, ehcon en e 'd tect in the movements of diplo- E . whose rhyt ms we can e E modities, the argument continued, were not produced until the ninth or urope, a TIse, d I think slaves as a new urope tenth century (at earliest) as competitively ranked and structured market­ mats, pilgrims, war~lO~, merchant~, an huma~wealth in exchange for places were created. Long-distance tradeinthe Baltic SeR and NorthSea, and its satellite SOCIeties exp.orted ItS own f Islam' (2001: 798). identified by earlier archaeologists such as Arbman, Jinkuhn and Dun­ -the-wea1tli-?fgoods and speCIes ofthe ~;~S:r;ative: 'emphatic images of ning, among others, was, for the most part, a trade of prestige goods or McCormlCk has cons~ruc~ed a '~;haw 2008: 90). But if McCormick primitive valuables. These were regulated at monopolistic centres -empo­ ---~~__v:iscosity ... pervade tJ:ris .~st~ry er ence of a peculiar north-west ria or wics -located on the limits of political territories. Social evolution stresses the major contInUl~Ies InlJhet~:bi; pipelines, including human occurred as peer-polity interaction (a term devised later by Renfrew (1986; European econo~~ was It re~cYdevelo ment (Shaw 2008: 90)? Were cf. Bauer and Agbe-Davies 2010: 39», mediated through the exchange of cargoes, that. fac~ht~ted?econo~~ Henni:g (2008) is certainly convinced, prestige goods, promoted political and often economic growth. By stages there rea~y bI~ plpelin?s. Jo~cf~ (2005' 696 n. 8). Subsequently, McCor­ up until the late eighth or early ninth century, this interaction generated while ChrlS WlCkham IS dou ~ d lt' " It is worth emphasising that the increasingly more complex economic development. But with Charle­ mick has offered a caveat to s ~o e rice ofagrarian developrrtent, nor magne's bid to replace plunder and gift-giving with regularised tributes new scenario does not lessen the ImJor a /t h sole and prime mover of the and taxation (cf. Reuter 1985; Verhulst 2002: 73-83), conditions were does it mean that long-.distance tr~: w~s ; the first European economy shaped, specifically by decrees agreed at the Council ofFrankfurt in 793/4, Carolingian economy: It was not. . e rise 0 r ran e trade appears in the for the introduction of a competitive market system and with it the seeds started with successful food productIOnci.Longe.~n d!velopment in several of a socially disembedded economy. Market towns, therefore, as the hall­ context of growing local exch~n1e ~nll af:\he boom in construction in mark of a non-kin-based political strategy, were adopted in the Frankish privileged regions' (2002: 53). s sas 0 ~t expansion of Carolingian territories and England, for example, by the late ninth century and in the early C",:olingian era, and th~~o:~=~lledmanual labour. But ~as regions under Frankish influence such as central Italy, west-central estates, certaInly created a dem~n 0 t S dinavian ports exchanging it met by Dorestad merchants In wes can 6 7

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.