ebook img

Conflict and Defense: A General Theory PDF

366 Pages·1962·28.994 MB·English
Save to my drive
Quick download
Download
Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.

Preview Conflict and Defense: A General Theory

'■v? ■Cv \-MAA V n;;u \,: i-.i: ' !■ L;'f I i■ AA !t : ; :y / CONFLICT AND DEFENSE A General Theory Kenneth E. Boulding Professor of Economics Institute of Behavioral Sciences University of Colorado UNIVERSITY PRESS OF AMERICA Lanham New York ® London Copyright © 1962,1988 by Kenneth E. Bouiding University Press of America, ® Inc. 4720 Boston Way Lanham, MD 20706 3 Henrietta Street London WC2E 8LU England All rights reserved Printed in the United States of America British Cataloging in Publication Information Available Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Bouiding, Kenneth Ewart, 1910- Conflict and Defense. Includes index. 1. Peace. 2. Social conflict. 3. International relations. I. Title. JX1963.B6954 1988 327.1'6 88-27677 ISBN 0-8191-7112-3 (pbk. : alk. paper) All University Press of America books are produced on acid-free paper. The paper used in this publication meets the minimum requirements of American National Standard for Information Sciences—Permanence of Paper for Printed Library Materials, ANSI Z39.48-1984. CONTENTS PREFACE TO THE UNIVERSITY PRESS OF AMERICA EDITION vii PREFACE XV 1. STATIC MODELS OF CONFLICT 1 2. THE DYNAMICS OF CONFLICT: RICHARDSON PROCESS MODELS 19 3. THE CONTRIBUTION OF GAME THEORY 41 4. THE THEORY OF VIABILITY 58 5. THE INDIVIDUAL AS A PARTY TO CONFLICT 80 6. THE GROUP AS A PARTY TO CONFLICT: THE ECOLOGICAL MODEL 105 7. THE GROUP AS A PARTY TO CONFLICT: THE EPIDEMIO­ LOGICAL MODEL 123 8. THE ORGANIZATION AS A. PARTY TO CONFLICT 145 9. CONFLICT BETWEEN THE INDIVIDUAL, THE GROUP, AND THE ORGANIZATION 166 10. ECONOMIC CONFLICT 189 11. INDUSTRIAL CONFLICT 208 12. INTERNATIONAL CONFLICT: THE BASIC MODEL 227 13. INTERNATIONAL CONFLICT: MODIFICATIONS AND APPLI­ CATIONS OF THE BASIC THEORY 248 14. IDEOLOGICAL AND ETHICAL CONFLICT 277 15. CONFLICT RESOLUTION AND CONTROL 305 16. EPILOGUE: the PRESENT CRISIS OF CONFLICT and DEFENSE 329 INDEX 345 V PREFACE To the University Press of America Edition The babies who were born when Conflict and Defense was written are now about 28 and presumably actively participating in the world around them. What does this book have to say to this generation, or more importantly perhaps, what does it not say that might be said if it were written now? Conflict and Defense was a very early product of what has come to be known as the peace research movement, embodied in journals, books, institutes around the world, programs in universities, and professional societies, especially the International Peace Research Association, which attracts over 300 people from all around the world at its biennial meetings. Conflict and Defense has reached the status of a “Citation Classic” and has been cited in over 360 publications.1 Somebody must have read the book! I have used it myself recently as a textbook in a course on The Theory of Conflict. Much, of course, has happened in these 28 years, and if I were writing it today it would certainly not be quite the same book. I am particularly grateful, however, to the University Press of America for reprinting it in its original form, so that It can perhaps have some impact on the next generation. 'Conflict and Defense: A General Theory, featured as the “Citation Classic,” Current Contents (Social & Behavioral Sciences), 18, 43 (Oct. 27, 1986): 20; and Current Contents (Arts & Humanities), 8, 43 (Oct. 27, 1986): 20. PREFACE TO THE UPA EDITION viii A whole book could be written—and one day perhaps will be—on the history of conflict thought in the last generation. The patterns of thought have not changed very much. This has been a period of what might be called “normal science” rather than a period of revolutionary change. The static models of conflict (Chapter 1) have not changed very much. There has been a little more “economics imperialism,” the attempt on the part of economics to take over the other social sciences. There have been some contributions from psychology on decision-making pathologies. What still remains to be done here is a much more careful study of who are the parties to conflict, particularly in the case of groups and organizations. Even in the case of the individual, studies of multiple personalities suggest that a single person, and especially a powerful person, is a “group.” Bismarck is supposed to have said “I am a committee.” The single unified person of “economic man” oversimplifies the complexity of actual human behavior. There has been some development of Richardson process analysis (Chapter 2), introducing a few more variables, without, I think, changing the fundamental model. I have even made some contribution to this myself in “The Parameters of Politics.”2 In this article I extend the Richardson process to three parties and show that if an equilibrium is to be reached, that is, a balance of power, the reaction coefficient, that is, how much each party will raise armament expenditures in response to a perceived one percent increase in the other party’s, cannot be more than about 0.7, whereas in a two-party system this is 1.0 or less. I have not seen anything on the n-party case as n gets larger. Oddly enough, the economist’s concept of perfect equilibrium may be relevant here. Game theory (Chapter 3) has continued to stimulate a good deal 2Kenneth E. Boulding, “The Parameters of Politics,” University of Illinois Bulletin (Urbana), 63, 139 (July 15, 1966): 1-21. Reprinted in Kenneth E. Boulding, Collected Papers (Boulder: Colorado Associated University Press), Vol. V, pp. 195-215. IX PREFACE TO THE UPA EDITION of work in the last generation, mainly in terms of the two-party game.3 The subject is still very lively today, as witness the remarkable work of Robert Axelrod4, which suggests that if the parties are given a tit-for-tat strategy, that is, no more than one eye for an eye or one tooth for a tooth, this is likely to be most successful. This theory has been criticized since by Jack Hirshleifer and Juan Carlos Martinez Coll,5 but it still continues to arouse a great deal of interest. From the point of view of its practical applications to conflict, however, game theory has a fundamental weakness: it assumes that the parties to conflict are known and given. In fact, both the origins and the effects of organized conflict are remarkably obscure. What might be called “unconscious conflict,” that is, the real dynamics of the distribution of welfare around the human population, often bears very little relation to conscious conflict. Thus, a union wins a strike, but who loses? Either the people who might have been employed if wages had not risen or the customers who have to pay higher prices. The employer against whom the conflict was ostensibly waged may even benefit. Military defeat often results in both an economic and a cultural expansion of the defeated party at the expense of the victor. Empire often impoverishes the imperial power. Game theory is merely a very abstract theory of conscious conflict. It has very little to say about unconscious conflict, which may be much more important. Chapters 4 to 9 really represent the beginning of an evolutionary theory of conflict, seeing conflict as merely one element in the vast process of evolutionary and ecological interaction which moves us ’See especially Anatol Rapoport and Albert Chammah, The Prisoner’s Dilemma, A Study in Conflict and Cooperation (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1965), for a fairly popular exposition. ■“Robert Axelrod, The Evolution of Cooperation (New York: Basic Books, 1984). ’Jack Hirshleifer and J.C.M. Coll, “What Strategies Can Support the Evolutionary Emergence of Cooperation?” Working Paper No. 58. (Los Angeles: University of California Center for International and Strategic Affairs, February 1987). PREFACE TO THE UPA EDITION X as a total system through time. A good deal of my work (and publications) since writing Conflict and Defense has been devoted to the study of this larger system.6 The role of conflict in this larger process is a matter of great conflict itself between the “dialecticians,” who see conflict as the most important part of the process, and “evolutionists” like myself, who see conflict as occasionally significant, but on the whole a minor part of the process of overall interaction of species in the immense complexity of mutational and selective processes. Since writing Conflict and Defense my main interest in the international field has been in the development of a theory which might be called the “evolution of peace,” as reflected in my book Stable Peace1. It is interesting to note that the biologists are beginning to see that evolution is not a continuous process, but is marked by some quite sharp discontinuities. This is what is called “punctuational evolution.”8 The evolutionary process seems to consist of periods of relative stability, with rather small and gradual changes, which are divided by short periods of very rapid and dramatic change, leading into a new periods of stability. These transition periods may be induced by some catastrophe which opens up all sorts of new niches for new mutations that would not have survived before. A transition may also happen through simply passing over some kind of systems boundary in which positive feedback processes—the more A, the more B; the more B, the more A—become more prominent rather than the negative-feedback processes which lead towards equilibrium (if A gets too big, it will get smaller; if it gets too small, it will get bigger). Punctuated ‘See Kenneth E. Boulding, A Primer on Social Dynamics: History as Dialectics and Development (New York: Free Press, 1970), Ecodynamics: A New Theory of Societal Evolution (Beverly Hills, Calif.: Sage Publications, 1978), Evolutionary Economics (Sage, 1981). ’Kenneth E. Boulding, Stable Peace (Austin: University of Texas Press, 1978). "See Steven Peterson and Albert Somit, eds., “Punctuated Equilibria Theory,” special issue of The Journal of Biological and Social Structures (forthcoming). XI PREFACE TO THE UPA EDITION evolution leads to the perception of stages. Thus, the age of big reptiles and dinosaurs was succeeded by the age of big mammals, as dinosaurs became extinct, perhaps because of some catastrophe about which there is still a good deal of disagreement. It is very tempting to divide human history Into stages—the paleolithic, the mesolithic (which seems to have been something of a catastrophe), the neolithic, leading into agriculture, which releases resources for increased human learning—pottery, weaving, metallurgy—which leads into weaponry, which leads into civilization. Now we seem to be in a transition period of very rapid change,' between civilization and something that can be called “post-civilization.” This transition is very far from being complete and indeed it may not be accomplished, but it is certainly within the realm of the possible. And there is at least some probability that it will lead to a world without war and without poverty. One must always be careful about “stages” because there is continuous change as well as discontinuous change and it is not always easy to say where one stage ends and the next stage begins. Nevertheless, it seems not unreasonable to postulate four stages in the development of international systems, which may also be found in other conflicts. Each of these stages, it should be emphasized, may be found in different places at the same time, and it is quite possible to retrogress, that is, to go from what normally would be a later stage to an earlier one. The four stages are: (1) stable war, in which war goes on all the time, perhaps with some ups and downs of intensity. Southeast Asia seems to have been in this condition for over 50 years. Stable war, however, is very expensive and destructive. It is not surprising that it tends to pass over into the second stage, (2) unstable war, where war is interrupted by periods of peace, although war is still regarded as the norm and peace as just a time of wound licking and preparing for the next year. The Middle East has a good deal of this kind of quality. We see the beginnings of it even in the early civilizations, with the development of royal marriages, diplomacy, trade, and so on.

See more

The list of books you might like

Most books are stored in the elastic cloud where traffic is expensive. For this reason, we have a limit on daily download.